Comments
Description
Transcript
C HRONICLES T HE
THE CHRONICLES ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS HISTORY RESEARCH CENTRE CHRONICLES JANUARY—MARCH 2006, V OLUME 1 / I SSUE 3 The American University in Cairo TABLE OF CONTENTS EBHRC CHRONICLES Editor: Dina Khalifa Hussein Director, EBHRC: Prof. Abdelaziz Ezzelarab Project Officers: Mostafa Hefny Mohamed I. Fahmy Menza Wael Ismail Administrative Assistant, EBHRC: Yasmeen Samir Young Scholars Contributors: Zeinab Abul-Magd Jano Charbel Amr Nasr El-Din Lee Nunley Karim El-Sayed Dina Waked Guest Contributors: Prof. Joel Beinin Layout &Design: Magda Elsehrawi Logo: Nadine Kenawy THIS ISSUE HAS BEEN COPY EDITED BY Prof. Hala El-Ramly Ms. Jayme Spencer Prof. Herbert Thompson ******* About EBHRC EBHRC Supporting Institutes: Center for Middle East Studies, Harvard University Near East Studies Program, Princeton University Middle East Center, University of Pennsylvania Middle East Center, University of Washington Global Business Center, Business School, University of Washington Office of Provost, AUC Office of Dean of BEC, AUC Economics Department, AUC The Editor’s Note 2 From our Archives Margins of the Economic Past 3 A Prologue to Egypt’s Industrialization 5 Graveyards and Digital Recordings 7 Interview When Firms and Entreprenures Cross Borders 12 Historical Perspectives Egyptian Textile Workers in the Transition to a Neo-Liberal Order 16 The Story of Egyptian Railroads 19 The Nurturing of Wealth: The First Call for a National Bank in Egypt Translated Manshour p. 26 23 History in the Making Law and Economy in Egypt 30 Skirmishes in the War for Drugs 34 The Chinese Real Estate Boom 38 In the Pipeline Egypt’s Trade Unions: Reason for Hope or Hopelessness 44 Business Not as Usual Traditional Crafts—An Untraditional Source of Income 47 Research Ideas The Laws of Competition 50 Book Review The Story of an Arab on Wall Street 52 EBHRC Collaborating Scholars: Prof. Ellis Goldberg, (University of Washington) Prof. Roger Owen (Harvard) Prof. Robert Tignor (Princeton University) Prof. Robert Vitalis (University of Pennsylvania) 1 Our Archives 54 Announcements back cover Cover image: Salim Khalil al-Naqqash, Misr lil-Misriyin. (Alexandira, 1884) EDITOR’S NOTE EDITOR’S NOTE... istorians and storytellers have a lot in common. They both endeavor to describe a story that occurs between a spectrum of fiction and reality, and mostly precedes a present disquiet and delve into the past, narrating details of incidents and how they occurred. More ambitious historians attempt to propose an answer to a question, such as what went wrong? People’s memories is the reservoir for our quest to revisit historical incidents and narrate similar historical stories and questions. Some of these memories expose a history on the margin of mainstream literature. The Chronicles’ From our Archives section presents stories of Egypt’s industrial experience and more importantly highlights the human factors behind important policies and their execution. H In an interview with Prof. Geoffery Jones, we delve into the intellectual development of a prominent business historian, and explore how business history is and should be conducted. Prof. Joel Beinin gives voice to the marginalized, the workers whose story is traced through their strikes and protests. Jano Charbel recounts the story of the unions and syndicates. As in all historical stories, the writers’ treasures are old documents that are themselves the foundations of historical realities. In this issue, Prof. Abdelaziz Ezzelarab introduces a communiqué or manshur titled “Inma’ al-Mal” (“The Nurturing of Wealth”) which was issued in April 1879 and urged the public to found a joint stock national bank through public subscription. Its opening statement claims that God commands people to invest in nurturing natural wealth. Thus, the first call for a national bank is nourished by a religious lingua whose consequent historical repercussions are raised by the author. We present this issue of The Chronicles as an intertwining of historical stories and contemporary realties. We shift between digital recordings of oral history to old documents and newspaper clippings among other sources to present 14 articles, with immense gratitude to our contributors and supporters. Dina Khalifa Hussein, Project Officer, EBHRC NOTE OF GRATITUDE One of our colleagues made a career shift last month. Wael Ismail is one of the founding project officers of the center and was present since its conception. We are immensely grateful for Wael’s contributions and wish him the best in his future plans. We also send our best wishes to Dina Waked, Karim El-Sayed, and Omar Cheta, our colleagues and friends who have embarked on new careers, and thank them for their continuing support. 2 FROM OUR ARCHIVES Margins of the Economic Past Wael M. Ismail, Project Officer, EBHRC oices of those on the margin are easily swept under the carpet of great events of a nation’s history. The marginalized have been cast in the past as those oppressed classes of the underprivileged, the poor and the working classes. Our definition of the term has to be broadened however for us to truly understand the course of events. The marginalized are not necessarily those mentioned above, in some cases they are not those working on the factory’s floor but those sitting in their offices higher up the ladder. V Egypt’s economic history can be summed up with ease into neat, clear cut compartments and epochs. Looking from the outside it would seem that before the 1952 revolution the country “... the marginalized are in some cases not those working on the factory’s floor but those sitting in their offices higher up the ladder...” 3 possessed a liberal economic system, the revolution came to change all that and transform the country and the economy into a state-run enterprise. The death of Gamal Abdel Nasser brought new waves of reforms that culminated in the 1974 October paper that ushered the way for the open door policy and a complete change in the country’s economic policies. It would seem that Egypt for the past fifty years has been working its way back to the pre-1952 current state of things, although this brief outline of the country’s economic transformation might be true to an extent; this is an outline that stands on shaky ground. For the past two years, interviews conducted by the Economic and Business History Research Centre brought to the fore, at least to the interviewers conducting interviews with various public officials, whether ministers or public sector managers, new issues and questions. The roster of interviewees was mainly focused on individuals who had played an important role in shaping Egypt’s economic past. Their reflections on their careers and current state of things produced a number of interesting and insightful narratives. These narratives often opened a window onto a past that was blocked by mass generalizations and assumptions usually taken for granted about the epochs discussed. Dr. Eng. Adel Gazarin, was one of the first interviewees. His tenure at Al Nasr Automotive Co. and his involvement in institutions such as the Egyptian Federation of Industries (former presi- “... To truly understand the impact of economic policies, it was essential to grasp the point of view of the men responsible for their execution ...” dent) helped illuminte issues concerning Egypt’s industrial experience - especially after 1952. To truly understand the impact of economic policies, it was essential to grasp the point of view of the men responsible for their execution. Dr. Gazarin’s input mainly revolved around Al Nasr Co.. From his account of the ups and downs of this fallen giant, a number of observations can be extrapolated. The importance of such an account and others compiled is that these figures witnessed the changes that occurred in Egypt’s economic policy as they took place. They were not themselves marginalized, but their accounts and narratives were clearly marginalized when Egypt’s economic history was numerously. Listening to Dr. Gazarin narrate his own version of the past, a number of issues that were formerly taken for granted were problematized in light of the new material. FROM “.. The marginalized have been cast in the past as those oppressed classes of the underprivileged, the poor and the working classes. Our definition of the term has to be broadened however for us to truly understand the course of events ...” OUR of the state’s political agenda. On more than one occasion Dr. Gazarin spoke of how some policies that were enacted severely impacted the public sector and, in particular, Al Nasr Co. According to him the company was burdened with so many projects, it never had the chance to specialize in one area and excel in it. From the outset the company, everything was politicized, from the pricing of the cars that was determined by politicians to the refusal of partnering foreign capital in the establishment of the company. The latter reason contributed to the failure of the company as Dr. Gazarin noted, especially if Al Nasr was to be compared to the other car manufacturing companies that were established in the Far East with the participation of foreign capital leading to various success stories. Another major problem that the company faced was the introduction of the labor force as important players on the board of the company under Nasser. The workers gained numerous rights that according to Dr. Gazarin were abused, and, on more than one occasion kept the management from running the company efficiently. What is mentioned in this article, are glimpses of what the entire narrative offered. The narrative offered by Dr. Gazarin gave birth to numerous perspectives, some already known to the academic public and others, which are not. One of the most interesting issues raised in the interviews with Dr. Gazarin was the intangible benefit of the public sector endeavor that Egypt embarked upon. Talking about the public sector Dr. Gazarin mentioned the difficulties that mangers of public companies faced from lack of investment, to poor economic and financial planning. However, he was also aware that these companies, and Al Nasr Co. in particular, acted as an “academy” that graduated executives who gained experience and know how in the company that they later transferred to the private sector where they now work. In these holistic narratives dealing with the economic history of Egypt, rarely do we find mention of the role of the managers of public companies. In most cases they were merely executives. Clearly there is more than one example of managers who were not blindly following orders but were individuals who truly cared for the enterprise they were running. The account given by Dr. Gazarin is invaluable on its own; however, such an account gains a whole new perspective when it is amassed with other narratives from the same era of individuals who had more or less the same position, whether as managers of public firms or policy makers involved with economic policies. The three interviews conducted with Dr. Gazarin offered a run down of the impact of various economic policies on Egypt’s industrial sector. From his post as the longest, serving chairman of Al Nasr Co and later as the president of Egypt’s Federation of Industries, Dr. Gazarin spoke of how the state’s attitude changed regarding the country’s industrial base. Dr. Gazarin was equally critical of both the nationalization laws of the 1960s and the open door policy adopted under Sadat. In both epochs the economy was left under the mercy Dr. Heba Handoussa is an economist and an academic who also worked as a consultant for various ministers of industry over the years. In an interview with her, she commented on the state of public sector managers in the 1960s, asserting that with the increased government role, managers of public sector firms were transformed from daring young executives to mere bureaucrats. The transformation of this class of executives from entrepreneurs in their own right (albeit in public sector firms) to ARCHIVES “... The transformation of this class of executives from entrepreneurs in their own right (albeit in public sector firms) to exactly what critics of public sector firms warn against is an issue that is rich and intriguing, yet remains largely unexplored by researchers in the economic and business history of Egypt ...” exactly what critics of public sector firms warn against is an issue that is rich and intriguing, yet remains largely unexplored by researchers in the economic and business history of Egypt. Such narratives, more than anything else, help us shed some light on areas that have been untapped by research, either because of ignorance of their existence or due to the lack of research material. These counter narratives, so to speak, allow us to see what could have happened and what actually did happen in the end. They are pathways to a treasure of missed opportunities that are at times more telling about an era than those chances taken. 4 FROM OUR ARCHIVES A Prologue to Egypt's Industrialization Dr. Ismail Sabri Abdallah introduces the human elements behind Egypt’s industrialization Dina Khalifa Hussein, Project Officer, EBHRC he economic history of Egypt is founded on the decisions of political rulers-independent and otherwise. Mohamed Ali might be the first in a line of political leaders who shaped modern Egypt’s economic history and Gamal AbdelNasser has strongly staked his position in this historical structure. A myriad of arguments are still sounded, almost on daily bases, that are either critical of Nasser’s era or in praise of his policies. In most cases, we are left to bay the moon, searching for a clear understanding of Egypt’s historical experience, particularly when it comes to industrialization. Without promising any easy way out of this dilemma, it becomes insightful to look closer at how the players of this era introduce the story of Egypt’s industrialization. T Dr. Ismail Sabri Abdallah was less than thirty years old when he was first asked to be a consultant for Nasser. In an environment that applauds young people’s involvement in public policy, an ideological conflict occurred between Nasser and Abdallah. “Nasser wanted to benefit from me as an economist, while fighting me as a communist, so I ended up most of the time, either in a position of power in the government or as a political prisoner,” Abdallah stated. He was the head of the Economic and Financial Division at the Economic Development Organization (EDO) at the time of the implementation of the nationalization policies, and he chose to introduce us to the narrative Egypt’s industrialization by focusing on the human factor behind such policies. Who were the economists, engineers, industrialists and policy makers behind 5 Egypt’s industrialization and nationalization policies and how did they function? This is the focus of this article, which is extracted form a series of interviews with Abdallah. Data collection and research that the policy makers and economic planners undertake are significant to their decision-making. Abdallah was the economic authority inside the EDO, which was responsible for administering the nationalization process. It is interesting to note that Abdallah, one of Egypt’s prominent economic planners, shaped his understanding of the status of Egypt’s economic position through studying the companies that were involved in the process of nationalization. The EDO was established in 1957, after the Suez war, to administer the Egyptianization and nationalization process. Through the EDO, Abdallah was able to establish a system of data collection from the companies that were considered for nationalization, which became a significant source of information on Egypt's economic status. According to Abdallah they used to study all the conditions surrounding the companies and the companies themselves were the source of information. They implemented a proficient system of studying the companies through promoting a new method of preparing the companies' annual reports - adding new information on the sector that the company belonged to and its relation to other sectors. Information on the company's competitors, its market share, other companies' market share and labor information were also added. This was done through sending a team of economists who used to spend 15-30 days to train employees in the extraction and recording of such information. The importance of such endeavor is that it provided a unique opportunity for Abdallah and his team to study the various sectors in the Egyptian economy, the position and status of each sector and the key companies within them. In addition, it highlighted the relationship between the Egyptian economy and foreign companies. It is worth noting that according to Abdallah, a company such as al-Bayda was very significant in the textile sector. It was beneficial to other textile companies since it introduced to the market some essential feeding industries, such as the dying industry. Through EDO data collection efforts, it was possible to understand inter-company relations and to obtain a clearer picture of industry in Egypt. Moreover, it demonstrated the relationship between the various industries and service sectors such as transportation. The story behind the EDO and its data “...Nasser, Abdallah stated, was from a rural background and was convinced that agriculture alone will not solve Egypt's poverty...” FROM OUR ARCHIVES collection mechanism is significant in understanding how the economists responsible for nationalization formulated their knowledge of the Egyptian economy that consequently shaped the decision making process. The nationalization of the early 1960s is a key event in the economic history of modern Egypt and a central feature in the country’s path to industrialization. Nevertheless, the controversy concer ning its appropriateness is huge and beyond the scope of this piece. However what is worth highlighting is the perception of those who were responsible for this policy. According to Abdallah, the process took two major turns. The first stage of nationalization was dominated by an understanding that only foreign companies [viz. European or American] with key economic positions are to be seized. As an example, the famous Shamla department stores did not fall in the nationalization grip given their origins as Tunisian jews, in spite of the fact that its owners held French citizenships. On the other hand, the insurance companies that were under foreign control were nationalized due to their power as major saving and investment agents. The EDO, according to Abdallah was concerned with the companies that had a downstream or upstream multiplier effect. He added that mistakes occurred in the nationalization of the publishing sector and other small sectors were due to the fact that some ministers and others bought many of the foreign establishments that were under custody. As Abdallah reiterated, the EDO was not a holding company but a developmental agency, since it used some of its resources to establish new companies and study the surrounding conditions thoroughly to ensure their continuity and success. It is futile to approach the policies of the State control era without touching upon Nasser's policy- making strategies. Being a consultant for Nasser during this era, Abdallah unveils some of Nasser's perceptions. Nasser, Abdallah stated, was from a rural background and was convinced that agriculture alone will not solve Egypt's poverty. It would neither attain its own developmental goals nor create employment opportunities for the masses. He argued that the high dam was first conceived as a tool for land reclamation that would increase Egypt's agricultural capabilities, contrary to the widespread belief that it was established solely to produce electricity that was crucial for “... the high dam was first conceived as a tool for land reclamation that would increase Egypt's agriculture capabilities...” industrialization. The original conception was based on the hope that the dam would fulfill the hopes of the smallest of peasants by availing three fiddans of agricultural land to each of them. Nasser's background as described by Abdallah made him con cerned with the agricultural laborers commonly referred to as 'umal altarahil, who are transported from one piece of land to another to work on a haphazard seasonal manner with very low day by day wages. Abdallah stated that such laborers were one of the reasons that made Nasser consider the industrialization option as a solution to Egypt's developmental problems. He further stated that this shift to industrialization was not based on ideological or theoretical grounds, but on Nasser's understanding of the reality of challenges facing Egypt. This shift materialized when Aziz Sidqi established the Ministry of Industry and commenced the first industrialization plan 1958. Abdallah claimed that Nasser believed in a trial and error as the approach by which indigenous Egyptian calibers would drive the country. Thus, Nasser advocated free education to give Egyptians an opportunity to enhance their capabilities. An obvious move towards industrialization took place in the 1950s and among its major contributors were a group of military engineers. Those engineers were the ones who proposed the establishment of military industries during Farouk's era and visited various European industrial complexes and studied business administration and other critical disciplines, which made them qualified to contribute to the industrialization effort. Among those engineers are Sidqi Soliman who supervised the establishment of the high dam and Moahmed Younis who headed the Suez Canal Company. At the same time, Nasser depended on academicians such as Aziz Sidqi and Mostafa Khalil to lead the industrialization endeavor. Prior to what Abdallah called “serious industrialization” by the Egyptian engineers and academicians, the situation was one he characterized as a collage of haphazard initiatives of "venture capital." The success stories were initiatives that mirrored the already successful sectors, such as the textile industry. As for the military engineers or the new industrialists, they chose the iron and steel industry as their starting point. From an engineering perspective, this was a typical starting point for countries in earlier stage of industrialization given their interest in ensuring adequate supplies of basic raw materials that are necessary inputs for establishing industry. This, according to Adballah, was not always economically efficient. It would have been best, for example, to import raw iron rather than manufacturing it given its low share in the final product. The material outlook that the engineers held in their undertaking of the industrial project lacked efficiency considerations, essential as they are from an economic perspective. Abdallah insisted that Nasser's policy and the environment in which the revolution's policies were formulated were mostly not ideologically based nor were they an attempt to copy other countries' models. Abdallah tried to explain some of the intellectual and human factors that accompanied Egypt's industrial experience. He added that more attention should be paid to the role of the military engineers when studying Egypt's industrialization, especially that they performed a remarkable job in operating the Suez Canal Company after nationalization. The nationalization of the Suez Canal, he explained, was not a decision taken on the spurt of the moment, but required a close study for two years by three committees. Abdallah acknowledged the problems that Nasser's policies bore, namely the mammoth bureaucratic system and lack of freedom of expression. He concluded that Nasser's experience was a very unique one and what Egypt needs now is democracy, which is the only guarantee for sustainable development. ISMAIL SABRI ABDALLAH headed the Economic and Financial Division of the Economic Development Organization (EDO) in 1957. He was the General Director of the Institute of National Planning (19691977) and the Minister of Planning (19711975). He is currently the Chairman of the Third World Forum. 