Trends and Cycles in China’s Macroeconomy Chun Chang Daniel F. Waggoner Tao Zha
by user
Comments
Transcript
Trends and Cycles in China’s Macroeconomy Chun Chang Daniel F. Waggoner Tao Zha
Trends and Cycles in China’s Macroeconomy1 Chun Changa Daniel F. Waggonerb Tao Zhac a SAIF, Shanghai Jiao Tong University Reserve Bank of Atlanta c FRB Atlanta, Emory University, and NBER b Federal University of Chicago November 13, 2014 1 c 2012-2014 by Chang, Waggoner, and Zha. The views expressed Copyright herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta or the Federal Reserve System or the National Bureau of Economic Research. Table of Contents Overview Data Empirical method Empirical evidence Conclusion Introduction I For the past two decades Chinas economy has grown rapidly. Introduction I For the past two decades Chinas economy has grown rapidly. I Growth in investment has recently fallen because of excess capacity. Introduction I For the past two decades Chinas economy has grown rapidly. I Growth in investment has recently fallen because of excess capacity. I The common view is that business cycles are unimportant in China and growth is driven entirely by trend. Introduction I For the past two decades Chinas economy has grown rapidly. I Growth in investment has recently fallen because of excess capacity. I The common view is that business cycles are unimportant in China and growth is driven entirely by trend. I Yet there has been little empirical evidence to support this view. Introduction I For the past two decades Chinas economy has grown rapidly. I Growth in investment has recently fallen because of excess capacity. I The common view is that business cycles are unimportant in China and growth is driven entirely by trend. I Yet there has been little empirical evidence to support this view. In particular there has been little empirical study on I I I the basic facts on trends, cycles, and volatilities of China’s economy, and how various monetary instruments interact with the real variables. Introduction I For the past two decades Chinas economy has grown rapidly. I Growth in investment has recently fallen because of excess capacity. I The common view is that business cycles are unimportant in China and growth is driven entirely by trend. I Yet there has been little empirical evidence to support this view. In particular there has been little empirical study on I I I I the basic facts on trends, cycles, and volatilities of China’s economy, and how various monetary instruments interact with the real variables. This paper is to fill this important vacuum by providing some empirical facts on China’s macroeconomy. What does this paper do? The first challenging task is to construct a set of core macroeconomic time series for China to be as consistent with the NIPA as possible, all in level on quarterly frequency from 1991Q1 to present (2013Q2): I nominal and real GDP (fixed-weight – the 1993 UN standards), implicit GDP deflator; I CPI, nominal retail consumption (no data available for some services); I nominal investment, prices of investment goods; I nominal exports and imports of goods (these data are collected by customs, so no data available for services); I nominal exchange rate for the RMB and the USD; I nominal government spendings; I M2, monetary base; I Required reserve ratio; I Deposit rates. Table of Contents Overview Data Empirical method Empirical evidence Conclusion Sources of the data I Our quarterly macroeconomic series are constructed based on the CEIC (China Economic Information Center, now belonging to Euromoney Institutional Investor Company) Database—one of the most comprehensive macroeconomic data sources for China. I Two major sources of the CEIC Database are the National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) and the People’s Bank of China (PBC). I During the past one and a half years, we have been assembling the macroeconomic time series and are still in the process of improving our data quality. Challenge The difficulty of constructing a standard set of quarterly time series lies in several dimensions. I The NBS—the most authoritative source of economic data—reports only percentage changes of certain key macroeconomic variables such as real GDP. I Many variables, such as investment and consumption, do not have quarterly data. Annual books published by the