Comments
Transcript
REAL%THEORY%OF%THE%PRICE%LEVEL% Background%
REAL%THEORY%OF%THE%PRICE%LEVEL% Eric Leeper Briefing, 21 September 2015 Background% There are two basic tasks that macroeconomic policy—monetary and fiscal—has to achieve: determine the aggregate price level and stabilize government debt. Without these, other tasks become difficult or impossible. Conventional assignments give monetary policy the task of controlling inflation and fiscal policy the job of stabilizing debt. From this conventional assignment springs the now-standard institutional arrangements of independent central banks that target inflation and fiscal authorities that choose spending and taxes to ensure fiscal sustainability. Both the monetarist and modern new Keynesian perspectives that dominate monetary policy thinking embody those conventional assignments.1 New research has discovered that assignments can be reversed with monetary policy stabilizing debt and fiscal policy determining the price level. This insight has emerged by modeling fiscal behavior with the same attention to detail that monetary theory accords to monetary policy. Filling in the fiscal aspects of macroeconomic theory expands the class of equilibria that can arise to address a broader set of issues and to shed fresh light on traditional issues. The new perspective is called “the real theory of the price level” to distinguish it from a purely monetary theory.2 The real theory of the price level builds on existing monetary and fiscal theory and is in that sense a natural outgrowth of current thought. But the implications for how we treat monetary versus fiscal policy, the empirical predictions and resulting policy implications, and the intellectual framework with which we approach macroeconomic issues, are profoundly different in certain circumstances. For that reason it is also a radical departure.3 Differences between traditional monetary theory and the new theory of the price level can be understood through two equilibrium conditions that are central to price-level determination in all models4 !! !! = !! !! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 1 and 1 See, for example, Friedman (1956) and Woodford (2003). The academic literature labels this new perspective “the fiscal theory of the price level,” but for reasons explained below, “real theory” seems more descriptive. The new theory grew out of work by Leeper (1991), Sims (1994), Woodford (1995), and Cochrane (1998), with significant contributions from Bergin (2000), Bianchi (2012), Bianchi and Ilut (2014), Cochrane (2001, 2005, 2011, 2014), Davig and Leeper (2006), Eusepi and Preston (2013), Leeper and Leith (2015), Sims (1999, 2013), and Woodford (2001), to mention a few. Intellectual predecessors include Friedman (1948, 1960), Tobin (1961, 1969), Brunner and Meltzer (1972), Sargent and Wallace (1981), and Wallace (1981). 3 By way of analogy we might look to general relativity that supplanted Newtonian gravitation, not so much by contradicting as by providing a new paradigm that extended the existing theory. General relativity is a more comprehensive theory, providing a new view of how the universe works, but it does so by extending Newtonian theory to new domains while still giving the same predictions in the low-energy limit. 4 This exposition builds on Cochrane (2005). 2 1 !!!! !!! !!!! !! = !! !" !"#$%"!&! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!(2) where !! !!!! is shorthand for the dollar value of the outstanding government bond portfolio, allowing for a maturity structure for bonds. Condition (1) is the venerable equation of exchange: total nominal expenditures in a year, PY, must equal the stock of money, M, scaled by the number of times each dollar is spent, V, over that year. Friedman developed this identity into the quantity theory of money by deriving a theory of money demand (or velocity). The second condition is a valuation equation that equates the real market value of nominal government liabilities to the expected present value of primary—net of interest payments— budget surpluses. Condition (2) resembles an asset-pricing equation that links the value of an asset to the expected discounted stream of cash flows: the “cash flows” that back government liabilities are the real resources that the government extracts from the economy.5 Although both conditions hold in any equilibrium, they are conceptually quite different. The equation of exchange is an identity that defines velocity; the valuation equation embodies private-sector optimization, so it arises in equilibrium as prices and expected surpluses adjust. Condition (1) is static (though many theories of velocity do introduce dynamics); the