6 FROM OUR ARCHIVES In November 2005 the Economic & Business History Research Center held a panel entitled “New Approaches in Business History” at the Middle East Studies Association [MESA] Conference in Washington DC. The following is an excerpt of “On Business History”, one of four papers presented dur ing the session. In the excerpt the center’s oral history methodology is considered before selection of the center’s oral history archive is surveyed with the aim of demonstrating the possibilities of using this type of oral record in the writing of history. & Digital Recordings The Apparatus of Economic & Business History Research Center Mostafa Hefny, Project Officer, EBHRC. The Modus Operandi Prior to its official establishment, EBHRC’s director assigned some his students and former students at the American University in Cairo the task of reviewing the available literature on Business History, which, at that point, was assumed to be a discipline whose tenants could be examined for application in an Egyptian context. An intensive three-day seminar was held on the subject. It quickly became clear that what had started as a question about the applicability of the pillars of business history for our purposes became a search for those very pillars. We started out questioning whether business history could travel from its bases in 20th century United States and Western Europe only to find that the discipline had disintegrated prior to takeoff. Business history maybe defined as a nexus of variably incorporated social sciences bound by demonstrable behavior of economic actors in history. Business history failed to provide EBHRC with a theoretical framework with which to proceed. The absence of a framework is far from a crippling impediment to practice. Indeed it is the docility of the field of business history, and the variability of the material presented under its auspices, that enabled the center to proceed with 7 the task of chronicling 20th century political economy of Egypt through the history of enterprise and governance in a way that best suited the prevailing conditions. In this way business history released the center from the ivory tower to which many historians remain confined. Ground level turned out to be a fine place to start. Hence the method of oral history. As a mainstay of anthropological practice, oral history’s considerable tradition is more inclined towards service to that social science. It remains nonetheless, in the parlance of another social science, fungible; a method to be molded and remolded. The anthropologist's fingerprints are however unambiguously betrayed in the considerable literature on the method and technique of oral history. Consider The Voice of the Past: Oral History by Paul Thompson, a complete textbook. Marrying a procedural approach with an argumentative one, and therefore raising the discussion above the merely technical, the author offers a highly readable work that provides instruction to the collector of oral accounts whilst making an argument in favor of oral history as a valuable medium. In doing this, however, he betrays an ideological presumption that limits the use of the apparatus for the center. For Thompson, an oral historian himself, the technique of oral history is first a democratizing process that gives voice to the marginalized and inarticulate; a counter-history through which a stance that is a priori established as antithetical to a prevailing history is put forth. Of this way of thinking arise two immediate implications: First, the venerable egalitarianism that motivates the seeking of the accounts of the marginalized and inarticulate will inevitably aggregate said accounts in what would amount to a community history. Second, the assumption that oral history provides a "counter-history" is embedded with the assumption that a history to which the aggregated voices are contrasted already exists. For EBHRC, working in the mostly unsullied field of Egyptian business history this primary protagonist, the anti-hero against which oral historians seem to rally, simply did not exist. Although the accounts obtained by the center frequently clash with official stories and popular myths, the disorderly state of those stories and myths makes disqualifies them from any mandate over what can authoritatively be identified as the mainstream. The center's accounts, because of novelty of the field, will inevitably be central to any discussion of Egyptian business history. For EBHRC, the interviews were never going to be method to amass an alternative history. FROM OUR ARCHIVES In the literature of oral history one finds allusions to the unique suitability of oral history to the countries of the South where it is claimed that oral tradition has been more thoroughly embraced because of the absence of institutions that provide raw material for more traditional, i.e. written histories. Here are tentacles of a West-East clash: does this development of a well meaning blanket method for the "South" not carry the assumption that there are no traditionally decipherable institutions in a country such as Egypt? Or is it, in counterpoint, in fact a call for historians working in Egypt to explore unique, local, methodologies of which oral history is a mere example? The clash is a false one. At EBHRC the incongruity of the oral history methodologies proposed by the literature was due more to the implicit purposes of the process rather than where and by whom it was developed. It was indeed the western institution of Columbia University and the system it had devised that added the most to the EBHRC's intuitively devised oral history apparatus, of which an overview is now in order. Egypt remains without a tradition of free access to document. Oral accounts are not without their objective advantages over written documents, but this is a case where talking to the decision makers, administrators and entrepreneurs was less a matter of preference than an imposition by circumstance. The narratives of Egypt's industrial and entrepreneurial experience are absent from the written records. Those interviewees are therefore the guardians of a history that has never been made available to scholars, let alone the public. Specialized as they often are, many remain innocent of the historical value of their experiences. A coherent synthesis of the testimony of officials, bureaucrats, administrators and businessmen is a prism through which an historical perspective will almost certainly be entirely original. Then there is the quandary of time. Oral history maybe richer source material than accessible written documents but its sources are human - and mortal. It is a delicate but unavoidable fact that the guardians of precious accounts of economic and business endeavors are in many cases in the twilight of their lives. An invaluable history of Egypt may perish with these men. Indeed for an administrator or worker to have been substantively involved in the immense flux of resource allocation that characterized the state-led industrialization of the early 1960s, a decisive span in the economic history of Egypt, that person would likely have been, at least, in his thirties. This in turn makes potential purveyors of first hand experiences of that important time a group with a minimum age of seventy. The connotation of this elementary observation is not limited to the need for urgency. That much is obvious. What had concerned us at EBHRC was what this rush to interview those most likely not to be available for testimony in a few years would do as far as the cohesiveness of the center's output was concerned: If the most important criterion for choosing a subject becomes their age this would demote other considerations such as sectoral analysis and other unifying themes to a secondary status. This fear however proved to be unsubstantiated as the interviewees themselves proved the greatest source for other potential oral history subjects who, in many cases, traveled in similar circles, worked in the same sectors and were of a similar age. “...In contrast to military service in Latin America, a necessary stage in the life of young aristocratic heir, the Egyptian army was shunned by the landowning elites and embraced by classes who would otherwise have had no access to education...” As interviews continued in the fall of 2004, an apparatus started to take shape. The lear ning-by-doing approach continued, but experience had refined the apparatus to include an initial meeting with the subject in which a free flow of memory was encouraged with the subject having been made aware of the framework of inquiry which, in turn, had been refined to addressing the relationship of finance and Egyptian industry. The interviewers would listen to a recording of the initial session and formulate a series of questions that connects the subjects’ experience with the framework of inquiry. This procedure governed the reminiscences to the general topic without unnecessarily curtailing potentially valuable information that had not been targeted beforehand by the interviewers. The apparatus was taking shape. Yet as more and more interviews were recorded there were fresh concerns about the final form this labor would take. Here we entered into the perilous realm of the transcript – the bête noire of the EBHRC project officer. "People," writes one commentator on oral history, "do not usually speak in paragraphs"(1) . We are well advised in the literature on oral history of the dangers of distorting the intonations and meanings of the oral record during the process of transcription, a process that is described by this commentator as one of temptation and decadence. (2) No one at EBHRC ever courted such temptations. The center's first attempt at transcription was scrupulous in its fidelity to the recorded interview inasmuch as it was a verbatim transfer of the record to paper. The interview, conducted over five sessions was with Eng. Mohammad Abdel-W ahab, Egypt's Minister of Industry from 1984 to 1993 - a period through which he was involved in protracted negotiations with the International Monetary Fund over the form of Egypt's adoption of its structural adjustment program. The fullness of the account was such that EBHRC later developed a workshop during its annual May forum devoted entirely to issues raised by the interview. Yet none of this was evident in the ad verbatim transcript. In fact if one were to successfully wade through the colloquial Arabic of that first document one would more likely be left with scatterings of meaning barely decipherable to a native speaker who had heard the oral recordings. The prospects of this document being of use to researchers outside EBHRC looked bleak. 8 FROM OUR ARCHIVES It is a matter of language. Written (fusha aka classical) and spoken Arabic in Egypt are drastically different. The language of Egyptian dailies and popular fiction does integrate colloquialisms, but the amalgam tilts strongly in favor of the written Arabic and is weighted arbitrarily by the writer. Surprisingly, the solution to this local, culturally specific problem was inspired by the oral history tradition of an institution that, as far as we know, has never collected an account in Arabic. In January of 2005, the center's director visited Columbia University's Oral History Research Office, an important institution in the practice of oral history. The crux of the Columbia method is the centrality of the final, written transcript. The oral recording is secondary. Columbia enables the interviewees to amend a transcript of their documents, to add, edit and delay the publication “...The oral history, as conducted by EBHRC may be validly critiqued as a top-down history inasmuch as those interviewed are persons nearer the center of things, but any history written on the basis of these accounts will be history written with the building blocks intact - a history written from the ground up. ...” 9 of its contents. This empowering of the interviewees makes the final written transcript the definitive document that is later made available for researchers. This was a watershed moment of sorts. The fact that interviewees review and sign off on the final transcript meant that the final transcript could be written in fusha and the ideas sorted and clarified. For all the loss of inflection and tone justifiably predicted by critics of this method – even when editing is reduced to a utilitarian minimum, the presentation of a written transcript to the interviewee has proved to be an incredibly rewarding step. More than just providing space for an editing and expansion of their comments, some of the people interviewed were moved to see their stories treated as text; as historical documents. The transcripts enable the interviewees to see the fruits of the sessions and the goals of the interviewer. A transcript, which is presented to the subject after the first session, helps guide subsequent sessions – the process of transcription crystallizes, to the interviewers and the interviewee, what issues raised in the initial meeting would be worthwhile to pursue further. Most important however is the increased level of trust that interviewees feel towards the entire process once its fruits are laid before them. Oral history is, in part, the black market that develops when the ceiling on access is set below the standards of scholarship, which has sullied its reputation somewhat; as a last resort, a poor man's history. This is a trivial reading of the method. Whether it provides the central pathway to political, economic and business institutions of a country, as it does in EBHRC's primary oral history project, or it serves as an alternative mode, this is a method with unique scope. One need only consider the question of externalities, patronage and other unofficial – if not under ground- dealings to see but one example of this scope. In their recent work on the development of the Cairo suburb of Heliopolis early in 20th century, Dina Khalifa and Lina Attallah link the preponderance of Bedouins working as security guards and janitors in the neighborhood to a promise made by the Belgian industrialist, Baron Edouard Empain, to the Bedouns of jobs in return for their land. Of this deal there are no official records save the testimony the authors were able to extract. The usage of the method may be enforced by circumstance – but this adaptation to the realities of working in Egypt has led to one whose advantages are not limited to evasion of authoritarian constraints on academic research. Indeed its principle advantage as a method designed for the landscape in which it is put to use is that it prompts a reappraisal of socalled universal practices that may have otherwise been awkwar dly employed. Contrasts and Intersections Oral history, when conducted as part of a project larger than the subject interviewed, becomes a study of contrasts. Crucially, in the oral history that is the primary activity of EBHRC, and in profound distinction from history written about a particular institution, the building blocks of history, the life stories of the interviewees, exist independently as intact historical documents uninjured by editing for an a priori established objective. The overarching goal maybe the chronicling of economic and business history of Egypt, but in no way should such a goal segregate the professional experience of interviewees from the rest of their makeup. A life history must, and indeed does, cover the life and times of an individual. Once that record is extracted intact, we may then subject it to all manner of critique and contrast with press clippings and lesser discourses. It is not that an oral history in the form of a life history is necessarily a complete or exceptionally truthful document – but it must be, within the parameters set by the life history format – whole before it is put to a service of a more narrowly defined objective. The oral history, as conducted by EBHRC may be validly critiqued as a top-down history inasmuch as those interviewed are persons nearer the center of things, but any history written on the basis of these accounts will be history written with the building blocks intact - a history written from the ground up. Now we return to the records in the center's archive. Each had been extracted independently – a fact that makes contrast more meaningful, and overlaps more noteworthy. Surveying the records one is struck by overlaps in the accounts – the contrasting perspectives and overlapping experiences of some of the major figures in the modern economic history of Egypt. A brief tour of a selection of oral history records demonstrates the possibilities of how the overlap maybe used to construct a history. FROM OUR ARCHIVES Consider, as a point of departure, the narrative of Mohammad AbdelWahab, whose association with the Egyptian industrial experience spans a period of fifty years from his appointment as an engineer in military factory no. 54 to up until 1993 when his nineyear tenure as Egypt's Minster of Industry came to an end. AbdelWahab described a nation's industrialization that began within the army barracks where a clear dedication to independent innovation led to the manufacture a wholly Egyptian rifle license for which was then sold to Iraq in 1959. For Abdel-Wahab the transfer of military industries to the civilian Ministry of Industry in 1967 was a severe blow to sector previously dedicated to developing an integrated industrial base. The political considerations and unfocused vision led to a public sector becoming a misshapen apparatus that was gravely overstaffed and under employed. Remedially, Abdel-Wahab was one of the architects of Law no. 203 of 1991 designed to place an "iron curtain" between the government, with its inefficient administrative apparatus, and the public sector so that latter could "go as private" without having to be actually sold. This rehabilitation of the public sector he hoped would save it from the World Bank's incessant pressure to liquidate. Muhammad Abdel-Wahab briefly headed Al-Nasr Automotive Company (1983 – 1984). Adel Gazarin, also an engineer, who was at the helm of that emblematic institution from 1968 to the early 1980s seconded Abdel-Wahab's charge that the administration of the Egyptian public sector was politically distorted. For Gazarin, the automotive industry was an illustration of a whole industrial process that was wrongly aimed at complete import substitution. He was particularly critical of the famous Nasserist era claim that Egypt would eventually build everything from "the needle to the rocket" which he felt led to politically motivated investment which valued the symbolic above the practical and the politically saleable above the economically efficient – which at Al-Nasr Automotive was mani fested in the bias towards passenger cars. Though an advocate of the private sector, Gezarin refused to support the so-called "Open Door Policy" instituted by President Anwar El-Sadat in 1974 – there he saw no sign of a framework in which the private sector could play a role in industrialization - then relegated to a secondary role in favor of more commercial activities. In the 1970s “...In the literature of oral history one finds allusions to the unique suitability of oral history to the countries of the South where it is claimed that oral tradition has been more thoroughly embraced because of the absence of institutions that provide raw material for more traditional...” there was little evidence of strategy for industrialization. Mohamad Elwi Taymour, chairman of EFG-Hermes, Egypt's leading fund and portfolio company and investment bank shared Gazarin's disenchantment with the politicization of public sector administration in the 1960s. Taymour had also passed through Al-Nasr Automotive Company. His stay there was brief, but the effect it had on him was decisive. An eager young graduate in 1963, Taymour pressed his brother in law, the influential nationalist writer Mohamad Hassanien Hiekal to have him placed at Al-Nasr, then a symbol of the nation's industrial birth. He was critical of what he described as a rampant predilection towards political rather than economic or technical considerations in production. He cited one incident where the factory's painting apparatus was permanently damaged because of an order to spray the sheet metal in spite of the fact that the chemical components of the paint had yet to arrive from Italy. The administrators, in lieu of a visit by a Belgian industrial expert to the factory, ordered Taymour to run the apparatus with substitute chemicals that would give the impression of a functioning spraying mechanism – he followed the order and an entire line of sheet metal was lost. Disillusioned, he left the company and the country. After spending time in the United States and the Arabian Gulf, Taymour returned to Egypt in the early 1980s armed with an extensive experience in fund management - there he set up a financial analysis and intermediation company whose influence rose steadily as economic transformation of Egypt towards a market oriented economy became de rigueur. His firm received numerous commissions to study the mechanisms of capitalist transformation including privatization. This was a process to which successive governments of Egypt in the 1980s and 90s were never commited, preferring postponement to confrontation at any price. Never more so, in Taymour's view, then in the government's wasteful defense of the Egyptian Pound, justifiable only as political denial of an economic pressure that the government never sought to alleviate. The government's protection of the Pound contended Fouad Sultan was a grave error illustrative of an administration forcibly pressed to implement an economic liberalization in which they never believed. Sultan, who was always a firm believer in, and persistent advocate of, economic liberalism, was the surprise member of cabinet as Minister of Tourism and Civil Aviation from 1985 to 1993 when he was brought over from a career in banking at the National Bank of Egypt and the International Monetary Fund to head what he was told was the "least distorted sector in the Egyptian economy." Sultan had been allowed to write in