NBS, using the expenditure approach, have only annual data with continual revisions of the data from 2000 on. I For quarterly or monthly frequencies, there are data published by the NBS, using the value-added approach (Brandt and Zhu 2010), for only subcomponents or variables with definitions different from those with the NIPA expenditure approach. I Many series on quarterly frequencies are not available for the period of the early 1990s. For that period, we extrapolate the series that are likely to be unreliable. I Few seasonally adjusted data are provided by the NBS or by the PBC. Illustration: Construction of Real GDP in Level I The NBS publishes y/y changes of real GDP in two forms (let t be the first quarter of the base year): yt+1 +yt yt I year-to-date (YTD) y/y changes: yt−4 (Q1), yt−3 +yt−4 (Q2), yt+2 +yt+1 +yt yt−2 +yt−3 +yt−4 yt+3 +yt+2 +yt+1 +yt (Q3), yt−1 +yt−2 +yt−3 +yt−4 (Q4); yt+1 yt+2 yt+3 yt I non-YTD y/y changes: yt−4 (Q1), yt−3 (Q2), yt−2 (Q3), yt−1 (Q4). I What is published: the data on non-YTD y/y changes go back to only 1999Q4, while the series of YTD y/y changes begins from 1991Q4 on. I Given yt (the nominal GDP at quarter t), we obtain yt+4 from yt+4 = at+4 yt = bt+4 yt , where a represents YTD y/y changes and b represents non-YTD y/y changes. I We then obtain yt+1 and yt+5 by solving the following two equations yt+5 + yt+4 = at+5 , yt+1 + yt yt+5 = bt+5 . yt+1 Illustration: Construction of real GDP in level I Now given yt , yt+1 , yt+4 , yt+5 , we obtain yt+2 and yt+6 by solving the two equations yt+6 + yt+5 + yt+4 yt+2 + yt+1 + yt yt+6 yt+2 I = at+6 , = bt+6 . Then, we obtain yt+3 and yt+7 by solving yt+7 + yt+6 + yt+5 + yt+4 yt+3 + yt+2 + yt+1 + yt yt+7 yt+3 I = at+7 , = bt+7 . Given yt , yt+1 , yt+2 , yt+3 , yt+4 , yt+5 , yt+6 , yt+7 , we use the YTD y/y changes to calculate out all the series of real GDP in level. Quality of constructed data We choose the base year (2008Q1) to minimize the differences between the non-YTD y/y changes implied by our constructed level series and those from the NBS. 18 16 YTD GDP growth: raw data non−YTD GDP growth: raw data non−YTD GDP growth: constracted data Percent 14 12 10 8 6 1992Q1 1997Q1 2002Q1 Year/Quarter 2007Q1 2012Q1 Inflation data The implicit GDP deflator is more volatile than the CPI (consistent with Nakamura, Steinsson, and Liu (2013)). Inflation (annualized %) 50 GDP CPI 40 30 20 10 0 −10 −20 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Constructed quarterly core data for estimation Log implicit GDP deflator Log M2 5 12 4.8 11 4.6 10 4.4 9 4.2 4 8 7 1990 3.8 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 3.6 1990 1995 Log real investment 8.5 8 8 7.5 7.5 7 7 6.5 6.5 6 6 5.5 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 5 1990 1995 Log real imports 2010 2015 2000 2005 2010 2015 2010 2015 Log real GDP 8 5.5 7.5 5 7 4.5 6.5 4 6 3.5 5.5 5 1990 2005 Log real exports 9 8.5 5.5 1990 2000 3 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2.5 1990 1995 2000 2005 Growth rates (y/y, %) M2 growth (y/y) Inflation (y/y) 45 25 40 20 35 15 30 10 25 5 20 0 15 10 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 −5 1990 Investment growth (y/y) 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Real exports growth (y/y) 60 80 60 40 40 20 20 0 0 −20 −40 1990 −20 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 −40 1990 1995 Real imports growth (y/y) 60 16 40 14 20 12 0 10 −20 −40 1990 2000 2005 2010 2015 2010 2015 GDP growth (y/y) 8 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 6 1990 1995 2000 2005 Further data analysis Inflation (y/y, %) Inflation (q/q, %) 30 50 GDP CPI 25 20 30 15 20 10 10 5 0 0 −10 −5 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 −20 1990 Money growth (y/y, %) 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Real exchange rate (RMB/$) 50 11 M2 Base 40 10 30 9 20 8 10 7 0 −10 1990 GDP CPI 40 6 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 5 1990 3−month deposit rate (%) 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Reserve requirement (%) 7 25 6 20 5 4 15 3 10 2 1 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 5 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Further data analysis Ratio of investment to GDP (%) Ratio of government spending to total investment (%) 60 50 55 45 50 40 45 35 40 35 30 30 25 25 20 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 