second condition is intrinsically dynamic, linking outcomes today to anticipated policy choices over the infinite future. Most importantly, (1) connects nominal objects—nominal spending to nominal sales; the valuation equation connects nominal objects—government liabilities—to real actions taken by government. The last point about expression (2) leads us to label outcomes that emphasize the role of condition (2) “the real theory of the price level.” How%the%Real%Theory%of%the%Price%Level%Works% The real theory of the price level can be thought of as generalizing currently popular moneyonly perspectives on how macroeconomic policies, together with private economic decisions, determine the aggregate price of goods and services. Money-only theories—whether monetarist or new Keynesian—make implicit and rarely explored assumptions about the behavior of fiscal policy whenever those theories are invoked to interpret economic data or to deliver monetary policy advice. 6 The real theory generalizes those views by emphasizing that it is always the joint behavior of monetary and fiscal policy that determines aggregate prices and inflation. One key insight that underlies the real theory is that ultimately the ability of government to affect the relative price of goods and nominal government liabilities—that is, the aggregate price level—lies in the power to tax. Taxes directly extract resources from the private sector and it is that fiscal backing that gives fiat currency—an intrinsically useless object that the issuer does not promise to convert into anything of value—its value in exchange.7 Lerner argues that “money is a creature of the state,” deriving its value from the government’s willingness to accept money in 5 If the government generates seigniorage revenues, those revenues are included in primary surpluses. “Money-only” is a convenient label for analyses that leave fiscal behavior implicit. 7 The government’s ability to extract resources by debasing the currency requires that the currency be valued in the first place. Because no one is compelled to hold fiat currency, this channel cannot serve as a fundamental means by which governments obtain resources. 6 2 payment of taxes: “[Money’s] general acceptability, which is its all-important attribute, stands or falls by its acceptability by the state.”8 Recognizing the fundamental importance of fiscal policy does not deny monetary policy’s importance in affecting macroeconomic outcomes. Instead, it refocuses attention on the joint behavior of the two macroeconomic policy tools. By expanding the perspective to consider monetary and fiscal policies jointly, the analysis uncovers a broader set of macroeconomic equilibria than are typically studied. Those new equilibria can contrast sharply with money-only outcomes. A topical example comes from predicting the macroeconomic consequences of normalizing interest rates. After seven years of near-zero federal funds rates, once the Federal Reserve senses that inflation may begin to rise above its 2 percent target, the Fed will start to raise rates toward their historic average levels. A higher federal funds rate generally raises all interest rates, including those on U.S. treasuries. The money-only view sets aside this fiscal implication of higher interest rates by implicitly assuming that future taxes will rise as needed to finance the higher debt service with larger primary surpluses.9 By “neutralizing” the fiscal impacts, this assumption leads to the money-only conclusion that higher nominal—and real—interest rates will make current consumption more costly, reduce demand for goods, and, through a Phillips curve mechanism, keep inflation in check. But the fiscal implications are huge when, as now, government debt is near 100 percent of GDP. In 2012, when the yield on 10-year Treasury bonds was 1.8 percent, interest payments on the debt were 7.8 percent of federal expenditures. If yields rise to their 50-year average of 6.6 percent, debt service will consume 28.6 percent of the federal budget or over $1 trillion in 2012 dollars. To neutralize the aggregate consequences of this run-up in interest payments, future taxes must rise by $1 trillion in present value. Those higher taxes offset the wealth effects of larger interest receipts and permit the monetary policy tightening to reduce aggregate demand. When higher taxes are not assured, higher wealth cancels monetary policy’s contraction and inflation rises. The effectiveness of monetary policy rests on fiscal behavior. A second insight which the real theory exploits is that it matters a great deal whether the government issues real—indexed for inflation—or nominal debt. Real debt is a claim