advocacy of economic liberalism in the state owned press at the dawn of Anwar El-Sadat's presidency. He was writing from his turf in the Yemen where he was the IMF representative at the Central Bank of Yemen. His inclusion in the same cabinet as Mohammad Abdel-Wahab, over roughly the same time span, suggests a level political disorder that bordered on the chaotic. Whilst Abdel-Wahab was attempting to rehabilitate the public sector, he was advocating its dismantlement. Sultan claims that the cabinet never held general policy meetings and that he proceeded to privatize several hotels not as part of an organized policy, but simply because he was never questioned about his decision to do so. 10 FROM OUR ARCHIVES “...Abdel-Wahab was one of the architects of Law no. 203 of 1991 designed to place an "iron curtain" between the government, with its inefficient administrative apparatus, and the public sector so that the latter could "go as private" without having to be actually sold. This rehabilitation of the public sector he hoped would save it from the World Bank's incessant pressure to liquidate. ...” The great discrepancy in policy on part of government, and the regime responsible for its appointment, was, to Sultan -who claims to be an apolitical advocate of economic liberalism who was never interested in political liberalism - a simple failure of will. The contradictions could bare no political reading. The economist Heba Handousa did offer a political reading. Sultan, she contended, was a test case by the regime. His appointment to lead a sector that Sultan himself conceded was relatively undistorted by public administration was, in part, a signal of intent. Sultan would also bear the brunt of public criticism should the inclination 11 towards a market orientation be greeted with hostility. Indeed a review of the press from 1985 to 1993 reveals that the Minister of Tourism and Aviation had indeed become a hate figure for all those suspicious of the government's stated aims of economic liberalization. The reaction to Sultan may have resulted in what Mohamad Taymour described as a paralysis of a government unable, or unwilling, to pay the political cost of full capitalist transformation. Taymour likened the Egyptian government policy in the 1990s to an aloof man sitting in bathtub where the temperature is rising incrementally – one moment is never drastically worse than what had come before. In the end the man finds himself burned all the same. The politicization of industrialization was never in question for another economist, the remarkable Ismail Sabri Abdullah. Abdullah currently chairs the Third World Forum and is widely regarded, across the ideological spectrum, as one of the country's foremost intellectuals. It is in this capacity, as an expert, that he sought to participate in the oral history project. His reluctance to delve into an extensive autobiography could not curtail interest in his own journey: In the post-revolutionary era of the 1950s, Abdullah, then a left wing activist, was subjected to severe intimidation and frequent arrest – subjugation that was curiously and intermittently interrupted by Abdullah providing professional advice on development and industrialization to Gamal AbdelNasser, in person. In between non-judicially sanctioned prison terms Abdullah headed the Economic and Financial Division of the Economic Development Organization (EDO) in 1957, which, at the time, was the principle planning apparatus of the regime and was responsible of surveying the economy and collecting information – a pre-requisite for considered central planning. Abdullah had seen in the Egyptian military a progressive class that was committed to transforming the country and in doing so transform the coup of 1952 into a revolution. In contrast to military service in Latin America, a necessary stage in the life of young aristocratic heir, the Egyptian army was shunned by the landowning elites and embraced by classes who would otherwise have had no access to education. It was a core of military engineers who first led the move towards the industrialization of Egypt. For Abdullah, Gamal AbdelNasser was a deeply pragmatic leader. He strong- ly refuted the popularly held belief that the nationalization of the Suez Canal was an emotional act fueled by nationalistic fervor. There were three separate committees convened well before the decision was finally made to consider the technical, legal and financial ramifications of nationalization. In contrast, the rule of Anwar ElSadat, wherein Abdullah was generally spared prison and appointed as Minister of Planning besides – from 1971 to 1975, when he resigned – there was a great ideological drive to dismantle, starve of funds and atrophy the public sector. It was an overwhelmingly negative policy designed to tear down public enterprise without providing an alternative strategy for industrialization – a capitalism that, with the demise of the pre-revolutionary bourgeoisie, was to be built without capitalists. 1. Samuel, Raphael. "Perils of the transcript." in The Oral History Reader, edited by Robert Perks and Alistair Thomson, London ; New York : Routledge, 1998: P 389 2. Ibid. MESA PANEL—NOVEMBER 20, 2006 Egyptian Business History: New Sources, New Methods and New Directions in Research Organized by Roger Owen, Harvard University Chair: Roger Owen, Harvard University Discussant: AbdelAziz EzzelArab, American University in Cairo Robert J. Vitalis, University of Pennsylvania Captive Narratives: On the History of Firms and States in the Middle East (and Beyond) Karim Mostafa El-Sayed and Dina Waked, American University in Cairo Café Riche: In Pursuit of a NonQuantitative Business Model: Implications of Macro Changes for Small Eateries in Downtown Cairo Dina Khalifa Hussein and Lina Atallah, American University in Cairo A Brave New City! Heliopolis: Place, Business and People Mostafa Hany Hefny, American University in Cairo The Business History Voyager: Revisiting Western Methods in the Light of Oral History Accounts of Egypt's Industrial Experience INTERVIEW When Firms and Entrepreneurs Cross Borders Professor Geoffrey Jones Shares his Experience with Business History Dina Khalifa Hussein, Project Officer, EBHRC n Cambridge, Massachusetts stands one of the most prestigious universities in the United States and the world today. Harvard Business School (HBS) poses in glamour as one of Harvard’s most sought after schools. If the American empire today rests on business foundation, then definitely the Harvard MBA graduates are its future leaders. An interview with Professor Geoffrey Jones, one of the most prominent scholars of business history, unveils puzzling questions in the field. Due to his generous invitation, we sat for an hour in his office in HBS last November and explored various questions such as: what is business history? What are the big questions posed through business history? What is the impact of multinationals on host countries? How does studying business history change the outlook of MBA students and business practitioners? These are only few questions that came up in a rich interview that manifests scholars’ endeavors of understanding the world, in this case, through looking closer at business entities and entrepreneurs who cross borders, impact cultures, and create markets that shape the world’s economic map. I EBHRC crew: Could you give us an overview of your encounter with business history and your intellectual development? Prof. Jones: Cambridge University: Government and Industry I started in Cambridge in the history department, where business history was taught in the context of economic history, and history more generally. It was there that I first encountered the work of Mira Wilkins on international business. I had begun my doctoral research on the topic of the history of the oil industry. A former head of British naval intelligence told me that there was a very interesting story about the British government and its creation of the national oil company, which we now call British Petroleum (BP). He was thinking that I would look at it from a political point of view. I actually got more interested in the companies themselves. So my initial work in business history was focused on issues surrounding the relationship between government and industry. I remain interested in this research area, although it has not been the focus of my work for a long time. Government is very important in business, so you cannot really get a sense of business history, without talking about governments. London School of Economics: Comparative Studies and Multinationals After some years at Cambridge, I decided to move to London School of Economics (LSE), where a new unit had been established to study business history, funded primarily by business. At LSE my interest in comparative studies grew because I had to teach a course on the economic history of Russia, India and Japan. This made me think of the role of entrepreneurs and investment flows across borders, and this has been an important theme in my work. At LSE I transitioned from oil to thinking more generally about why companies in all industries crossed borders, and their impact. I did my first work on multinational companies at this time. I also undertook my first commissioned company history, when HSBC asked me to write a study of the history of their affiliate The British Bank of the Middle East, which had originated as the Imperial Bank of Persia. The resulting two-volume study enabled me to go deep inside the history of a banking institution, as I was given privileged access to that bank’s confidential archives. University of Reading: Conceptual Thinking In the late 1980s I moved to the University of Reading’s Economics Department, then as now a leading world center for the study of the multinational enterprise. I experienced a different set of intellectual influences. Suddenly, I had no students who had the remotest interest in history, so I was obliged to consider new ways of teaching business history. I developed a whole new course on the history of international businesses. I started to explore ways of moving in the classroom between past historical experiences and the present day concerns of students in economics and management. The intellectual environment at Reading had a significant impact on my work. It has a long tradition and strength in international business, and a cluster of economists who focused on transaction cost 12 INTERVIEW economics. The group included Mark Casson, a pioneer in applying transaction cost economics to studying multinationals, and who later wrote an outstanding book on the economic theory of the entrepreneur. So, within this environment, my work started to become more conceptual, even if it remained fundamentally Chandlerian in its empirical nature. I became more inclined to search for generalizations and general patterns in the evolution of business. It was in this environment that I turned my detailed study of one bank into a general study of British multinational banking over 150 years. In the resulting book, British Multinational Banking 1830-1990, published in 1993, I used a variety of theoretical concepts including, transaction cost and agency theory to try to understand historical patterns. At Reading, I also organized a series of conferences, where I put together theorists and historians. The aim was to encourage the historians to stand away from individual details towards searching for more general pictures. I also wanted to challenge theorists to look at what actually happened, and the contingency of what did happen in the specific environments. I held conferences on branding and marketing, multinational banking and international trading, all of which followed this format. I developed a pattern in which I organized such a conference, which would invariably be inter nationally comparative and include theorists, and I would then go on to write a monograph, which used these insights to understand the evolution of a set of business institutions, such as trading companies, over time. Unilever Over the years my research had shifted from oil to manufacturing companies, and then to banks and trading companies. My research on the latter culminated in my Merchants to Multinationals book, published in 2000. The Anglo-Dutch consumer products company Unilever happened to own one of Africa’s largest trading companies, and by co-incidence as I was exploring their history, I was approached by Unilever to undertake a history of their company from the 1960s. This project, which resulted in my Renewing Unilever book published in 2005, introduced me to many issues, which had not featured highly in my previous work. It took me to corporate culture and issues of human resource management, and to questions such 13 as why women could not rise up the hierarchies of this type of large companies. Moreover, the Unilever history made me think more systematically about organization and information flows within companies. All these issues definitely expanded my own research agenda. Today they feature highly in my on-going research agenda. “... Government is very important in business, so you cannot really get a sense of business history, without talking about governments...” Harvard Business School: MBA students, business history and the beauty book Towards the end of the 1990s, I received a call inviting me to visit HBS. After two years as a visitor, I accepted a permanent appointment in 2002. At HBS, you are faced with a different teaching and writing challenge; how to transmit complex historical processes to MBA students and to business practitioners? This challenge has had a major impact on my work. In 2005 I published a wholly revised version of my survey of the history of international business, published originally as the The Evolution of International Business (1996). The new book, Multinationals and Global Capitalism, shows many of the changes in my approach which have resulted in my sojourn at HBS. It makes more intensive use of concepts, and it is more global in its outlook. I have written new chapters on the organization of firms. Finally, there are also multiple mini case studies scattered around the text, reflecting the use of the case method at HBS. My job at HBS has also opened up a new set of research opportunities. This is primarily because HBS is uniquely well connected in the global business community. As a result, it is possible to access executives and companies in ways which are not replicable at other institutions. I am now writing a book on globalization and the beauty industry: The idea of such a book originated through my work on Unilever. Unilever began to consider diversifying from its traditional soap and margarine business into personal care from the 1950s, although it was only in the 1980s that a series of acquisitions made this wish a reality. In studying Unilever’s strategy, I discovered how little serious business literature existed in the beauty industry, as well as its extraordinary growth and size after World War 2. HBS is proving an idea base to undertake work on the beauty industry. I have already done two HBS cases on the French beauty company, L’Oréal and Shiseido, the Japanese beauty company. In both cases senior executives of those firms have collaborated closely with me. I hope in time to write a book on this global industry since 1945. In most of my previous research, I was trying to understand the why question, why do companies go international? Then I spent quite a bit of time on the how question, how did they organize themselves? While exploring this issue, it was brought home to me that while the U.S. has been frequently used as the benchmark for organizational effectiveness, historically there have been multiple ways in which firms organized themselves, some of which worked extremely efficiently on quite ‘unAmerican’ lines. During my Unilever research, I really started to think about the impact of firms crossing borders, and the globalization process more generally. With the book on the beauty industry, I am going to look at how an industry moved from being highly fragmented, locally and culturally based, into a global business with a few large global players. I am going to look at what that means for culture and society, people’s senses and personal identities. In addition, I am going to study entrepreneurial reactions from companies based in developing countries. Thus I will not only focus on large western or Japanese companies globalizing, but on how Brazilian, Thai or Chinese firms responded to that, and how they have developed their own competitive advantage. Can they survive or do global giants wipe them out? In the longer term, I want to write a study of how much global firms have contributed to the patterns of global wealth and poverty that we have seen over the last 100-150 years. Thus, my focus and interest is heading towards the question of “impact” of the companies. INTERVIEW EBHRC Crew: Was it generally the case that business history developed through historians rather than business studies academicians? Prof. Jones: Yes, this is usually the case. Fundamentally, business history confronts historical evidence and in doing so, it is important to have professional skills and understanding of historical material and approaches. I think business historians should be good historians. But, I would add that business historians will only make an impact if they also conceptualize and generalize. That is why I admire Alfred Chandler’s work so much. He asks big questions, such as what is the relationship between strategy and structure or why do firms grow, and he provides big answers. They can sometimes be contested, but they move the debate on enormously.Therefore, I do not think the future of business history is to collect more and more data on individual institutions. Such research is of course an essential building block, but business historians need to use that information to ask big questions. EBHRC crew: Does the type of question then differ from a business historian who has a history background to one who has an economics or business background? Prof. Jones: Actually, it depends on the business historian himself. I can think of business historians trained as historians who now use standard social science methodologies, employ the assumptions of neo-classical economics, and exploit large data sets. I can think of people trained as economists who write historical narratives of the most traditional kind. In other words, pr ofessional training is not a once for all experience. However there are certainly many methodological tensions within the discipline. There is a big difference between a social science methodology, which seeks to test theories on empirical historical facts, and the classic historical methodology, which starts by looking at the evidence and tries to generalize from it. Issues of Methodology The problem of social sciences is that it has a methodology that is rather restrictive in nature. Historical methodology is more similar to natural sciences such as astrology and geology in the sense that it is better able to deal with highly complex situations in a world that is more complicated than a one in which the use of multiple regressions can help us understand things. In the real world, chaos, uncertainty and complexity drive events. We need methodologies which can understand this, not assume them away. I have tried to put forward some of these ideas in a forthcoming article entitled, “Bringing (History) Back into International Business,” in the Journal of International Business Studies, co-authored by HBS colleague Tarun Khanna, an economist by training. “... I will not only focus on large western or Japanese companies globalizing, but on how Brazilian, Thai or Chinese firms responded to that, and how they have developed their own competitive advantage. Can they survive or do global giants wipe them out?...” In general I think there are many opportunities for the research of business historians to reach wider audiences. There has never been a time when social scientists have talked more often that ‘history matters’. The job of business historians and historians generally is to publish research to show why it matters. The problem with much business history at the moment is that the books are too long, too complex and often not focused on a particular issue. There is invaluable empirical research which explores why entrepreneurs succeed, why they came from some countries and not others, and so on, but it is written in such an inaccessible form that even a professional like me cannot really draw out general patterns. EBHRC crew: Since you are currently teaching business history to MBA students, what will business history contribute to the business practitioners? Prof. Jones: As I begin the course, I tell the students that business history is not a course where they get a set of tools that is going to make them rich. It is a course that would change their outlook. My course is on global business history. Many MBA students have no idea that the world has globalized in the 19th century, and then this global world fell apart and is only being restored over recent decades. The course challenges students to appreciate that things change. Globalization was not a linear process. Improved communications and transport were no guarantee of continuous globalization. In turn, the course challenges the students to consider if the present global economy might collapse in due course, and to use history for signs. What is going on now that would signal a reaction to globalization? The students come to realize that reactions to globalization occur because there are more losers than winners. As future business leaders, they need to make fewer losers and more winners in the global economy. The course highlights the importance of ethics in business decisions, and the complexity of making ethical judgments. There is a case on multinationals in South Africa during apartheid. We look at four such companies, two which divested and two which remained, and look at both the ethical and commercial implications of their decisions. During class we discuss the difficult issue concerning how evil a government or regime must be before a firm takes the decision to divest, and whether such divestment helps or hinders the people of a country living under an awful political regime. Looking at very concrete historical evidence brings to the attention of our future business leaders such issues in a highly concrete and vivid fashion. EBHRC Crew: Since you are interested in the impact question and contextualization of business history, there have been views on the separation of the private and public spheres of business history. Is business history apolitical? What do you think of the justification to copy business models in any country, under the banner of economic liberalization? Prof. Jones: Business history provides much evidence on the disastrous consequences of transferring management systems from one country to another. 