20 1990 Ratios of exports and imports to GDP (%) 28 2000 2005 2010 2015 Ratio of net exports to GDP (%) 7 Exports Imports 26 6 24 5 22 4 20 3 18 2 16 1 14 0 12 −1 10 1990 1995 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 −2 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Table of Contents Overview Data Empirical method Empirical evidence Conclusion Regimes switching Dates of switching December 1978 Beginning of 1992 Early 1990s January 1994 1994 1995-1996 July 1997 November 1997 November 2001 July 2005 September 2008 2009-2010 Major events Introduction of economic reforms Advanced the reforms by Deng Xiaoping Price controls and rationing Ended the two-tiered foreign exchange system Major tax reforms and devaluation of RMB Phased out out price controls and rationing Asian financial crises started in Thailand Began privatization Joined the WTO and trade liberalization Ended an explicit peg to the USD U.S. and world wide financial crisis Fiscal stimulus of 4 trillion RMB investment An important role of monetary aggregates in China I The PBC heavily regulates lending operations (lending rates, credit quotas, and “window guidance”) of the four largest commercial banks: Bank of China, Agricultural Bank of China, Industrial and Commercial Bank of China, and Construction Bank of China. I With underdevelopment of other forms of financial intermediation, bank loans remain the major source of funding for Chinese domestic firms. I Thus, broad monetary aggregates such as M2 represent a good approximation to the central bank’s policy tool as well as a financial intermediation in the transition of China’s economy. An important role of reserve requirement in China I Interest rates in the money market have been heavily regulated by the PBC—in essence, no money market has existed until recently. I The required reserves are used by the PBC to influence the changes in money supply. Question I With all the major political and economic events, as well as many other such events on a smaller scale, how do we know which event affects cycles, which event affects volatilities, and which event triggers trend break? I Chow (2002) and Lin (2011) offer an informative narrative of how the PBC used money supply as a main tool to stabilize the cycles by expanding or cooling economic growth. I The question is how to decouple cycles from trends and volatilities. Econometric approach Built on the VAR framework—Sims and Zha (1998), Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (1999), and Waggoner, Sims, and Zha (2009). The model I P 0 A + ε0 Ξ−1 (s ∗ ). Primitive form: yt0 A0 = c st† + p`=1 yt−` ` t t I The dimension of yt is n. I I I I I I I The switching processes represented by st† and st∗ are independent of each other. Regimes: st† ∈ {1, . . . , h† }, st∗ ∈ {1, . . . , h∗ }. P 0 B + u0 . Reduced form: yt0 = c̃ st† + p`=1 yt−` ` t −1 0 0 −1 (s ∗ ) A−1 . c̃ st† = c st† A−1 t 0 , B` = A` A0 , ut = εt Ξ 0 The covariance matrix for −1the reduced-form residuals ut is . Σ (st∗ ) = A0 Ξ2 (st∗ ) A00 Companion form: xt = C st† + Bxt−1 + ũt . The dimension of xt is m × 1, where m = np. The dimension † of C st is m × 1. The dimension of B is m × m. The dimension of ũt is m × 1. Imposing the trends I Following Hansen, Heaton, and Li (2008), we’ll impose conintegration relationships on the model and compute the marginal likelihood to see the fit. I In sharp contrast to the HP filter, it allows us to compare the long-run behavior of the model to the VAR evidence. Separating trends from cycles I I Decompose B into eigenvalues and eigenvectors: d1 0 0 −1 , B = UDU −1 = u1 , . . . , um 0 . . . 0 u1 , . . . , um 0 0 dm where d1 ≥ · · · ≥ dm . P We have xt = m i=1 αt,i ui , where αt,1 .. −1 . = U xt αt,m Separating trends from cycles I I I Suppose the first q largest eigenvalues are equal to a unit root. P The trend component is xtp = qi=1 αt,i ui . P The cycle component is xts = m i=q+1 αt,i ui . Table of Contents Overview Data Empirical method Empirical evidence Conclusion Model comparison I I With extensive model comparison, data do not favor many of the changes. Stochastic switches for volatility regime improve the fit considerably: I I I I Large volatility in 1998Q1-1998Q3 (during the Asian financial crisis). Large volatility in 2008Q3-2009Q2 (during the U.S. financial crisis). Marginal data density (MDD) in log value: 1.447.9 (no switching) and 1507.5 (volatility regime). Data also favor a change in the intercept after the late volatility regime (2009Q3). I MDD in log value: 1508.6. Estimated volatility regimes Volatility regime 1 1.4 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2008 2010 2012 2014 Volatility regime 2 1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 Intercept change GDP 15 10 5 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 30 M2 25 20 15 10 1996 10 Inflation 5 0 −5 1996 First intercept regime in China—1995Q1-2009Q2 I The period of 1995Q1-2009Q2 can be characterized as the period of privatization and trade liberalization. I Cheap labor supply, strong worldwide demand for China’s exports, productivity gains from restructuring the state-owned-enterprises (SOEs), and reallocation of capital and labor between SOEs and domestic private enterprises (DPEs) are the most important aspects of privatization and trade liberalization during this period. I The low-productive SOEs had access to bank loans, while the high-productive DPEs faced severe external finance constraints (Bai, Hsieh, and Qian, 2006; Song, Storesletten, and Zilibotti, 2011; Yang, 2012). I In March of 1998, the PBC began to use the RRR as an important instrument for conducting monetary policy. Second intercept regime in China—2009Q3-2013Q2 I In the aftermath of the world wide financial meltdown in September of 2008, the government put in 4 trillion RMB investment in 2009 and 2010 as a fiscal stimulus. I But the most conspicuous stimulus was given by the PBC with a sharp increase in M2 growth in 2009-2010 (in contrast to an increase in the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet). I These efforts aimed partly at stabilizing the fluctuations caused by the financial crisis and partly at stemming the tide of an inevitable lower growth trend. I Thus it is important to extract trend and cyclical components from the data in one single time-series framework. Estimated results I Decomposition of growth rates (annualized %): Regime M2 Inflation Investment Exports Imports GDP Data I II 16.38 15.48 2.69 4.27 12.25 9.05 11.56 9.90 10.06 10.78 9.36 8.46 Intercept Changes Trend I II 17.93 15.86 3.57 3.15 11.08 8.00 3.34 4.69 6.33 3.63 9.80 9.30 Cycle I II -1.55 -0.38 -0.88 1.11 1.17 1.04 8.22 5.20 3.72 7.14 -0.43 -0.83 I Cyclical fluctuations contribute to a considerably large portion of growth changes in prices, exports, and imports. I A nontrivial fraction of growth in investment and output is also drive by cyclical fluctuations. I Slower trend growth of output in Regime II is driven by slower trend growth of both M2 and investment, as well as exports (see the distribution). 68% error bands for growth rates under intercept changes M2 Inflation Investment Exports Imports GDP M2 Inflation Investment Exports Imports GDP Low 13.07 2.14 9.39 2.67 6.79 7.34 Regime I—Higher Growth Trend Cycle Estimate High Low Estimate 17.93 18.28 -1.96 -1.55 3.57 4.37 -1.70 -0.88 11.08 14.81 -2.61 1.17 3.34 18.34 -6.85 8.22 6.33 19.93 -9.94 3.72 9.80 11.21 -1.85 -0.43 High 3.30 0.54 2.83 8.66 3.18 1.99 Low 10.88 1.66 5.69 -0.38 2.11 5.17 Regime II—Lower Growth Trend Cycle Estimate High Low Estimate 15.86 15.56 -0.08 -0.38 3.15 3.63 0.62 1.11 8.00 10.63 -1.58 1.04 4.69 11.16 -1.34 5.20 3.63 13.90 -3.12 7.14 9.30 8.75 -0.29 -0.83 High 4.59 2.60 3.34 10.14 8.59 3.27 Estimated trends 5 12 Price M2 14 10 8 1995 2000 2005 2010 4 1995 2015 8 7 2005 2010 4 1995 2015 5 5 GDP Imp 2000 4.5 2000 2005 2010 2015 2000 2005 2010 2015 2000 2005 2010 2015 2000 2005 2010 2015 4 3 1995 2015 0.03 Drate 0.12 RRR 2010 5 6 0.1 0.08 1995 2005 4.5 5.5 4 1995 2000 5.5 Exp Invest 9 6 1995 4.5 2000 2005 2010 2015 0.025 0.02 0.015 1995 Estimated trend distributions: Exports 0.09 Regime I Regime II 0.08 0.07 Probability density 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 −20 −10 0 10 Exports 20 30 40 Estimated trend distributions: Investment 0.35 Regime I Regime II 0.3 Probability density 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 Investment 12 14 16 18 20 Estimated trend distributions: GDP 0.35 Regime I Regime II 0.3 Probability density 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 0 5 10 GDP 15 Estimated cycles 0 Price M2 −0.4 −0.6 −0.8 1995 2000 2005 2010 −0.2 −0.4 1995 2015 0.5 0 1995 2000 2005 2010 GDP Imp 2 2000 2005 