on goods in the future, requiring the government to back the debt with resources obtained through taxes. If a government cannot raise sufficient resources to pay off the debt, it has no alternative but to default. Nominal debt is much like fiat currency: it is a claim to future dollars. So long as the government controls monetary policy, it can always generate new dollars to meet debt service. This distinction explains recent observations from sovereign debt markets. Starting in 2008, but particularly since 2010, some members of the euro area—Greece, Portugal, Spain, Italy, and Ireland—have seen large increases in their government bond yields relative to Germany. In the cases of Portugal and Spain, yield spreads rose even at moderate debt-GDP levels. Japan’s 8 Lerner (1947, p. 313). This view is rooted in what Knapp (1924) called “chartalism,” the idea that fiat currency has value because of the power of the sovereign to levy taxes that are payable in the currency the sovereign issues. But even earlier Adam Smith (1904, chapter II, p. 311) acknowledged the fundamental importance of taxation: “A prince, who should enact that a certain proportion of his taxes should be paid in a paper money of a certain kind, might thereby give a certain value to this paper money; even though the term of its final discharge and redemption should depend altogether upon the will of the prince.” 9 Of course, since primary surpluses service the debt, government spending could decline instead. 3 government debt, in contrast, is more than double its GDP, while debt in the United Kingdom and the United States is near 100 percent, yet none of these countries face any risk premia in their bond yields. Eurozone nations issue debt in euro, but the quantity of euro is controlled by the European Central Bank rather than individual member nations. To those countries, their debt issuances are effectively real, demanding real (tax) backing. When the backing is not assured, default probabilities rise. Japan, the U.K., and the U.S. can always devalue their outstanding debt through higher inflation or lower bond prices, just as condition (2) depicts. We conclude with another example drawn from recent economic developments: what are the consequences of an interest-rate peg? In his presidential address, Friedman warned that “monetary policy cannot peg interest rates,” and that attempts to do so will lead to everincreasing money growth and inflation.10 Sargent and Wallace formalized the argument by showing that under rational expectations a pegged interest rate leaves the price level untethered: the public anticipates that monetary policy will accommodate whatever quantity of money is demanded at the pegged rate; with real money balances pinned down by the pegged interest rate, any increase in the price level will be met by an increase in the money stock to maintain the desired level of real money balances.11 In his textbook, Sargent goes further to state: “There is no interest rate rule that is associated with a determinate price level.”12 Since December 2008, the Federal Reserve has pegged the federal funds rate near zero, yet there is no evidence that the U.S. price level has become unhinged from fundamentals. During the Great Depression until the Treasury Accord in 1951, the Fed effectively pegged interest rates, again without any apparent untethering of the price level. The real theory of the price level provides an explanation for this apparent contradiction of orthodox monetary theory with observation. Implicit in the Friedman-Sargent-Wallace argument is the assumption that fiscal policy will adjust as needed to ensure that the drifting price level is consistent with equilibrium. Condition (2) makes the required adjustment clear: a pegged interest rate effectively pegs the bond price, !! ; any increase in the price level will reduce the real value of outstanding government liabilities and require fiscal backing to shift down accordingly. Money-only analyses automate this fiscal adjustment without scrutinizing its plausibility. An alternative and at least as reasonable assumption is that there is no automatic adjustment of surpluses to fluctuations in the price level. In both of the historic episodes when the interest rate was pegged, fiscal policies were pursuing goals like economic stabilization, rather than debt stabilization, making surpluses unresponsive to the value of government liabilities. In this case, the present value in (2) is effectively fixed. If bond prices are pegged, then there is a single price level that is consistent with equilibrium. This example reconciles actual policy behavior with economic outcomes to deliver a result that conventional monetary theory cannot address. 