14 INTERVIEW There is rich literature on the difficulties of transferring American management techniques in Europe after World War 2. Management systems are rooted in their context, and to seek to transfer whole packages to other countries is a recipe for failure. Business history research on the impact of multinationals shows that it is foolish to assume that outcomes are always positive for host economies. There can be a virtuous circle if the entrepreneurs and other business elements in the host company respond in a particularly dynamic way. This virtuous circle involves government, the public policy framework, local entrepreneurs and foreign companies. Foreign companies can transfer knowledge and information, but this is useless unless there are local entrepreneurs who respond and a government that provides the suitable context. In my MBA class, we compare the strategies of India and China. During the 1960s and 1970s most foreign companies left India. This was regarded by many as one cause of India’s slow economic growth, as the country found itself isolated from international flows of knowledge and technology. Yet this era laid the foundations for the growth of powerful indigenous firms such as Tata, which are now becoming globally competitive. India has almost no foreign companies and depends on indigenous entrepreneurship. In contrast, China is currently hailed as a great success story due to the large amount of foreign direct investment it has attracted since the 1980s, and it lacks the kind of strong domestic enterprises seen in India. Which is the better model for sustainable economic success? EBHRC crew: What can business history contribute to studying the Middle East? Prof. Jones: Foreign companies dominated most of the economies of the Middle East in earlier times, but this brought mixed economic results. Foreign firms enabled the exploitation of mineral resources, which transformed Middle Eastern economies, but they captured much of the value created themselves. They were also not very good at diffusing knowledge to the local economies. In Egypt, the Suez Canal Company created an infrastructure, but operated in a system that restricted locals from rising up the hierarchy. I think foreign companies have been and remain important conduits of technology, information and knowledge, yet the way they structured their business in the past occurred within a 15 geopolitical system and thought process that probably did not facilitate growth in developing countries. Local entrepreneurs We also need to get into issues related to the local entrepreneurs, their response and their background. Where do entrepreneurs come from and how far does their culture, religion or the social structure impact them and what they choose to do and not to do? Clearly variations in entrepreneurial skills play a significant role in understanding why some countries are rich and others are poor. Unfortunately we still lack convincing explanations of the origins of entrepreneurship, and the reasons for variations in its quality. “... Why are some cultures capable of creating organizations that can exploit knowledge and transform it, while others cannot? ...” Evidently societies and their entrepreneurs differed in their abilities to absorb knowledge. The kind of knowledge that was created with industrialization in western counties from the late eighteenth century was rapidly diffused about northwest Europeans, and the colonies they created in North America and elsewhere, but proved hard to diffuse beyond that, with the very significant exception of Japan. The primary reason have been the inabilities of many countries to create the organizational forms that could exploit this knowledge to generate wealth. Business history has the potential to answer these fundamental questions about the drivers of economic growth. What are the barriers of diffusion of business and technological knowledge? Why are some cultures capable of creating organizations that can exploit knowledge and transform it, while others cannot? The answers are evidently to be found in the political systems, cultures and institutional structures of countries, all of which are legitimate subjects for business history to explore. EBHRC crew: With the current trend of studying multinationals, how much can this tell us about the host country where it operates? Prof. Jones: From the perspective of a country that has poor surviving archival information, it can tell us a lot. In the case of British banks in the Middle East, the archives contain millions of pages of documents on credit transactions of Arabs and Iranians. The problem, however, is that if you read British colonial records on Africa, for instance, you will be lead into a direction that Africans are hopeless entrepreneurs and that the culture is in a dire need for the colonial regimes to put things in order. If such material is used, a lot can be discovered but within the context of realizing the bias of the source. It is not good to write the history of the country through the eyes of foreign companies in a too literal way. EBHRC crew: What do you think of relying on oral narratives as a source of writing history? Prof. Jones: Oral narratives are a great potential source for business history, but they need to be used with caution. One has to be aware of people’s agendas and the frailty of their memories. You cannot rely solely on oral narratives for dates and statistics, for instance. Nevertheless, what any historian wants to do is get into the heads of people. Oral history is very good at that, but one has to constantly remember that he is in a head of a person. If people are alive, it is quite irresponsible to write about something without talking about the people themselves. GEOFFREY JONES IS JOSEPH C. WILSON Professor of Business Administration at Harvard Business School. He was the direc tor of the Centre for International Business History at Reading University until 2002. He previously taught at Cambridge, London School of Economics and Reading Universities in the UK. He is a business histo rian, whose main research interests focus on international business and entrepre neurship, and the impact of multinational firms crossing borders. His publications include: British Multinational Banking 18301990 (1993), Merchants to Multinationals (2000), Multinationals and Global Capitalism (2005), and Renewing Unilever:Transformation and Tradition (2005) . He is currently working on a history of the globalization of the beauty industry. HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVES Egyptian Textile Workers in the Transition to a Neo-Liberal Order Joel Beinin, Professor of Middle East History, Stanford University rom the mid-1950s to the present, despite the nationalization of most of the textile industry in the early 1960s, the encouragement of private enterprise in the mid-1970s, and the denationalization of a number of enterprises since 1991, one factor has remained constant: the state has attempted to assert full control over all workplaces of any significance. Trade unions have been tightly controlled. Elections to local union executive committees have often been fixed. In 1987 the High Constitutional Court ruled that the right to strike was constitutionally protected. But striking workers continued to risk severe repression. Legislation adopted in 2003 formally legalized strikes, but under severely restricted circumstances. Labor news has rarely been reported on the radio and television and in the government press. In the mid-1980s the legal leftist weekly, al-Ahali, consistently covered labor issues; and for several years in the early 2000s Al-Ahram Weekly tolerated more labor news than other government owned newspapers. F Egypt’s defeat in the 1967 Arab-Israeli War undermined the legitimacy of the Nasserist regime and exposed it to significant political and social criticism for the first time since 1954. Since then there have been sporadic outbursts of collective action and strikes in response to declining real wages in 1971-72 and 1975-76, reductions in consumer subsidies and the imposition of Washington consensus neo-liberal policies in 1977 (the January food riots), price increases and increases in workers’ contributions to health insurance and pension plans in 1984-89, and the privatization of the public sector in the 1990s and early 2000s. Textile workers in the large public sector mills – the Misr mills in Mahalla al-Kubra, Kafr al-Dawwar and Helwan, and the ESCO mills in Shubra alKhayma and Qalyub – were prominent in all these waves of protest and strike activity along with other public sector workers. Private sector workers participated much less active in collective actions of any sort. In the mid-1980s several “alternative” newspapers and organizations emerged to give workers a voice outside the framework of the state-dominated trade union federations, which had long ceased to represent them. Veteran textile union activists, the late Taha Sa‘d ‘Uthman and Muhammad “... Egypt’s defeat in the 1967 ArabIsraeli War undermined the legitimacy of the Nasserist regime and exposed it to significant political and social criticism for the first time since 1954...” Mutawalli al-Sha‘rawi were among the editors of Sawt al-‘Amil (Workers’ Voice), which began publication in 1985. Sawt al-‘Amil sharply criticized the historic absorption and repression 16 HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVES of the labor movement by the Nasserist state. It tried to connect the workers’ movement of the mid-1980s with the militant trade union upsurge of the 1940s and early 1950s by publishing biographies of veteran activists and other historical material. One of its major projects was a series of articles presenting a legal case for the innocence of Mustafa Khamis and Muhammad al-Baqri – two textile workers who were executed on September 7, 1952 because of their participation in a strike on August 1213 in support of the demand for a freely chosen trade union for the workers at the Misr plants in Kafr al-Dawwar. Textile workers at Mahalla al-Kubra formed the core of an area-wide organization, al-Fagr (Dawn), which had several hundred members and issued a newspaper with the same name in the mid-1980s. Another regional newspaper of the period was based among the textile workers of Shubra al-Khayma (‘Ummal Shubra alKhayma). The fiercest confrontations between workers and the state during the 1984-89 strike wave were two sit-in strikes at the Iron and Steel Co. in Helwan in July and August 1989 (1). Its leaders were among the founders of the Center for Trade Union and Workers’ Services. The Center subsequently established a branch in Shubra al-Khayma whose primary objective was to serve the textile workers in the area. After the Iron and Steel Co. strikes, the regime of Husni Mubarak, became less tolerant of labor dissidence, an aspect of its generally more repressive character in the 1990s. This revival of labor militancy occurred in the context of a structural crisis of the textile industry concentrated in the public sector. The proportion of textile workers in the industrial work force began declining in 1960; the absolute number of textile workers began declining in 1976 (2). The index of real wages of textile workers declined from 100 in 1986 to 61 in 1994, an even more precipitous decline than that of the industrial work force as a whole (3). Due to lack of capital investment, productivity in the Egyptian textile industry was actually lower in 1999 than in 1985. It is now much lower than in neighboring countries like Tunisia and Turkey. A quarter of the machinery is outdated and needs to be renovated or replaced (4). Average wages of Egyptian textile workers are among the lowest in the world: 85 percent of wages in Pakistan and 60 percent of wages in 17 India. A weaver in a well-run private sector enterprise makes about LE 1,000 a month (including base pay of about LE 500-600 plus incentives); a spinner makes about LE 800 a month (including base pay of about LE 400 plus incentives). It is, of course, not accidental that the lower paid spinners are mostly women. Private sector textile workers work twelve hour shifts and rarely receive health insurance or other social benefits (whose total cash value is about LE 400 a month) despite the fact that they are legally entitled to receive these benefits. Wages are about half this amount in public sector enterprises, where daily shifts are 7 hours and workers receive time-and-a half for overtime (5). Nonetheless, the industry is globally uncompetitive. Exports began to decline in 1990, exacerbated by a global textile recession in 1991. The value of total production reached the lowest point since government statistics began to be collected in 1996/97 (6). The private sector has been encouraged by the state since Anwar al-Sadat’s declaration of an “open door” economic policy in 1974. There was relatively little private investment in any industrial sector in the 1970s. Private sector investment in textiles declined precipitously from 1983 to 1987. It grew following the 1991 Gulf War, but stalled in mid-2000 (7). The 1991 Gulf War created the conditions for Egypt to sign an Economic Reform and Structural Adjustment Program “... The pattern of workers’ collective action since 1971 indicates a significant disparity between the work experience, trade union and political consciousness, and militancy of public and private sector workers...” agreement with the IMF and the World Bank. Law 203 of June 1991 was the first tangible step towards privatizing the public sector, which the international financial institutions had been urging for over a decade. After resisting privatization since 1974, the leadership of the Egyptian Trade Union Federation endorsed this legislation. Several state-owned textile firms were sold to Egyptian and foreign investors during the mid-1990s spurt of private investment. They generated 12 percent of all proceeds from the sale of public sector enterprises. From 1992 to 2000 the market share of the private sector in cotton spinning grew from 8 percent to 58 percent (8). In response to the crisis in spinning and weaving, production of ready-made garments became a more salient factor in the textile industry. This replicated the practice established in the late 19th and early 20th centuries, when competition from imported European cloth led to a decline in Egyptian spinning and weaving, but a sharp rise in garment production (9). In 2000/01 there were 209,272 spinning, weaving and dyeing workers and 163,241 garment workers (compared to 457,191 spinning, weaving, and dyeing workers in 1976). Private investors are well-represented in garment production. The value of private sector garment production increased nearly 30 percent from 1996/97 to 2000/01, while the value of public sector production fell by approximately the same amount. In other words, neo-liberal privatization in the garment industry did not result in a substantial increase in the value of total production, nor did it provide enough employment opportunities to replace the lost jobs in spinning and weaving. Moreover, the garment workforce is highly feminized, which has resulted in lower wages, just as was the case 100 years ago. Of all public sector garment workers, 51 percent are women; 40 percent of all shirt makers are women, all in the private sector; and 52% of all other private sector garment makers are women (10). Precise information about working conditions in privately owned textile and garment enterprises is difficult to come by. While they are legally required to provide the same social benefits and health insurance as public sector firms, most do not. They evade the law by bribing inspectors and producing for the local market, which requires lower standards of SEMINAR SERIES HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVES “... the garment workforce is highly feminized, which has resulted in lower wages, just as was the case 100 years ago. Of all public sector garment workers, 51 percent are women; 40 percent of all shirt makers are women, all in the private sector; and 52% of all other private sector garment makers are women...” documentation than the export market. Firms that pay social insurance benefits must pay a severance package equal to two months wages for every year worked if they dismiss a worker. Firms that successfully avoid paying social insurance benefits are able to fire workers with no restrictions, a strong incentive for illegal behavior (11). Before enactment of the 2003 Unified Labor Law it was widely reported that workers signed undated letters of resignation when hired so that they could be dismissed without receiving severance pay if they “made trouble.” Firms often hired workers on three-month temporary contracts and fired them before they became permanent. The 2003 legislation legalized indefinitely renewable temporary contracts (12). This means that many workers remain in limbo for years living in fear of exercising their rights and with no job security. Several of the new private enterprises are located in the new cities surrounding Cairo. Workers are therefore cut off from the social networks required to support collective action; few private sector firms are unionized. By 1999, 137 of the 314 public sector firms declared eligible in 1991 had been privatized. Although the 1991 privatization legislation forbade mass layoffs after privatization of a firm, managers of public sector firms under consideration for privatization often attempted to make them more attractive by reducing the workforce before the sale. Anxieties about unemployment and other possible consequences of privatization prompted a renewal of strikes and collective action in the mid-1990s, with major strikes at Misr Fine Spinning and Weaving in Kafr al-Dawwar in November 1994 and Misr Helwan Spinning and Weaving in August 1998. At the Misr Helwan mill, the entire workforce of 8,700 was given a three-week vacation. Then management announced that only 2,800 workers should return to work. Rumors spread that the enterprise would be leased to a private investor (13). Some 400 workers of ESCO’s Qalyub Spinning Mill sat in at their enterprise for over four months from February to June 2005 protesting the sale of their firm to a private investor because neither the government nor the new owner would commit to maintaining the level of their wages, benefits, and pensions (14). Despite the moves towards privatization, the textile industry remains the core of the public sector. The single largest state-owned enterprise is the Misr Spinning and Weaving Company in Mahalla. It employed over 20,000 workers in 2000 and generated revenues of LE 700.2 million. By contrast, one of the most successful new private fir ms, Alexandria Spinning and Weaving, employed 3,200 workers and earned revenues of LE 160.68 million. The recently privatized Arab Polvara Spinning and Weaving earned LE 213.52 million (15). The pattern of workers’ collective action since 1971 indicates a significant disparity between the work experience, trade union and political consciousness, and militancy of public and private sector workers. Even among the generally more militant public sector textile workers, gender, locality, the differential effects of foreign competition, the particular commodity manufactured, the fabric worked, and the political character of the local trade union leadership all produced important differences. Therefore, it is very problematic to define a set of common experiences and a consciousness that define “the” Egyptian textile worker. The entire Egyptian working class has been disorganized over the last three decades, and the long-term effects of the efforts to re-privatize the economy since 1991 are still not knowable. END NOTES: 1. Omar El Shafei, "Workers, Trade Unions, and the State in Egypt: 1984-1989," Cairo Papers in Social Science 18, no. 2 (Summer 1995): 2229, 33-35. 2. Tamer Abdel-Kader, “State, Capital and Workers’ Protests in Egypt,” (M.A. thesis, American University in Cairo, 1998), 79. 3. Ibid., 84. 4. American Chamber of Commerce in Egypt, The Textile and Clothing Industry in Egypt (Cairo: The Chamber, August 2004), 70. 5. Interview with the owner of a private sector textile enterprise who wishes to remain anonymous, Cairo, March 19, 2005. 5. Abdel-Kader, 81; Egypt, Central Agency for Public Mobilization and Statistics, On-Line Census of Industrial Production, 2000/01 “`Adad al-mansha’at wa-`adad al-mushtaghalin hasba fi’at al-sin wa’l-naw`.” 7. Abdel-Kader, 81. 8. Jolynn Khamky, "Liberalization to Divestment: Egypt, 1960-2000," senior honors thesis, Department of History, Stanfor d University, 2003), 50, 65. 9. John Chalcraft, The Striking Cabbies of Cairo and Other Stories: Crafts and Guilds in Egypt, 1863-1914 (Albany: State University of New York Press, 2004), 55-58. 10. Central Agency for Public Mobilization and Statistics, On-Line Census of Industrial Production, 2000/01 “‘Adad al-mansha’at wa-‘adad al-mushtaghalin hasba fi’at al-sinn wa’l-naw‘.” 11. Interview, Cairo, March 19, 2005. 12. Marsha Pripstein Posusney, "Globalization and Labor Protection in Oil-Poor Arab Countries: Racing to the Bottom?" paper presented at the conference on “The Jordanian Economy in a Changing Environment” (Amman: University of Jordan, July 22-23, 2003). 13. Agnieszka Paczynska, "Globalization and Pressure to Conform: Contesting Labor Law Reform in Egypt," paper presented at the DC Area Workshop on Contentious Politics (College Park, MD: University of Maryland, October 23, 2002). 14. Joel Beinin, “Popular Social Movements and the Future of Egyptian Politics,” Middle East Report Online, March 10, 2005, http://www.mafhoum.com/press7/231S24.ht m 15. Khamky, "Liberalization to Divestment," 67. JOEL BEININ is a professor of Middle East History at Stanford University. He taught at Stanford University since 1983. He was the President of the Middle East Studies Association of North America in 2002. His research interest focuses on workers, peasants, and minorities in the modern Middle East and on Israel, Palestine, and the Arab Israeli conflict. His publications include: Workers on the Nile: Nationalism, Communism, Islam and the Egyptian Working Class, 1882-1954 (1987; co-authored with Zachary Lockman), The Dispersion of Egyptian Jewry: Culture, Politics, and the Formation of a Modern Diaspora (1998). Workers and Peasants in the Modern Middle East (2001.) 