2010 2015 2000 2005 2010 2015 2000 2005 2010 2015 2000 2005 2010 2015 2 −0.2 −0.3 1995 2015 0.04 Drate 0.2 RRR 2010 −0.1 2.5 0 −0.2 1995 2005 3 1 1995 2015 3 1.5 1995 2000 4 Exp Invest 1 2000 2005 2010 2015 0.02 0 −0.02 1995 Some facts about the cyclical movements I The cycles are very long. I Prices, GDP, reserve requirement, and the deposit rate tend to comove. I Imports, exports, investment tend to comove. I There is little comovement between investment and GDP. I The relationships between exports and GDP are weak. I Money supply tends to move in opposite with investment and the external sector (imports and exports) than with GDP. Correlations over business cycles M2 Price Investment Exports Imports GDP RRR D Rate M2 1.0000 0.4016 -0.7759 -0.9794 -0.9602 0.3951 -0.3706 0.4835 Prices 0.4016 1.0000 0.0584 -0.2758 -0.5252 0.9116 0.6828 0.7910 Investment -0.7759 0.0584 1.0000 0.8485 0.7230 -0.0177 0.6597 -0.2223 Exports -0.9794 -0.2758 0.8485 1.0000 0.9398 -0.2901 0.4880 -0.4525 Imports -0.9602 -0.5252 0.7230 0.9398 1.0000 -0.5617 0.2044 -0.5551 GDP 0.3951 0.9116 -0.0177 -0.2901 -0.5617 1.0000 0.6139 0.7135 RRR -0.3706 0.6828 0.6597 0.4880 0.2044 0.6139 1.0000 0.3631 D Rate 0.4835 0.7910 -0.2223 -0.4525 -0.5551 0.7135 0.3631 1.0000 Table of Contents Overview Data Empirical method Empirical evidence Conclusion Dynamic responses with square root Drate RRR GDP Imp Exp Invest Price M2 M2 Price Invest Exp Imp GDP RRR Drate Dynamic responses withCholeski Drate RRR GDP Imp Exp Invest Price M2 M2 Price Invest Exp Imp GDP RRR Drate Impulse responses to a trend shock −3 M2 Price x 10 0.02 7 6 0.018 5 0.016 4 3 0.014 2 0.012 1 0 0.01 −1 0.008 −2 0 5 10 15 20 25 0 5 10 −3 Investment 20 25 15 20 25 GDP x 10 0.016 15 3.5 0.014 3 0.012 2.5 0.01 0.008 2 0.006 1.5 0.004 1 0.002 0 0.5 0 5 10 15 20 25 0 5 10 Impulse responses to two stationary shocks −3 2 −3 M2 x 10 1 1 M2 x 10 0 0 −1 −1 −2 0 5 10 −3 2 15 20 25 −2 0 5 10 −4 GDP x 10 5 15 20 25 15 20 25 GDP x 10 0 0 −5 −2 −4 −10 0 5 −3 6 x 10 10 15 20 25 −15 2 4 0 0 −1 0 5 −3 1 10 15 20 25 −2 10 Reserve requirement ratio x 10 0 5 −4 Interest rate 15 0.5 10 0 5 −0.5 −1 5 x 10 1 2 −2 0 −3 Reserve requirement ratio 10 15 20 25 20 25 Interest rate x 10 0 0 5 10 15 20 25 −5 0 5 10 15 Findings I Money supply has been largely endogenous in response to a trend shock so that M2, the price level, and GDP co-move (previous figure). I In contrast to Leeper, Sims, and Zha (1996) and Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (1999), the effect on output of a stationary shock to the reserve requirement ratio is stronger than that of a stationary shock to the interest rate (previous figure). I Right column of the previous figure: an increase of 0.1% in the interest rate lowers Chinas GDP by 0.08%, but not very persistently. I Left column of the previous figure: an increase of 0.1% in the required reserve ratio lowers Chinas GDP by 0.08%, but very persistently. Recap I Trend inflation appears not to be a problem. I Rapid trend growth in investment seems to be a driving force of impressive trend growth of GDP. I Cyclical fluctuations, even after controlling for a switch in intercept, are important for China’s economy. I Cyclical fluctuations of exports and imports move together with those of investment. I Cyclical fluctuations of investment and exports, however, do not comove with those of GDP (fiscal policy implications). Leaning-against-wind monetary policy: I I I M2 moves in opposite with both GDP and inflation over the business cycle. The required reserve rate and the deposit rate comove with both GDP and inflation over the business cycle. Conclusion I I In the transition of China’s macroeconomy, monetary aggregates such as M2, as well as required reserves and the deposit rate, play a substantive role in both fluctuations and growth of aggregate output. Moving beyond privatization and trade liberalization, financial liberalization (as confirmed by the November 2013 plenum of China) is needed in the future: I I I Economic growth may face a trend break or a long cycle with more reliance on an increase of domestic demand (consumption). Fluctuations of M2 will inevitably play a less important role in both growth and cycles as financial reforms go beyond the banking sector. Any structural macro model should take into account all these salient features. Back to Introduction