10 Friedman (1968, p. 5). See also Friedman and Schwartz (1963). Sargent and Wallace (1975). 12 Sargent (1987, p. 463). 11 4 References% Bergin, Paul R. (2000): “Fiscal Solvency and Price Level Determination in a Monetary Union,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 45(1), 37-53. Bianchi, Francesco (2012): “Evolving Monetary/Fiscal Policy Mix in the United States,” American Economic Review Papers & Proceedings 101(3), 167-172. Bianchi, Francesco and Cosmin Ilut (2014): “Monetary/Fiscal Policy Mix and Agents’ Beliefs,” manuscript, Duke University, May. Brunner, Karl and Allan H. Meltzer (1972): “Money, Debt, and Economic Activity,” Journal of Political Economy, 80(5), 951-977. Cochrane, John H. (1998): “A Frictionless View of U.S. Inflation,” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1998, eds., B. S. Bernanke and J. J. Rotemberg, Cambridge: MIT Press, 323-384. Cochrane, John H. (2001): “Long Term Debt and Optimal Policy in the Fiscal Theory of the Price Level,” Econometrica, 69(1), 69-116. Cochrane, John H. (2005): “Money as Stock,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(3), 501-528. Cochrane, John H. (2011): “Determinacy and Identification with Taylor Rules,” Journal of Political Economy, 119(3), 565-615. Cochrane, John H. (2014): “Monetary Policy with Interest on Reserves,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 49(December), 74-108. Davig, Troy and Eric M. Leeper (2006): “Fluctuating Macro Policies and the Fiscal Theory,” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2006, vol. 21, eds., D. Acemoglu, K. Rogoff and M. Woodford, Cambridge: MIT Press, 247-298. Eusepi, Stefano and Bruce Preston (2013), “Fiscal Foundations of Inflation: Imperfect Knowledge,” manuscript, Monash University, October. Friedman, Milton (1948): “A Monetary and Fiscal Framework for Economic Stability,” American Economic Review, 38(2), 245-264. Friedman, Milton (1956): “The Quantity Theory of Money—A Restatement,” in Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money, ed., M. Friedman, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 3-21. Friedman, Milton (1960): A Program for Monetary Stability, New York: Fordham University Press. Friedman, Milton (1968): “The Role of Monetary Policy,” American Economic Review, 58(1), 117. Friedman, Milton and Anna Jacobson Schwartz (1963): A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960, Princeton: Princeton University Press. Knapp, George Friedrich (1924): The State Theory of Money, London: Macmillan and Company. Leeper, Eric M. (1991): “Equilibria Under ‘Active’ and ‘Passive’ Monetary and Fiscal Policies,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 27(1), 129-147. Leeper, Eric M. and Campbell Leith (2015): “Inflation Through the Lens of the Fiscal Theory,” forthcoming in Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. 2, eds., J. B. Taylor and H. Uhlig, Amsterdam: Elsevier Press. Lerner, Abba P. (1947): “Money as a Creature of the State,” American Economic Review Papers & Proceedings, 37(2): 312-317. 5 Sargent, Thomas J. (1987): Macroeconomic Theory, 2nd ed., San Diego: Academic Press, Inc. Sargent, Thomas J. and Neil Wallace (1975): “Rational Expectations, the Optimal Monetary Instrument, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule,” Journal of Political Economy, 83(2), 241254. Sargent, Thomas J. and Neil Wallace (1981): “Some Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 5(Fall), 1-17. Sims, Christopher A. (1994): “A Simple Model for Study of the Determination of the Price Level and the Interaction of Monetary and Fiscal Policy,” Economic Theory, 4(3), 381-399. Sims, Christopher A. (1999): “The Precarious Fiscal Foundations of EMU,” De Economist, 147(4), 415-436. Sims, Christopher A. (2013): “Paper Money,” American Economic Review, 103(2), 563-584. Smith, Adam (1904): An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, vol. I, London: Methuen. Tobin, James (1961): “Money, Capital and Other Stores of Value,” American Economic Review Papers & Proceedings, 51(2), 26-37. Tobin, James (1969): “A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 1(1), 15-29. Wallace, N. (1981): “A Modigliani-Miller Theorem for Open-Market Operations,” American Economic Review, 71(3), 267-274. Woodford, M. (1995): “Price-Level Determinacy Without Control of a Monetary Aggregate,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 43, 1–46. Woodford, Michael (2001): “Fiscal Requirements for Price Stability,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 33(3), 669–728. Woodford, Michael (2003): Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy, Princeton: Princeton University Press. 6