18 HITORICAL PERSPECTIVES Railroads in the Land of the Nile The Story Egyptian Railroads of Amr Nasr El-Din, Political Science Graduating Senior, AUC 19 n a daily basis, around 2.3 million passengers use trains operated by the Egyptian National Railroads (ENR) to reach their destinations. In addition, more than 11 million tons of freight is transported on an annual basis (1). Thus it could be fairly said that the ENR plays a major role in Egypt's economic activity. This role has been successfully fulfilled by the Egyptian railroad service since it was first created more than 150 years ago. O The development of railroads in the 19th Century was initially and in most cases dominated by economic factors. Railroads were used to exploit natural resources and facilitate exports and/or imports. It was a general trend, especially outside North America and Western Europe, to find major colonial powers investing in infrastructure projects, especially railroads, to gain access to natural resources and/or facilitate penetrating local markets. This happened in India, China and other parts of the world (3). The creation of Egyptian railroads was a direct result of the massive changes that took place in Egypt in the early years of the 19th century. But despite the long history of the ENR, and the vital role it plays in the life of the country, little is known about this massive establishment which employs around 90,000 people and operates a wide network of routes which range from fast high-density trafficked routes to small lazy Delta branch lines (2). Its long and interesting history is virtually unknown to most Egyptians. This piece is concerned with the history of the Egyptian railroads and investigates the reasons why railroads were introduced in Egypt in the first place. In the case of Egypt, the introduction, building and development of railroads was not intended as a service to the Egyptian economy or as a means to penetrate Egyptian markets, or even exploit Egypt's natural resources; rather, it was motivated by the desire of Great Britain to gain political leverage in Egypt in order to secure and strengthen its grip on its main access route to India. In pointing this out, I do not mean to underestimate the economic rationale behind the construction of railroads, but rather to highlight the presence of other factors that, in some cases, played a decisive role regarding railroad development in Egypt. The British Connection: The British Interest in a Permanent Route to Asia: The British were primarily interested in securing an access to their dominions in Asia and creating a safe trading corridor to India, the largest and most important British colony, or the jewel of the British crown, as it was aptly described at the time. Historically, there were two main routes connecting Europe and Asia: the first was through the Middle East and was mainly a land route passing either through Egypt or through, what is now known, as Syria. This famous land route which encompassed the famous Silk Road rapidly deteriorated in the years following 1498, when Vasco Di-Gama discovered the Cape of Good Hope. This newly discovered naval route allowed the British and other European powers easy and unrestricted access to Asia, avoiding the high tariffs they used to pay to use the old land rout (4). Moreover, the new route, though much longer, was much safer than the old one, which was prone to political upheavals that could drastically affect its accessibility. HITORICAL PERSPECTIVES The New Middle Eastern Route: The expansion of British and European influence in Asia and their subsequent entrenchment in their new colonies automatically transferred European conflicts and rivalry to the Asian hinterlands. This required a faster means of communication to transmit orders as evidenced by a report written by Colonel James Capper of the East India Company around 1738 in which he says: “during the late war in India, we frequently, had no intelligence from England for eight to nine months; nor did we hear of the rupture of Spain until upwards of eleven months”(5). In addition, the ships used to maintain contact between Europe and Asia urgently needed massive re-supply stations along the naval route, which entailed huge economic and political costs. These two factors highlighted the need for a much faster route to reduce the time and the number of supply stations needed. At the time, the main alternative to the Cape of Good Hope was the Middle East which was becoming more favorable not only on account of the time factor, but also because the crumbling Ottoman empire posed a lighter threat to the European powers. In the Middle East there were two main routes to access the Far East; the first was by Sea, to what is now known as Syria, then through desert caravans to the Ottoman provinces Baghdad and Basra, up the Euphrates, then by ships through the Persian Gulf to India and the Far East. The Egyptian Option: Transiting Through Suez: The second Middle Eastern route was across the Mediterranean, through Egypt to the Red Sea. It was a very old route, which dated to the time of the Pharaohs. Historically, this route used to pass through the city of Pithon, better known as Heroopolis, at the Gulf of Heroopolis, before it dried and retreated to today's city of Suez, which was connected to the Pelusiac Nile, one of the many Nile branches that, also, dried out. It was repaired and used in Greek and Roman times, during the era of Ptolemy and Trojan respectively. Later on, after the Islamic conquest, it gained importance not only as a trade route between Europe and Asia, but also as a passage to the Hejaz used annually by pilgrims heading for Mecca. The route passing through Egypt possessed a clear advantage over both the Cape of Good Hope and Mesopotamian routes since it required less time to cover. At the time sea travel was cheaper and faster than land transportation, and the Egyptian route entailed carrying goods between the harbors of Alexandria and Suez – a distance much shorter and safer than crossing the Mesopotamian desert. The time factor was soon recognized by the British; in a report by Capper he says: “when the peace [referring to the peace treaty between England and Spain] was signed, the news of it was transmitted to India, both across the great desert [of Mesopotamia] and also round the Cape of Good Hope. Nevertheless it did not reach Madras until the end of June… [H]ad the passage through Suez been available at the time the dispatch might have been sent from England to the scene of action in 70 days”. In 1768, and again in 1775, Capper came to Cairo in an effort to negotiate a treaty with Mohamed Abu Al-Dahab that would open the “Sacred Sea” – the Red Sea – to British ships in return for 200,000 pounds paid to the Egyptian government per annum in the form of duties. The Ottoman protest against the treaty forced the British ships to stop coming to Suez from 1779 (6). In 1794, George Baldwin, the upholder of British interests in Egypt, managed to hold a new treaty with Mourad Bey and Ibrahim Bey. This gave British ships the right of free navigation, landing and transit of goods, mails and passengers and was later endorsed by a faraman (official decree) issued by the Ottoman sultan. Four years later, however, this was disrupted by the French invasion to Egypt in 1798 (7). The Creation of the Modern State: Mohammed Ali and the Pillars of Modernization: It is often said that the founding of the modern Egyptian state and, therefore, the beginning of the modern history of Egypt dates back to the reign of Mohammed Ali (1805-1848). The powerful government institutions, backed by a powerful economic base that rested upon advanced industries and a flourishing agriculture, created by Mohammed Ali ensured that the government had sufficient financial resources, which, in turn, guaranteed the spread of its control over Egypt. Increased government contr ol improved security throughout Egypt and made the Western powers, and Britain in particular, more interested than ever in benefiting from Egypt's unique geographical position to secure a permanent route to their Asian and African colonies. Renewed British Efforts to Re-Open the Egyptian Route: Britain's renewed interest in Egypt and its desire to establish a faster link between England and its colonies in the Indian sub-continent is attested to by a memorandum sent by John Barker in 1815, the British Counsel General in Egypt between 1828-1833, in which he suggested using steam ships in the Mediterranean and the Red Sea to create a faster link. In addition, a report written in 1829 by lieutenant Thomas Waghorn of the Bombay Marine stated that a trip between London and Bombay could take between five to eight months under sail and up to three months with steam ships through the Cape of Good Hope (8). In contrast, a trip through Egypt, using what was then known as the “overland route”, could take only 40 days, even without the use of steam ships (9). One could therefore conclude that three main reasons led the British and other western powers to favour the Egyptian route. First, Mohammed Ali's reforms, particularly the introduction of new technologies, like the use of steam-powered vessels in the Nile in the 1830s with all associated advantages. Second, the increased safety of Egyptian trade routes as the government's policing abilities improved (10). Third, the fact that the Egyptian route required much lesser time than its alternatives since the distance was much shorter. At the time the Egyptian route consisted of two main sections. The first started in Alexandria where the commodities coming from Europe were unloaded at its port, to be loaded onto small vessels which sailed through the Mahmoudiya canal, dug in 1819, then through the Nile to Cairo. The 269 kilometres long trip took three to four days or according to some sources 42 hours of day navigation to end its journey at the port in Bulaq. Commodities, mail and passengers were then moved on to Suez by desert caravans, which in fair weather covered the 144 kilometres distance in 16 to 18 hours (11). 20 HITORICAL PERSPECTIVES Time for Railroading: The First Trails to Establish a Railroad in Egypt: The above-mentioned facts encouraged the British to think seriously about establishing a fast land link to connect the two naval hubs in Alexandria and Suez. Building a railroad seemed an ideal solution, especially since the Egyptian government would gain revenues from the duties on transshipment. There is disagreement among historians as to who first presented the idea. Some sources suggest it was a British firm, others, that it was Thomas Galloway, a British engineer of Scottish origins who used to work for Mohammed Ali (12). The massive project began in 1834, less than 10 years after the inauguration of the first railroad in Britain between Stockton and Darlington. The first stage was a 128-kilometer, single-track railroad on the land section of the “overland route” between Cairo and Suez. The distance would be covered in 6 hours, as trains then could only run at a speed of 20 to 24 kilometers per hour (13). Railroads as Means of Political Influence: The railroad project received huge backing from the British government since it meant less transit time and increased security on its main trading route to India. Moreover, all the essential equipment and experts would come from Britain and it was automati- “...The railroad project received huge backing from the British government since it meant less transit time and increased security on its main trading route to India...” cally assumed that Mohammed Ali would resort to British capital to finance this massive project. An Egyptian railroad built by Britain would not only 21 ensure the improvement of the overland route to India, but would, in addition, bring about a direct British involvement in Egyptian affairs which, if well used, could be translated into political leverage. The British keenness to manipulate the Egyptian railroad project for political interests was further sharpened by their fear that the French, who at the time were heavily lobbying with Mohammed Ali to approve their idea of digging a canal between the Red Sea and the Mediterranean, were gaining political influence in Egypt. The False Start: End of the First Trials to Construct a Railroad in Egypt: In November 1834 Mohammed Ali approved the construction of Egypt's first railroad and sent Thomas Galloway to Great Britain to purchase the essential equipment. By the end of the year most of the equipment, including the tracks, had arrived to Alexandria only to be left in the their crates (14). The ruler of Egypt had suddenly decided to drop the project. A set of political debacles and fear of foreign intervention are believed to have made him change his mind and put an end to this ambitious project before it even started. The fear of foreign intervention, political or economic, could be partially explained by the high cost of the project, which would have forced Egypt to resort to foreign capital. Mohammed Ali decided it was better and cheaper to concentrate on digging irrigation canals, since they could be dug using local expertise and with minimal costs. They would also be useful both for irrigation and transportation. Meanwhile, the equipment that was shipped to Alexandria was used to build small railroad lines on which the carriages were horse-drawn. The first of these lines was near the now famous Cairo suburb of Maadi; the short line used to run between the large quarries and a small dock on the Nile waterfront. It was used to transport rocks needed for the construction of barrages and other irrigation projects. The second line was in Alexandria and ran between El-Dekhla quarries and the Alexandria harbor. Like its twin line, this one was also used to transfer rocks and building material needed for the expansion of Egypt's main port in Alexandria. Another short line was built to connect granaries in Alexandria with the port; 30 small carriages were used on it (15). Egypt, therefore, entered the age of railroading in a de-facto rather than in an official manner by 1835. Interestingly John Galloway, the brother of Thomas Galloway, re-offered the rail link project in 1843 to Mohammed Ali who refused it once more and on very much the same grounds as before. It could be assumed that Mohammed Ali refused to build the railroad for its possible political and economic consequences; but it is equally probable that he realized that Egypt did not really need a new, fancy and expensive means of transportation. Yes, transportation has always represented a major historical challenge to humans and the ease of transportation has always been unanimously identified with development and prosperity. Egypt is no exception; and its economic history is very much related to the history and development of its local and international transportation systems. Egypt's geography and topography played a major role in determining the patterns of life and economic activities of Egyptians. Egypt, or, to be precise, the inhabited part of Egypt, is concentrated round the Nile, in its valley and Delta. Most of this area is flat ground, which allows easy overland movement. In addition, the dependence of Egypt on the Nile for water dictated, by default, that most of its economic and urban centers and agricultural land had to be on or near the Nile's waterfront. These factors, plus the navigability of the river, greatly facilitated transportation in Egypt. For thousands of years, the Nile was Egypt's main transportation hub and carried people as well as all kinds of commodities, ranging from small bundles of wheat to the massive obelisks. While the Nile and its branches provided Egypt with an excellent internal transportation system, most of its meager international trade, or, more precisely, interaction with the outside world was conducted through desert caravans or large sea vessels (16). It should be said that the Egyptian railroads during their first days did not attract a large percentage of Egypt's internal transportation either in the form of passengers or in the form of goods as many preferred the Nile as a safer and more accessible means of transportation. In other words, internal transportation in Egypt had always been adequate for its needs and never constituted a major obstacle to economic development. At the time the railroad project was proposed, Egypt did not have a major transportation problem. This probably played a role in Mohammed Ali's decesion to turn down the railorad HITORICAL PERSPECTIVES offer twice. It would be more than 20 years before efforts to build a railroad in Egypt were launched again. The Start: The Beginning of the Railroading Era in Egypt: Passenger station, Egypt, Mass., July 9, 1955. Charles B. Gunn Collection (19880001.ph2139). Courtesy of railroads.uconn.edu/. ../ma/egypt.htm The Egypt-Suez Railroad Station (Published by Arougheti Brothers) (Unused Postcard, Undivided back). Courtesy of www.post cardman.net/ egypt_suez.html The first Egyptian locomotive built by Robert Stevenson and delivered in 1852 and it was used mainly for haling passen ger trains. Courtesy of www.geocities. com/ amrsmodelrailroad/ha.html The Cairo Railway station. Courtesy of www.gasolinealleyantiques.com/ trains.htm The British efforts to convince Egyptian rulers to build railroads continued, and with accession of Abbas to the Egyptian throne, a new and more vigorous campaign to convince him to approve the project was launched. Unlike its predecessors, this attempt succeeded, partly due to British efforts to help Abbas overcome the Ottaman's refusal to his accession to Egypt's throne. In November 1851, the contract to build the first railroad in Egypt was signed between Egypt's forigen minister, Stephen Bek, and a representative of Robert Stephonson, the son of George Stephonson, the inventor of the railroads. It would be a single line from Alexandria to Cairo, then from Cairo to Suez, following the footsteps of the old famous overland route (17). In April 1853, the first section, 105 kilometres long, between Alexandria and Kafr Al-Eies on the western bank of the Nile, was opened (18). The first line between Cairo and Alexandria was completed in 1855 with the total cost of one and a half million Egyptian pounds including the price of the tracks, flanges, locomotives and carriages. The second line between Cairo and Suez was built between 1856 and 1858 and upon its completion a modern railroad line now served the overland route and its revenues helped the finances of the Egyptian state. It should be said that in 1869 and after the opening of the Suez Canal, the revenues coming from the “steel” overland route declined and Cairo-Suez railroad was closed. Consequently, the number of foreign passengers per kilometre using the Egyptian railr oads decreased to only 14 (19). Britain's interest in creating and maintaining a link with its colonies in Asia was behind the building of the first railroad line in Egypt. At that time, due to its special geographic and topographic circumstances, and notwithstanding all the benefits a railroad could bring, Egypt had no great or urgent need for one. It was built not to address the social and economic needs of Egypt, but because a foreign power, namely Great Britain, decided that it was in her interest to have it built. The story of the Egyptian railways presents a clear example in the history of international railway development in which the desires and interests of a foreign power dominated the pattern of railroad establishment and development. END NOTES: 1. Gary Goldfish. Steel in the Sand, the History of Egypt and its Railways: Dorset Press, 2003. 2. Ibid. 3. Danial Thorner. "The Pattern of Railway Development in India." The Far Eastern Quarterly 14, no. 2 (1955): 201-216. 4. A.F.C De Cosson. "History of the Egyptian Overland Route." The Egyptian State Railroads Magazine 1, no. 2 (1934). 5. Ibid. 6. A.F.C De Cosson. "History of the Egyptian Overland Route." The Egyptian State Rialroads Magazine 1, no. 2 (1934). 7. Ibid. 8. A.F.C De Cosson. "History of the Egyptian Overland Route." The Egyptian State Rialroads Magazine 1, no. 2 (1934). 9. Ibid. 10. Gary Goldfinch. Steel in the Sand, the History of Egypt and its Railways: Dorset Press, 2003. 11. Sikak Hadid Masr Fi 125 Aamn 1852-1977 (Egyptian Railways in 125 Year 1852-1977): Egyptian Railways Press, 1977. See also Gary Goldfinch. Steel in the Sand, the History of Egypt and its Railways: Dorset Press, 2003. p. 3. 12. Fatma Alam Al-Din. Tatur Al-Nakal Ua AlMuaslat Al-Dakhelya Fi Masr Fi Ahd Al-Ihtlal Al-Biritani 1882-1914 (Development of Internal Transportation System in Egypt under the British Occupation 1882-1914): AlHaiea Al-Masrya Al-Ama Lil-Kitab (General Egyptian Book Organization), 1989. See Also Sikak Hadid Masr Fi 125 Aamn 1852-1977 (Egyptian Railways in 125 Year 1852-1977): Egyptian Railways Press, 1977. 13. Sikak Hadid Masr Fi 125 Aamn 1852-1977 (Egyptian Railways in 125 Year 1852-1977): Egyptian Railways Press, 1977. 14. Sikak Hadid Masr Fi 125 Aamn 1852-1977 (Egyptian Railways in 125 Year 1852-1977): Egyptian Railways Press, 1977. p. 10. 15. Fatma Alam Al-Din. Tatur Al-Nakal Ua AlMuaslat Al-Dakhelya Fi Masr Fi Ahd Al-Ihtlal Al-Biritani 1882-1914 (Development of Internal Transportation System in Egypt under the British Occupation 1882-1914): AlHaiea Al-Masrya Al-Ama Lil-Kitab (General Egyptian Book Organization), 1989. p.39. 16. Goghrafya Al-Nakal Fi Masr (Geography of Transportation in Egypt). Dirsat Fi Goghrafya Misr (Studies in the Geography of Egypt): Maktaba Al-Anglo Al-Masria (The Anglo-Egyptian Library), 1987. 17. Fatma Alam Al-Din. Tatur Al-Nakal Ua AlMuaslat Al-Dakhelya Fi Masr Fi Ahd Al-Ihtlal Al-Biritani 1882-1914 (Development of Internal Transportation System in Egypt under the British Occupation 1882-1914): AlHaiea Al-Masrya Al-Ama Lil-Kitab (General Egyptian Book Organization), 1989. p. 42. 18. Sikak Hadid Masr Fi 125 Aamn 1852-1977 (Egyptian Railways in 125 Year 1852-1977): Egyptian Railways Press, 1977. 19. Ali Basha Mubarak. Al-Kohtat AlTawfikiya Al-Gadida (the New Tawifkiya Plans). 7 vols. Vol. 7. 22 HITORICAL PERSPECTIVES The Nurturing of Wealth The First Call for a National Bank in Egypt, 1879 Abdelaziz Ezzelarab, Associate Professor of Economics, AUC and Director, EBHRC n April 1879, a group of Egypt’s social and political elite joined ranks to issue a communiqué (or, using the Arabic term, a manshur) calling on the public to subscribe to a joint stock bank for which they proposed the name al-Bank al-Watani alMisri (The National Egyptian Bank). This is the earliest traceable call on the Egyptian public to found a joint-stock national bank. It may also be the earliest call on Egyptians for public subscription to any business venture, as the text of this manshur strongly indicates. This document appeared in the Egyptian daily alTijarah under the title “Inma’ al-Mal” (The Nurturing of Wealth) (1). I The status of Inma’ al-Mal, as one of the earliest public subscription calls, would alone give it a historic importance. What I find very striking, however, is the way it is imbued in an ideological discourse that draws a connection between business organization, economic progress, and global political domination and makes of the project a national, religious, and historic duty all at once. Not very surprising, though. The issuers of 23 “Inma’ al-Mal” knew that public subscription in a joint stock company was an unorthodox business practice. Consequently, they had to address this practice in principle and apply an arsenal of arguments to impress on the public its legitimacy, viability, and historic promise. We find a mix of all this in the manshur (see the complete text and translation below). In what follows, I will attempt a basic reading of the main lines of argument in this document, and I will use ‘manshur’ and ‘Inma’ al-Mal’ interchangeably to refer to it. Our analysis should begin by a look into the immediate context. This was a power struggle over the control of Egypt’s finances and government that originated in the public debt crisis of the late 1870s. April 1879 could be situated within a phase of Egyptian public debt history, which started when interest payments were postponed for the first time (April 1876), and ended with the promulgation of the Liquidation Law (July 1880). The dominant issue at that time was negotiating a plan for debt settlement, and the general trend was one of transferring control over Egypt’s finances and government to European powers, while curtailing the power of the ruler (Khedive Ismail). This trend was briefly interrupted in April 1879 when a National Front was formed of a broad alliance of elite domestic forces, led by large landholders, many of whom were senior state officials or MPs. The Front produced a National Program (“al-La’ihah alWataniyyah”) which was a packageproposal in which domestic elites undertook to liquidate the debt within a framework of political restructuring that involved sharing power with the Khedive. Subsequently, a new cabinet took office under Sharif Pasha, a veteran statesman and a leading signatory to the National Program, and a brief interlude followed during which the cabinet strived to fulfill the program. Within three months, this attempt collapsed, European powers took over again, and the Liquidation Law was promulgated with debt settlement principles acceptable to European powers. It was in the earlier days of that interruption of foreign control in April 1879, within days of the National Program, that “Inma’ al-Mal” was issued. HITORICAL PERSPECTIVES We can trace three general strategies followed in the manshur in arguing for a joint stock national bank. The first is based on the historical record of Europe. In this line of reasoning, Wester n superiority is attributed to a single factor: conglomeration of capital in large incorporated structures. Capital conglomeration is seen as the main force behind western industrial progress, the prevailing pattern of East-West trade, and western ability to extend their presence, hence political domination, to every corner in the world (paragraphs 3, 4, and 15). A contrast is drawn here between the spread of the joint-stock model in Europe and the Eastern adherence to individually-owned enterprise (viz. proprietorships) which culminates in capital fragmentation, and hence losing ground to the West in production techniques, trade, and political power. Closely connected to this line of reasoning is Inma’ al-Mal’s discourse on the institutional uniqueness and vitality of banks, drawing again from the European experience and emphasizing a suggested link between the power of respective European countries and the strength of their banks (paragraphs 5 and 6). It is interesting to note here how notions of current usage in global political economy find their way into the manshur, as for example the allusion to the pattern of trade and division of labour on a global scale (paragraph 4), and to the clout of the East India Company as evidence for the power of transnational companies (paragraph 15). It is also interesting to note how Europe dominates the text, both by providing an inspiring historical model and, as we will see, by being the adversary against which the elites aimed at national self-assertion. Stemming out of this premise, the second strategy in arguing for the bank is based on nationalistic grounds. Having argued that political power is a function of economic superiority, that the latter is a direct result of massive capital mobilization, and that banking acts as the vital link in making this mobilization possible, the issuers of Inma’ al-Mal make a passionate argument that establishing al-Bank al-Watani al-Misri is the means— possibly the only means—for the economic and political salvation of Egypt (paragraphs 8, 13, 16). Given the context, the public must have already been prepared to accept that the ongoing financial and political crisis was to a large extent the making of foreign banks. This feeling must have been aggravated by a recent spread in the “...The joint-stock model is thus elevated from the realm of a rational business choice to a command on the individual and the community, on the strength of its role as an organizational pre-requisite for the nurturing of wealth....” mortgage and loss of agricultural lands to foreign moneylenders. An implicit link may be impressed on the public here between the preceding exposition on the expansion of European banking and the spread of foreign moneylenders in the countryside. The public debt crisis that created claims on the Egyptian treasury was thus compounded by the fear of loss of lands to foreigners due to default on private debts. The manshur, indeed, makes an explicit allusion to this threat by warning against the repercussions of absence of national financial institutions in order to impress on the public the urgency of that venture (paragraphs 7, 10). As if the nationalist duty, backed by European historical experience, was not enough motivation, Inma’ al-Mal delves into a third line of reasoning of a presumably stronger binding nature: religion. Interestingly, the issuers of the manshur not only found a need to borrow from this frame of reference, but they also apparently believed that this connection must be established at the outset. Their point of departure, therefore, was to begin the manshur by arguing that a religious obligation was incumbent on individuals and on the entire community to develop Godgiven resources beyond their natural or raw state (‘al-halah al-fitriyyah’—see paragraphs 1 and 3)—in other words, an obligation of nurturing natural wealth. Here, the significance of the title they chose for their manshur becomes evident. Proper fulfillment of this command, the argument continues, is only possible through applying the principle of cooperation. To impress this on their readers, the issuers spread this argument in various parts of the manshur, using different synonyms for ‘cooperation’: al-ishtirak, al-ta‘awun, al-takaful, al-ittihad etc. (paragraphs 2, 3, 4, 7, 15). Within this discourse, collective capital mobilization is then projected as an incidence of such cooperation (paragraph 4). The jointstock model is thus elevated from the realm of a rational business choice to a command on the individual and the community, on the strength of its role as an organizational pre-requisite for the nurturing of wealth. Given fears of inconsistency between religious teachings and the charging of interest, however, a general argument for joint stock structures would not alone resolve doubts regarding the legitimacy of banks. Here, the manshur moves in two interrelated directions in order to resolve this issue. One is by applying the principle of utility in explaining banks’ vitality to economic activity, and it reaches here the extent of describing banks as a public blessing (‘rahmah lilnas’—paragraph 6). The other approach is to directly employ opinions of Muslim jurists who distinguish usury from legitimate banking profits, with moderation as the yardstick (paragraph 9). The argument for establishing al-Bank alWatani al-Misri, thus, is carefully knit as a national duty that fulfills God’s commands in nurturing wealth, that is consistent with Islamic law, and that would be a landmark in emulating European institutional models which account for so much of Europe’s progress and clout. Clearly, these strings of reasoning are mutually reinforcing and interconnected. Interestingly, while the issuers of the manshur emphatically resort to these justifications, they allude to the Bank as a commercially viable project in an only brief and in-passing fashion, and do so only towards the end of the manshur (paragraph 14), adding the quick caveat that commercial viability is the least important factor in establishing it. Did this reveal a keenness in safeguarding the projection of the enterprise as a nationalist, religious, and historical quest, keeping the ‘misgiving’ of mundane motivations away from it? 24 HITORICAL PERSPECTIVES What we have at hand, thus, is not only a proposal for emulating a superior business-organization model predicated on the drive for material progress, but, a call impregnated in a mix of religious and nationalist duty to which the public should not, or would not, be expected to respond by a mere rational calculation of risk-reward prospects only. In a certain way, this reflects the issuers’ awareness that their call was an extraordinary initiative: a move outside the adopted practices, a challenge to existing power relations, and a quest for self assertion. To succeed, an appeal to decision making on the basis of extrabusiness considerations was crucial. Perhaps this could also explain the confident rhetoric in the manshur where it makes a promise for further nationalist success and self-assertion (paragraph 11) in an apparent reflection of the prevailing political context and the interim elite success in the National Front. Even though the call for al-Bank alWatani did not succeed, the ideological significance of Inma’ al-Mal remains upheld for various reasons. First, the manshur expressed an urge that seems to have existed at that time among a circle of large landholders, merchants, intellectuals, members of the parliament, and holders of key official positions (2). From this perspective, it stands as evidence that the drive and vision to establish a joint-stock national bank had “...As if the nationalist duty, backed by European historical experience, was not enough motivation, Inma’ al-Mal delves into a third line of reasoning of a presumably stronger binding nature: religion...” 25 “...[The immediate context of the manshur] was a power struggle over the control of Egypt’s finances and government that originated in the public debt crisis of the late 1870s....” existed long before the ultimate establishment of the first joint stock Egyptian national bank, Bank Misr, in 1920. The failure in ‘catching up’, at least in this instance, was not due to a lack of awareness, knowledge, or entrepreneurial drive but a product of other factors, including the prevailing balance of power. When Tal’at Harb quoted the entire text of the manshur in Ilaj Misr al-Iqtisadi aw Mashru‘Bank al-Ummah (‘The Economic Remedy of Egypt or The National Bank Project’) at the beginning of his campaign for Bank Misr some thirty five years later, this stood as further proof for the continuing ideological relevance of Inma’ al-Mal. But the context also suggested further parallels with 1879. Harb’s treatise on the need for a national bank was a product of the Egyptian National Conference of 1911, a platform that involved broad elite mobilization of a similar nature to the 1879 National Front. Notwithstanding important differences in instigating factors and purposes, both forums carried a sense of an opportune moment of national mobilization. Subsequently, the idea went dormant for a few years and was resurrected only within the euphoria carried in the 1919 national uprising. Was this further evidence that projects such as the national bank could only be carried in a context of some extraordinary set of circumstances that defy the usual state of affairs? Were the issuers of Inma’ al-Mal justified in betting the success of their bid for the national bank on the air of national mobilization that prevailed in April 1879? The preceding textual study of the manshur provides only limited insight into the immediate and long-term factors that could account for the formation of that call. But it opens up a whole set of investigations. How and when did the elites’ awareness of Western modes of business organization begin? What were their earlier encounters with European transnationals?(3) Could the drive to establish a national bank be interpreted as an elite ambition to promote their share in the domestic market by getting into business activities that Western capital had thus far monopolized? What insights does this give us about the dialects of Egypt’s integration in the world market as a cotton exporter several decades earlier? Finally, to conclude with a grain of salt, how much of Inma’ al-Mal could be taken to reflect the ideology of the economic and political elite, and how much of it should be credited, instead, to remote learning by the community of intellectuals who were beginning to use the spread of Arabic newspapers in the late 1870s to articulate and spread their own visions and views? END NOTES: 1. Inma’ al-Mal’ was reproduced in full and identical versions in Salim Naqqash, Misr lilMisriyyin (1883) and Tal‘at Harb, ‘Ilaj Misr alIqtisadi (1913). The latter was Harb’s treatise on the necessity of a national bank, and was published at the beginning of his campaign for Bank Misr. 2. For details, see the discussion and citations in chapters 5 and 6 in AbdelAziz EzzelArab, European Control and Egypt’s Traditional Elites – A Case Study in Elite Economic Nationalism (Edwin Mellen, 2002). 3. We already know that some large European corporations were active in fields bearing direct contact with the public since the 1830s. The East India Company operated shipping lines since 1834, Lloyd since 1838, and The Peninsular and Oriental Steam Navigation Company since 1840. Also, banks and companies owned by foreign capital were being locally incorporated since the mid 1850s. The Egyptian Company for Steam Navigation was established in 1854, the Bank of Egypt in 1856 and the Anglo-Egyptian Bank in 1864. Egyptian elites themselves were starting to participate with foreign capital in some business concerns. See EzzelArab, European Control, p. 130 and n. 24 & 25. HITORICAL PERSPECTIVES Manshur “Inma’ al-Mal” (Translation)(1) [1. The Nurturing of Wealth is a Religious Command] God in His highness did not create any of His creatures except to bear fruit (yuthmir) and to be useful. He does not approve of leaving His gifts buried in the ground without bearing fruit; verily, what He approves of is the cultivation of those gifts (yustath mar) so that they would grow and benefit the public. As people endeavour to nurture His gifts, the fruits (al-thamar)(2) would surely yield [private material] gain (naf‘)(3) to their owner and God’s contentment to the public, and He would increase their wealth and put more riches in their hands. [2. Cooperation in Nurturing Wealth as a Command] People on this earth, notwithstanding their various kinship relations and kinds, act in collaboration and combination (mutakafilun mutadaminun). They ar e all commanded to work together and to cooperate (ma’murun bil-‘amal wal-ta‘awun) in what they do: the rich furnishes the poor with his wealth [as capital], and the landowner hires the landless [as a labourer] in his agriculture. Science guides them all in using that wealth and in cultivating the land, the mother of all wealth, in the proper way. Had it not been for that cooperation (al-ta‘awun), mankind would not have reaped from his labour or from his wealth or from the earth that the Creator extended under his hands more than what other creatures obtain from hunting with their own claws or from what the land yields by mere coincidence. [3. Cooperation is the Key for Material Satisfaction] Don’t you see that the people of the central parts of our continent, notwithstanding the fertility of their soil and the abundance of minerals in their lands, can barely reap enough food for their day from the riches with which God endowed them because of their repulsion of each other, their separation, and their ignorance of the benefit of cooperation (alta‘awun) and of the power of unity (al-ittihad)? Don’t you also see that there are other nations who have similarly not achieved [material] satisfaction in spite of being far from that primitive state [of central Africa] or perhaps even approaching civil perfection (al-kamal al-tamadduni)(4) ? Verily, don’t you see how there are many of the Eastern nations of old, well established civilizations who are in need for the West in anything that goes beyond the natural produce of land, from the most complex to the sim- plest products? [Don’t you see how] they seek assistance [in everything, from] a machine to plough the land to a sewing needle, as a result of sending their crops [to the West] in the raw state (al-halah alfitriyyah) at minimal prices and getting them back in a transformed form in the manufactured, decorated, civilized state and consequently at multiple prices? [4. Economic Cooperation and Creativity: East versus West] God has privileged the East with the most fertile soil and the most precious mineral. There are many rich [people] of substantial incomes and abundant monies in there. Its peoples, however, were not guided to the most proper way for cultivating and nurturing their lands’ wealth. You find them confined in their commerce to what their ancient ancestors practiced, separated in their enterprises as if they fear that profits (al-barakah) would evaporate if they get into companies. [This is the case] in spite of the gains (barakat) from joining up in businesses (alishtirak fil-a‘mal) that was demonstrated to them in the peoples of the West, who bewildered the inhabited lands and opened up vast regions with their commercial companies and who were so creative in founding and diversifying such companies to the extent of creating commercial companies, industrial companies, and financial companies or banks, which are the subject-matter of this statement. [5. The Vitality of Banking to All Business Activities] It is evident that banking is the link between various kinds of companies, commerce, and crafts and is the inevitable intermediary between [idle] capital and the gainful [use] of it. Without banking, a large proportion of the world’s wealth would remain neglected without cultivation. Think of an owner of a vast property which yields a rent in excess of his needs and who has the habit of using that excess to buy new property. What would he do with the excess cash if it so happened in a certain year that he could not find a piece of land suitable for purchase and if there was no trustworthy bank where he can keep his money as a fruitful deposit, available on demand, subject to his instructions, once he needs it? And suppose, on the other hand, that another property-owner or merchant or craftsman had a need for a sum of money for a specific term, how would he procure the funds if there was no bank that would lend him on conditions suiting his interests? [If] such a person in need knew of the excess available with the [first] property owner, he 26 HITORICAL PERSPECTIVES would request it from him by way of a loan. But who would ensure that that person of abundance would trust him for his money or would agree with him on the terms? The bank is, hence, the closer intermediary between both because it accepts the money of the former and lends it to the latter at [mutually] agreeable terms. And since the bank is liable for the creditor’s money, it is careful not to lend it except to trustworthy people. This is an obvious primary advantage of banking, and is the basis for measuring all transactions between merchants and craftsmen [on the one hand] and capital owners [on the other]. It is evident from this example that the establishment of banks was a blessing for the people (rahmah lilnas) and a major factor of facilitating their dealings and of making their prosperity possible. [6. Banking and National Economic Power] As for public interests, the advantages of banking are too evident to require any verification. Those interests require financial means and administrative capacities that individuals cannot afford. Surely, if banks were omitted from European countries they would all become like a bird with a broken wing, or an unarmed soldier, or a horseman with amputated legs. [If this happens,] the power which made Europeans possess the seas and the deserts and control the world’s commerce and which made it imminent for all [business] interests contracted anywhere in the world to pass in their hands would be gone. If we look to the status of each of the European countries separately, we find that each of them maintains the independence of her important banking institutions. The most independent with their banks are the happiest of them. They enjoy the most extensive commerce, the most successful industry, the strongest clout, and the most forceful authority because capital is the basis of enterprise (al-mal asas al-a‘mal ). If it is not within reach, you cannot avail yourself of it when you need it most. [7. The Threat of the Loss of Land to Foreigners] Our condition is a fair testimony to the validity of the preceding [argument]. If we had an autonomous financial power, we would have been able to recover vital interests which sadly remain impaired [by way of mortgage] to foreigners. We all fear the loss [of those interests and] long to the day of regaining [them.] None of us alone is capable of bringing this closer by even one hour. But if we act collectively, the achievement of that end would be subject only to our determination. Why, then, don’t we make this effort if rescuing our land costs nothing more than getting together and cooperating (al-ijtima’ wal-ta‘awun) to establish financial companies that could achieve [ends] which individuals cannot reach? Should we wait while most of our soils are mortgaged to foreigners until that day when these are sold at the cheapest prices while their owners are watching without getting support from their brothers to keep their property ? [8. Resolution to Establish “al-Bank al-Watani al-Misri”] God forbids it. We will not accept this while we have 27 amongst us zealous [people] who would sacrifice their personal interests for the public good, and would spend generously to achieve such [public] ends. Verily, we do not accept it. We have seen how our enlightened people and elites were exploring ways for salvation until God guided them to establishing a national financial company. This was proposed to them by some leading merchants, and they enthusiastically received it and moved resolutely towards materializing it. It will come to existence shortly, adorned with a noble name, adopted as a good omen; verily it is: ... Al-Bank al-Watani al-Misri around which thoughts have often revolved and for which souls have longed. All our national newspapers had alluded to that idea, praised those promoting it, and called upon people to support them. Subsequently, they carried to us the good news that the idea won the support of the elite of the country’s enlightened people, the most notable of its notables, and a large number of the most notable of our delegates and prominent men. The bank has been the subject of various memoranda and correspondence between many of the higher authorities and none of them was but concurring, supportive, and wishing for success. No objection whatsoever was expressed by [our] countrymen because they are certain that it will all be beneficial, and are confident that it will fulfill the public interest. [9. Conformity with Islamic Law (Shari‘a)] Someone might protest, fearing that the bank may contradict the regulations of the sacred law on the assumption that its dealings are bound to be usurious. [Such a person] might tempt people to believe that countrymen’s support would not go beyond lip-service because most of them are religiously forbidden from usury. We [want to] reassure the protester and eliminate [such] illusions. The sacred Shari‘a has but forbidden pure usury, which is not part of our bank. On the contrary, our bank will do without it because it will be established for the purpose of serving national interests with sincerity and trust and in conformity with the religious doctrines of the country. Its activities will be lending and commissionearning from buying and selling on the account of its customers, all of which are activities that generate profits from [commercial] transactions and are admissible by Shari‘a. The [legal] position of partners to such [transactions] is that of partners in commercial speculation (mudarabah) which is a lawful partnership by the consensus of schools of Islamic law. Besides, commercial transactions which involve an element of profit-making through commercial credit (murabahah) are old estab lished and are abundantly explained in references on Islamic law. In the opinion of al-Khassaf, an example of legitimate transactions is [when] someone sells a garment worth twenty dinars for a price of forty, then lends the buyer another sixty, [this] would bring the latter’s indebtedness to a total of one hundred dinars, although his total receipts were only eighty. This is the school of thought HITORICAL PERSPECTIVES of Muhammad ibn Salama, the spiritual leader (imam) of Balkh. Shams al-A’imma al-Hulwani used to issue opinions in accordance with the opinion of al-Khassaf, and to say that this is not a loan that generated profit, but is rather a sale that generated profit (Ibn ‘Abidin, Radd al-Muhtar ‘alal-Durr al-Mukhtar, [The Answer to the Confused] vol. 4, page 175) (5). There is another chapter [in the same work,] (6) titled “If the debtor repaid the debt or died before the maturity date, the amount of profit made through commercial credit should only be that part proportional to the elapsed period.” [This chapter] contains the following passage which is quoted from al-Qunya in the name of Najm al-Din: according to the later [jurists,] [if] the debtor repaid the debt before maturity or [if he] died and the debt was taken from his inheritance, the amount of profit on the commercial credit should be proportional to the elapsed number of days. Najm al-Din was asked if this was also his opinion. He replied that it was, and added that if the creditor took the loan and the relevant profit before the maturity date, the debtor has the right to retrieve that proportion pertaining to the remaining days. END [sic.] The commentator mentioned at the end of the book that this was [also] the opinion of the late jurisconsult Abul-Su‘ud, who justified it on the grounds of sympathy between both parties. I add that such was the opinion of al-Hanuti and others. And in the Hamidiyya opinions, he was asked if [a borrower] was indebted to [a lender] by an identified amount of debt and the latter charged the former a specific profit on that loan that was due at the end of a year, then the [borrower] died twenty days later and the loan became immediately repayable by the heir[s,] should any part of the related profit on the loan be paid? The answer of the later [jurists] was that nothing would be taken from the contracted profit except an amount proportional to the elapsed days. The knowledgeable Najm al-Din was asked whether he would issue his opinions accordingly, and he said he would. Our learned master of Anatolia, Abul-Su‘ud, has issued his opinions similarly. (7) Whoever reflects on these excerpts would find that they closely apply to the perceived dealings of al-Bank al-Watani and would verify that the profits of the [proposed] bank are religiously lawful. It is well known that profits on commercial credit had reached excessive rates of reportedly thirty and forty percent during the reign of the beloved Sultan Sulayman. As a result, the imperial edict was issued in accordance with the opinion of our master, the jurisconsult Abul-Su‘ud, that the repayment value of a loan of ten [units] should not exceed eleven and a half as mentioned by Ibn ‘Abidin (volume 4 page 175). [10. The Rescue of Peasants from Usurious Practices] The profits of the [proposed] bank will not [even] reach the limit specified in references on Islamic law (fifteen percent). Indeed, it might not exceed half of this [rate]. This is so because the prime concern of the bank is the public good and the alleviation of the peasant’s sufferings by rescuing him from the unfairness of usurers who enjoy the sweat of his brow and the riches of his lands. These usurers seize the peasant’s toil as a cold booty by lending him at the usurious rates of thirty and forty percent [per annum,] and more than that in many instances, against the mortgage of his land. When the date of repaying the loan falls due, and after their greedy appetite is sat- isfied by that sinful usury, they force him to sell his land to them at whatever price they impose. The peasant complies with this helplessly after being overburdened by usury, which drags him to the ground and blocks the doors of hope in his face. Whoever looks to the miserable status that the peasant reached, at a time when he is the life and backbone of the country, would ascertain that if this prevailed for a few [more] years, the ownership of the Egyptian lands or of most of it would be transferred to foreigners. Egypt’s son, God forbids, would then be reduced to an agricultural labourer on his and his ancestors’ own land. [11. The Bank as a Demonstration of the Revival of Egypt] But there will be no more reasons [to fear] such outcome once public subscription for al-Bank al-Watani alMisri starts. The bank, God willing, will be founded shortly. This will please some souls and depress others. Those who will be depressed are none but those whose souls are full of hatred. They want to deceive [our] countrymen and frustrate their efforts so that they can continue to impose their excessive usury on those citizens who need loans because they know that if al-Bank alWatani al-Misri is established, national business will be switched to it and they will be deprived from their excessive usury. We have seen them making unfounded claims that we are incapable of cooperating whether to avoid harm or to realize gain, accusing us of incompetence of establishing a national bank that would save our country from the sufferings caused by foreigners, [and basing these accusations] on the pretext of [alleged] ignorance, weakness, and poverty. The nationals will cut their tongues with a sharp sword, and they will taste this themselves, and will prove to them that the nation which was the origin of civilization and the educator of the world, since time immemorial, cannot be accused of ignorance after it rose to retrieve its previous glory and after it covered in a few years, towards the cause of civilization, a distance which no other nation achieved in generations. [The nationals will prove] that the lands which endured the inequity inflicted by the Mamluks and other warriors and conquered all of them, and which sustained the costs of wars and reforms undertaken by the beloved Muhammad ‘Ali Pasha, the first Khedive of Egypt(8), and which was not destroyed by taxes and various excessive payments of the previous days, [that nation] should not be accused of weakness and of poverty. [12. The Necessity of Public Subscription] But the responsibility of establishing our bank cannot be the obligation of an individual or even of a few individuals of the nation. It is the obligation of all nationals to unite and cooperate to found it, starting from the servant who [would] take one share to the rich master who [could] participate in the thousands. This is an advantage that would distinguish the bank from all other banks and would guarantee its complete success, because all countrymen will endeavor for that success and mobilize their efforts to attract people to it. All people will, no doubt, prefer it over any other bank because it is from them and for them: it will deal with them in their own tongue, and will treat their business with the same care they devote to it. 28 HITORICAL PERSPECTIVES [13. The National Bank and Economic Salvation] Furthermore, the bank will benefit the country in vital matters, and will enable countrymen to rescue many of the country’s interests, like the Domain and Saniyya lands (9), from foreigners’ hands. The initiation of efforts to establish the bank coincides with the rise of the country’s enlightened people and the mobilization of most of their efforts for this task. They have all determined that a national bank is the only intermediary that will enable them to accomplish their aspirations, since the existence of a trustworthy guarantor is inevitable should those interests be extracted from the hands of foreigners. This can only be fulfilled by al-Bank al-Watani. Countrymen should hurry and race with the founders in subscribing for the bank and participating in it. [14. The National Bank as a Profitable Project] We have frequently read in the national newspapers that the country will not bear the existing unfairness, and that it will undoubtedly rise to end it. These papers were reflecting the aspirations of all countrymen. It is evident, however, that we are addressing a cause of purely material nature, in which tangible money is the only thing that counts. If savings are not used in this way, what would their benefit be? But the founding of the bank will not deplete any such savings, since the bank’s capital will be commercially employed in a profitable manner for its owners and will generate public benefits for the entire country, namely salvation from financial enslavement to foreigners. Private gains become a secondary matter relative to this cause. These aspirations are not far fetched because effort and perseverance will guarantee the materialization of hope, and power is in unity. [15. The Significance of the East India Company] Whoever remembers that the British possessions in India—whose border-lines circumvent half of the globe and is among the world’s most fertile and most populated territories—were joined to the British dominions by the efforts of a company established at the beginning of the eighteenth century and initially capitalized at 30,000 pounds, would ascertain the validity of the argument made in this treatise regarding the benefits of association (al-ishtirak) and will also ascertain that the power of capital is through [employing it in] business (quwwat almal fil-a‘mal). [16. Conclusion: A Call to the Entire Nation] We hope that this example suffices to incite the willpower of those who have not yet moved to serve their country, and who ignor the power of unity. [May] it motivate everyone to support the establishment of al-Bank al-Watani and to collaborate in founding it. There can be no progress for the homeland without liberating the peasant from the injustice of usurers, and there can be no might or freedom for the state without extracting its interests from foreigners’ hands. Both ends will not be 29 achieved except through the operations of al-Bank alWatani al-Misri. Therefore, princes, elites the wealthy people of the country, and all those who care for her interests, are called upon to immediately follow the example of their good brothers who initiated the subscription, and to collaborate in establishing al-Bank alWatani al-Misri. Time is of gold, and cannot be retrieved if it elapsed. God awards success to whoever seeks His blessings and reward. END NOTES: 1. A more literal, and more cumbersome, translation has appeared as Appendix 2 in EzzelArab, European Control. In the present translation, I am trying to give preference to clarity of expression over literal accuracy without distorting the meaning. Also, the original text, annexed above, has very little punctuation. In the earlier translation, this is clearly revealed by insertions of punctuation marks within square brackets. This is omitted here in the interest of a less cumbersome form. Substantial additions of words, however, are here retained within square brackets. All aub-titles are my own insertions. 2. Note the word “yuthmir” or “to bear fruit” and its derivatives “yustathmar” and “thamar,” which are used here to describe the extraction of a physical outcome (“thamar” or fruit) from economic endeavours. In our present day usage, the word “istithmar,” which generically means the application of human effort to a given resource for the purpose of extracting a fruit, is the term used for “investment.” 3. The word naf‘, which I translated to “[private material] gain,” may be equivalent in our present day usage to the term “profit.” 4. Clearly, “Inma’ al-Mal” makes a distinction here between civil perfection and material satisfaction, although the terms of this distinction is unclear. 5. This passage is not indented in the original text, but it is inserted between quotation marks. The names in the indented passage refer to Muslim jurists. I opted for an abridged translation of Ibn ‘Abidin’s work. 6. The statement in the text is “There is a passage on page 171 of the same volume in the chapter titled ...” 7. Again, this passage is not indented, but is inserted between quotation marks. The names and titles in the passage refer to Muslim jurists and writers on Islamic law. I placed “borrower” and “lender” between square brackets. The original text follows the convention of using the Arabic names “Zayd” and “‘Amr” in referring to hypothetical individuals by way of giving some example. 8. This is an obvious historical error. The title Khedive was first given to Isma‘il (1863-1879) in 1867. Prior to this date, Muhammad ‘Ali and his ruling descendants carried the title of Wali (governor). The issuers of the manshur were surely aware of this. However, they might have used ‘Khedive’ by way of showing additional respect to the Muhammad ‘Ali family. 9. The Domain and Saniyya lands were originally royal estates that were taken as collateral against Egypt’s public debt in the 1870s. These estates were later sold to private landholders and contributed to the expansion in the property of the large. HISTORY IN THE MAKING Law and Economy in Egypt Socio-economic Realities of the New Parliament Zeinab Abul-Magd, PhD Candidate, Georgetown University “Through ‘law,’ the State…tends to create a social conformism which is useful to the ruling group’s line of development.” Antonio Gramsci, Prison Notebooks ovember and December 2005, witnessed violent parliamentary elections in Egypt, which resulted in a substantial change in the political map of lawmakers as well as the socio-economic structure of the People’s Assembly. Although, the National Democratic Party (NDP) kept the majority of seats, 88 deputies from the Muslim Brothers won, while the leftist and liberal opposition managed to win only 17 seats. The 2005 parliament marks the emergence of new realities that might affect the course of “economic reform” over the coming five years, with the continuity of the domination of the NDP’s businessmen, the existence of a considerable conservative opposition representing middle- to upper-class professionals, and the absence of adequate left-wing opposi tion representing the lower classes. By and large, the history of the socio-economic structure of lawmakers reflected the structure of the ruling elite and their economic interests in the Egyptian state since the parliament was first founded in the 19th century till today. This article attempts to trace the history of change in this structure throughout the last century up until the present. Then, it deconstructs the new parliament to depict a preliminary picture of the social background of lawmakers and how they might affect the course of economic change five years from now. Changing Elites, Economies and Laws N Egyptian Parlliment. Courtesy of www.meib.org/ images/0308_dem.jpg Egyptian Parlliment (closeup). Courtesy of weekly.ahram.org.eg/ 1999/426/ec1.jpg The Egyptian historian Ra’uf ‘Abbas indicates, “if Egypt before the 1952 revolution was ruled by landowning bourgeois, the businessmen lobby today dominates the party’s [NDP] structure and the parliamentary life…they control the process of presenting projects of new legislations and laws, previously dominated by technocrats.”(1) Egypt went through radical changes in its political economy since its first parliament was constituted in 1866. It passed through an agriculture-based liberal economy from late nineteenth to early twentieth century, a socialist economy and state capitalism under Nasser in the 1960s, the open door policy under Sadat, until it reached the era of the structural adjustment and economic reform from 1991 onwards. The socioeconomic structure of the parliament reflected the state’s political alliances and was tailored to fulfill the economic policy adopted by the ruling elite. It has been mainly family-based; the state coopted local big families whose economic interests met with its own. Even the official name of the parliament changed in a manner that is parallel to perceived visions of its role in economic life. In the late 19th century, when the country’s economy was centered around 30 HISTORY commercial agriculture, the “Consultative Congress of Deputies” was selected from elite families representing the Turko-Egyptian large landholders. Large landowners and the new industrial bourgeois formed the majority of the parliament deputies in the early 20th century, but they enjoyed no actual authority in legislation. Under the socialist state, Nasser set the socio-economic order of the “Nation’s Council” in accordance with his corporatist system, where the bureaucrats, technocrats, workers and peasants were the main players. However, the president and executives, rather than the parliament had the upper hand in lawmaking. The Sadat open-door policy necessitated the incorporation of a new elite of capital owners into the legislative body. The old elite of the socialist period allied itself with the new one to enact laws transforming the system. The “People’s Assembly,” from 1976 up until the 1980s, dominated by the newly founded National Democratic Party (NDP), was more of a supervisory than a legislative body, since the presidential system made it a collaborating rather than an autonomous institution. (2) Businessmen emerged as a leading group of lawmakers only in the late 1990s. They have since capitalized on the economic reform program to achieve personal interests that neither observe the dictates of a market economy nor enhance economic development. Enhancing development would have been done through promoting competitiveness as opposed to monopolies and expanding the job market rather than generating unemployment. In 1991 the agreements on macroeconomic stabilization and structural adjustment with the IMF and the World Bank deemed the old socio-economic structure of the Assembly unfit for the state’s economic policy; a new elite had to be co-opted to work on promulgating necessary legislations. Eberhard Kenlie notes that, “a limited number of owners of capital saw their liberties extended and their position reinforced…it is difficult to see how the regime could do without them and not co-opt them in one way or another.”(3) Consequently, promulgated laws enhanced the benefits of capital owners at the expense of workers, peasants and the middle class. For example, Law No. 203 of 1991 that gave legal leeway for privatization of the public sector led to the sale of profitable state-owned 31 IN THE MAKING enterprises to businessmen at belowmarket prices. On the other hand, the same law allowed laying off hundreds of thousands of workers only to join the unemployed(4). Similarly, Law No. 96 of 1992 librated the agricultural land rents and led to the evacuation of around a million peasants from their plots for the benefit of old and new elite of large landowners (5). The laws of privatization and the reduction of subsidies led to a decline in the standard of living of the middle-classes, which is shrunk while poverty continued to mount (6). In 1995, 37 new businessmen joined the Assembly. The parliament included a total of 66 businessmen, 59 of whom belonged to the NDP. The number of businessmen in the 2000 parliament increased to 71 members among whom were 30 big businessmen. Gamal Mubarak’s and his associated business elite like Ahmad ‘Izz and Muhammad Abu al-‘Ainin, appeared in the last Assembly as main players. Heading important legislative committees, such as the Planning and Budget, the Economic, and the Industrial committees, they interfered heavily to enact laws pertaining to privatization that served their own interests (7). Ahmad AlSayyid al-Naggar illustrates that they imposed their vision on government executives in drafting laws, such as labor, mortgage, and tax laws(8). For example, the Egyptian Unified Labor Law No. 12 for 2003 maximizes the rights of the enterprise owner at the expense of the rights of the worker. It allows business owners to terminate labor contracts whenever they wish for unspecified reasons. The new Tax Law No. 91 of 2005 places all businesses that earn more than LE 40, 000 per annum under the same category. This allows large businesses that make millions of pounds annually to be subject to insignificant tax rates and yet benefit from all industrial and commercial public services that petty businesses and the lower classes pay for from their small pockets. Similarly, the new anti-trust laws did not lay out enough regulations to end the monopolies that already exist in certain sectors whose owners partake in drafting the laws, such as Ahmad Izz (9). In addition, businessmen keep the legislative agenda busy with law projects that they would benefit from, and block other law projects that might benefit workers, peasants and the middle class from being discussed (10). Laws relevant to privatization and agricultural land tenure were enacted in spite of the objections of the few opposition members who represent the disadvantaged lower classes. From the leftist opposition parties, there were only two Nasseri deputies and six from the Tajammu‘. They raised fierce arguments about the aforementioned laws, but the voice of the NDP majority prevailed (11). Deconstructing the New Parliament In the new Assembly of 2005, the list of the NDP lawmakers consists of businessmen, government bureaucrats, and former security and army officers. While the NDP won 320 seats after it admitted independents, the Muslim Brothers (MBs) won 88 seats. The opposition parties retained a totality of only 17 seats, including six from the Wafd, two from the Tajammu‘, and two Nasserists but no one from the Nasseri party. The social background of the deputies of each political camp is genuinely distinct: old and new elite of businessmen and landowners belong mainly to the NDP and the Wafd liberal party, and they control around 50 per cent of the “...After the recent enactment of the laws of taxation, investment, and labor has given leeway to businessmen to avoid their dues to public services and limit the rights of workers, more laws related to the programme of economic reform are waiting to be issued....” HISTORY seats after their number in the Assembly has doubled. Middle- and upper class doctors, engineers and other professionals belong to the MBs and a few middle- to low-class deputies belong to the left-wing opposition. No doubt that this social/political anatomy of the new parliament will affect the economic legislations in the coming five years. Outside large urban constituencies such as those of Cairo, the criteria of running and winning were family and clan based – regardless of political inclinations – for the NDP, the Muslim Brothers, and the opposition runners alike. Candidates of all political affiliations relied in voting on their hometowns, since they belonged to wealthy or reputable families some of which have kept parliamentary seats since the late 19th century. They provided community and charitable services in their own villages or places of origin, such as erecting schools and clinics or distributing foodstuff and clothes. There is no space for advocating any political agendas in such an environment. In addition, instants of bribery are numerous in the case of the NDP candidates, while some MBs candidates bought votes through distributing charitable items in villages and poor neighborhoods (12). The NDP’s wealthy elite is far from being a homogenous group. It consists of the very traditional elite of provincial and rural wealthy families, the conservative old guards surviving from previous regimes, and the new businessmen elite affiliated with Gamal Mubarak’s Lajnat al-Siyasat (The High Council for Policies) in the party. The latter group has gained enormous political power since the late 1990s, and it is the most assertive about liberalizing the economy. Gamal Mubarak and the business elite affiliated to his council attempted to construct a popular image during the electoral campaign, but they faced harsh failure and they ended up irritating the public in the constituencies they visited with immature political discourse and lead to the failure of the candidates they meant to support (13). Therefore, observers insist that the old guard has regained some of their lost power against the new business elite(14). At any rate, old and new capitalists in this legislature managed the vote through bribery; they spent millions to win seats and employed thugs to intimidate and threaten voters. Their declared agenda was designed for their own business interests (15). The for mation of the central legislative com- IN THE mittees still reflect the domination of the Lajnat al-Siyasat group, since Ahmad Izz has been nominated once more to head the Planning and Budgetary Committee and Muhammad Abu al-Inin is heading the Industry and Power Committee. The old and new elite will most probably collide, which might affect the acceleration of the course of economic reform one way or another. Although the current contr oversy about significant representation of the Muslim Brothers (MBs) in the new Assembly shows concern about the potential negative impact they might leave on economic reform, the socioeconomic structure of those members and their political discourse indicate that their effect will probably be less radical than imagined. The MBs bloc is composed of middle- to upper-class professionals such as doctors and engineers, who form the MBs prominent members(16). Their vision of the needs of the lower classes has a charitable character framed by an “alms-giving” perception of economic development. In general, their political rhetoric pays more attention to cultural/religious issues. Matters such as confronting corrupt businessmen or defending the rights of workers, peasants, and the middle class harmed by new privatization laws hardly appear in their discourse, as opposed to the issue of application of shari‘a law and political freedom. This is evident in their performance in the last Assembly, as their fifteen members focused their political battles on banning books or movies deemed violating Islamic law. In addition they argued for limiting women’s legal rights, rejecting American grants, prohibiting the import of meat not slaughtered according to shari‘a from the US and Europe, prohibiting dancing schools, prohibiting bank interests and similar matters (17). The post-election political rhetoric of the MBs leaders in 2005 is no exception to the aforementioned general trend. They campaign for changing the constitution, insuring that courts work in conformity with shari‘a law, banning alcohol and gambling, etc¸ (18). Furthermore, their current economic agenda is oriented toward charity, as apparent in their tactics of penetrating poor neighborhoods through discount clinics and educational centers besides large-scale alms giving on religious occasions. For example, they ask the rich to support the poor through providing free health and social sup- MAKING “...The socioeconomic structure of the parliament reflected the state’s political alliances and was tailored to fulfill the economic policy adopted by the ruling elite....” port for the disabled and the unemployed (19). This agenda does not seem to pose substantial threats to any potential NDP plans to enact new laws supporting the business elites’ vested interests. In terms of the MBs campaigns against corruption, some observers doubt such claim because the MBs themselves followed the example of the NDP members in mobilizing votes through bribery in some cons t i t u e n c i e s (20) . After winning, MBs fought for heading the education, health, and human rights legislative committees, but they succeeded in heading the health committee only. Some sources allege that the NDP will utilize the MBs to pass new controversial laws in economic reform using their fatawa or religious support to appease the public(21). The scandalous defeat of the leftist opposition parties, the Tajammu‘ and the Nasseri in particular, left no serious challenges to the NDP’s capitalists in the Assembly. The opposition’s political rhetoric insists that fraud was a means deployed by the State to fail its candidates, including their leaders, while independent observers affirm that the defeat is attributed to entrenched internal weaknesses in the parties. Only two Tajammu‘ deputies, from the constituencies of Cairo and Giza, won to 32 HISTORY IN THE “... Outside large urban constituencies such as those of Cairo, the criteria of running and winning were family and clan based – regardless of political inclinations – for the NDP, the Muslim Brothers, and the opposition runners alike....” represent the interests of workers and peasants, and they are not even as outspoken as their two former deputies who lost their seats in Alexandria and Port Said. The two leaders of the two parties, Dia’ al Din Dawud and Khalid Muhyi al-Din, failed to maintain their seats, and thus serious objections to new economic reform legislations will substantially decline. Leftist opposition in the previous Assemblies was weak, but at least some politically active figures were there to question the power of businessmen. As for now, Muhammad Abd al-Aziz Sha‘ban, one of the two Tajammu‘ deputies, stated that the role of the secular opposition will be more active in interrogating the ministers and monitoring the government policy rather than playing a role in drafting laws (22). As for the agenda of the Wafd liberal party, it raises issues of corruption and political development, but it does not go far in criticizing the economic reform program compared to the leftist parties. Its deputies do not genuinely represent the social classes that are negatively affected by the new laws of market economy. The head of the Wafd representatives, Dr. Mahmud Abaza, is an upper-class pro- 33 MAKING fessional who relied in winning his seat on the traditional power of his family of large landholders in Lower Egypt. The agenda of another Wafdist, Muhammad Shurdi from the Port Said constituency, focuses on the rights of merchants in the free trade zone in the port(23). After the recent enactment of the laws of taxation, investment, and labour has given leeway to businessmen to avoid their dues to public services and limit the rights of workers, more laws related to the programme of economic reform are waiting to be issued. For example, new regulations with regard to privatization, restructuring the pension and insurance schemes, and reforming the financial sector are expected to appear. If elite businessmen continue to be the only powerful group dominating economic affairs in the Assembly, while the leftist opposition is considerably weak and the middle- or upper class MBs are chanting with a charitable vision of development, the new parliament will continue enacting laws serving the elite businessmen at the expense of other segments of the Egyptian society. Biased and unbalanced regulations should severely disrupt the course of economic development in an already underdeveloped country. They have evidently led to lowering growth rates, increasing the budget deficit, and raising unemployment and poverty rates. The socio-economic structure of the new Assembly demonstrates that no radical change is likely to take place in the short term, as the new deputies’ agendas pay little or no attention to issues such as job creation, labor migration, or agricultural land tenure. In such a political climate, economic development seems far from being an attainable goal. END NOTES: 1. Al-‘Arabi, 4 April 2004. 2. See: Al-Sayyid Yasin (et. al.), Al-Ittijahat alJadida fi Majlis al-Sha‘b (Cairo : Markaz alDirasat al-Siyasiyya wa-al-Istratijiyya, 1976), pp. 14-21; Noha El-Mikawy, “The Egyptian Parliament and Transition to Liberal Democracy,” American Arab Affairs, no. 36 (Spring 1991), pp. 19-21. 3. Eber hard Kienle, A Grand Delusion: Democracy and Economic Reform in Egypt (London: I.B.Tauris, 2001), p. 130. 4. See: Nahid ‘Izz al-Din ‘Abd al-Fattah, Al‘Ummal wa-Rijal al-A‘mal: Tahawwulat alFuras al-Siyasiyya fi Misr (Cairo: Markaz alDirasat al-Siyasiyya wa-al-Istratijiyya, 2003). 5. See: The Land Center for Human Rights Peasants’ Report, Cairo, October 2004. 6. C.f: Dina Shehata and Manal Lutfi, “AlTabaqa al-Wusta wa-al-Dawla fi Misr,”Ahwal Misriyya, No.1, Summer 1998; Muhammad al-Sayyid Sa‘id, “Ahwal alTabaqa al-Wusta,” Ahwal Misriyya, No.1, Summer 1998. 7. Kienle, A Grand Delusion, p.59; Haytham Jabr, “Rijal al-A‘mal wa-al-Siyasa fi Misr,” Ahwal Misriyya, No.21, Summer 2003, pp.134-135; ‘Amr Hashim Rabi‘, “Rijal alA‘mal wa-Tashri‘at al-Khaskhasa,” Qadaya Barlamaniyya, No.40, July 2000. pp.6-11. For more details about Mubarak the son’s political coalition of businessmen see: Mohamed Menza, “Gamal Mubarak and Egypt’s NeoBusiness Community,” Chronicles, vol.1, no.2, pp. 33-36. 8. Al-Ahali, 21 September 2005. 9.For details and other examples see: Ahmad al-Sayyid Al-Naggar (ed.), Taqrir alIttijahat al-Iqtisadiyya, 2005 (Cairo: Markaz al-Dirasat al-Siyasiyya wa-al-Istratijiyya, 2005), pp. 309-315, The Land Center For Human Rights’ biannual reports on workers. 10. The Land Center for Human Rights Workers’ Report, Cairo, October 2003. 11. ‘Rabi‘, “Rijal al-A‘mal,” pp.6-11. 12. C.f. The Land Center for Human Rights’ Election Monitoring Reports, November/December 2005. 13. Ibid; Al-Arabi, 11 December 2005; Sawt al-’Umma, 12 December 2005. 14. William Wallis, “A Problem Putting Promise into Practice” Financial Times, 6 December 2005. 15. Al-Ahram Weekly, 8 December 2005; AlAhali, 2 November 2005. 16. Afaq ‘Arabiyya, 15 December 2005. 17. http://www.ikhwanonline.com/Article. asp?ID=14787&SectionID=496; Al-Ahram, 9 December 2005. 18. The Daily Star Egypt, 9 December 2005. 19. Al-Hayat, 13 December 2005. 20. C.f. The Land Center for Human Rights’ Election Monitoring Reports, November/December 2005. 21. Al-Ahali, 7 December 2005; Nahdat Misr, 11 December 2005. 22. Al-Masri al-Yawm, 12 December 2005. 23. Nahdat Misr, 19 Decmeber 2005. HISTORY IN THE MAKING Skirmishes in The War for Drugs A Report on "Egyptian Pharmaceuticals & TRIPs" Seminar Mostafa Hefny, Project Officer, EBHRC. T he devil really is in the details. The big picture is one of dramatic opposition. In the popular imagination, the battle line is cruel and stark. On one side is a corporate-governmental alliance, on the other are two billion people in the developing world without consistent access to vital medication - more often represented, if at all, by nongovernmental organization rather their own governments. Those governments have been reintegrated into a world economic system whose rules have been laid and are enforced by the ravenous alliance. In offices far above the population the system summons an arsenal of legal chains and mantraps that are finally distilled into that most odious of documents: The Patent. This representation maybe lacking in nuance, but not irony. If the enforcement of the new world economic system has been cruel in its insistence on the dismantling of social welfare systems in the countries of the south in favor of unbridled market capitalism, the maneuverings of this battle have reduced representatives of the poor to begging for the mercy of the market. Along with a parallel, and not entirely separate, North-South confr ontation over agricultural subsidies in Europe and the United States, the representatives of the poor seem to be clinging to rules laid out by the industrialized world – only for them to change their minds and demand a welfare program for a group of multinational pharmaceutical companies who oversee a 450 billion dollar industry that is the world's most profitable business. On those terms the battle quickly becomes apocalyptic. The representatives of the poor, be they the nongovernmental organizations or the occasional government, can only escape the repercussions of this arrangement by dismantling the patent system – the very paste that holds the whole apparatus together. If, as the multinational pharmaceutical companies continue to argue, patents are necessary for the development of vital medicines, then the only situation drugs maybe made accessible to the poor is one where there are no drugs to begin with. For those concerned with the welfare of the populations of the south – not to mention the local pharmaceutical industries under increasing pressure to halt production of generic versions of patented drugs – the task is one of rev- olution, not tactical adaptation. If this big picture is really an accurate depiction than clearly the whole debate currently underway is little more than nuisance to the multinational companies whose victory has been declared by this narrative – which has been ostensibly one of protest. The fact of the matter is the confrontation continues. But if the big picture scenario leads to a dead end, a closer consideration of the tributaries of this conflict my yield a fresh narrative stream. One such tributary is Egypt where, as of the 1st of January of 2005, the WTO Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPs) came into effect. The signs of substantive repercussions of the enforcement of the agreement on the pharmaceutical sector became evident in the press early in the year with consumers and then pharmacists inundating the press with complaints that price of medicine had suddenly skyrocketed – including those required for the treatment of chronic diseases. As noteworthy of the number of complaints was the avenue. Indeed the business daily, Al-Alam Al-Yawm-- normally a staunch supporter of every step towards capitalist integration--privati- 34 HISTORY IN zation undertaken by the Prime Minister Ahmad Nazif's government, published a number of these grievances. The frequency of commentary on the subject was such that it was indicative of important, and perhaps permanent, changes in Egyptian pharmaceuticals. The nature of the changes then became the subject of a seminar on "Egyptian Pharmaceuticals & TRIPs," organized on the 19th of September 2005 by the Economic and Business History Research Center as the first in its new “History in the Making” seminar sessions. The speakers, sought to represent differing points of view, were, first, Mr. Ahmed El-Hakim the "Regional External Affairs and Policy Director" of Pfizer. The company, a global behemoth, is the largest pharmaceutical multinational in Egypt with LE 300 million in investments and ambitious plans to expand. Mr. ElHakim was quoted in the press prior to the session explaining his company's intentions of increasing the size of its investments in Egypt to LE 700 million over the next few years and further build on its 7 % share in the fragmented Egyptian market, which is currently worth 1.3 billion dollars annually. Also present was Mr. Hossam Bahgat, the director of the Egyptian Initiative for Personal Rights (EIPR), an NGO whose pioneering Health and Human Rights program had recently published a policy paper entitled “The TRIPS Agreement and Egypt’s Responsibility to Protect the Right to Health”. Concluding the list of speakers was Dr. Mohamed Raouf Hamed a noted professor of pharmacology at the National Organization for Drug Control and Research and frequent commentator on the sector. Dr. Hamed had recently completed a booklet in which he offered an analysis of what he identified as a crisis in Egyptian pharmaceuticals. The case for the multinationals began in economic terms. Respect for intellectual property rights as represented by the TRIPs agreement is one of the vital components of creating a healthy business environment, argued ElHakim. Egypt, he asserted, needs 8 – 10 billion dollars annually in order to create between 700 thousand and 800 thousand jobs a year, a figure unattainable except by foreign investment such as that carried out by Pfizer Corp. Such investments, whether in infrastructure or in the development of new drugs, is contingent on the protection of intellectual property rights. 35 THE MAKING Reverting to a prepared presentation, El-Hakim gave an overview of the medical leaps made by humanity in the course of the 20th century. Citing the elimination of diseases such as Polio and Small Pox as global health threats, he lauded the initiative of private enterprise as the engine behind this unambiguous progress in decreased death rates around the world. Indeed, he attributed 90 % of all new medicines to private enterprise, a process composed of three demarcated steps: discovery, synthesis and formulation. The first of these steps, discovery, is the most important – dependent as it is on investments in research and development. El- Hakim then described four stages in the bringing of a new drug to the market, which are completed upon a positive answer to the following four questions: 1- Will the proposed drug address an unmet medical need? 2- Is it possible to produce the proposed drug in a laboratory? 3- Is it possible to conduct clinical trials on patients? 4- Is there a sufficient return on investment? The world's base of biomedical knowledge expands through the investment of either government-funded research initiative in national health institutes and universities or the independent research of private corporations such as that which El-Hakim represents. The mapping of the human genome has exponentially increased the possibilities of discovering new medicines but has, in turn, increased the costs of research and any resultant discoveries. The process begins with a consideration of more than 7 million molecules and all the possible permutations and linkages with other compounds and genes and is narrowed down, 12 to 15 years and "on average" 800 million dollars later, to one or two compounds. It is a process whose primary feature is failure and elimination of compounds whose potential has gone unfulfilled despite large investments. Even when a drug successfully navigates the obstacle course to the market, a significant risk remains with people’s reception of the drug. There will always be a percentage of drugs that, despite clinical trials and regulatory approval, must be recalled – with the attendant cost of such a recall, which must be absorbed entirely by the pharmaceutical company. It is these investments and the arduous- ness of the development of the final product – including years of clinical trials – that have been taken into account by authorities in their formulation of legal protections in the form of patents. The world has developed an incentive system to encourage this process and help alleviate the aforementioned impediments – the incentive system has been the protection of undisclosed trade secrets with patents. For Egypt, El- Hakim highlighted several important dates in the protection of intellectual property rights – the government's joining of the WTO in 1994. Egypt exercised its right to a five year "grace period" until 2000 when it was obliged to protect undisclosed "trade secrets". A further five year grace period was granted up to the year 2005 when complete protection was mandated by TRIPs. El- Hakim stressed that it is only with complete compliance with the protections of intellectual property rights that companies such as Pfizer may move some of their development activities to Egypt, and added that such compliance is already stipulated in Egyptian Law 82 of 2002 and is not only enforced by the new obligations under TRIPs. This, he argued, would help alleviate Egypt comparatively poor exports of pharmaceuticals, which in 2004 amounted to a mere 41 million dollars compared 261 million dollars for neighboring Jordan. Ahmed El-Hakim concluded his remarks by expressing confidence in the government of Ahmad Nazif and its willingness to implement its obligations as mandated in the agreement. But it was this very government that “... the system summons an arsenal of legal chians [..] that are finally distilled into the most odious document; The Patent....” HISTORY IN THE MAKING was addressed, in a more critical light, by Hossam Bahgat of the Egyptian Initiative of Personal Rights (EIPR), whose robust counterargument was, surprisingly, centered on a call to Egyptian authorities to implement the TRIPs agreement as written!Bahgat demarcated the divergence in bases and goals of his organization and a company such as Pfizer on the matter of public health and intellectual property. Intellectual property rights had never been targeted as an area of study or advocacy by EIPR – but as an organization concerned with the law and the legal framework surrounding issues of health and human rights it became imperative to engage the laws through which the state is required to protect its citizenry's health – or to put is more accurately, the citizenry's right to health. International law does not mandate state protection of citizens against contacting disease, but their access to health care in the case of ailment. For his part, Bahgat also provided four criteria with which the state's obligation to uphold the "right to health" is judged. In sum, the criteria are legal test for the existence of this right: 1- The quality of products and service provided 2- The acceptability of the products and service to the patients 3- The availability of the products and service to patients 4- The accessibility of products and services to patients. This in turn maybe split into two types of accessibility: access to information regarding the product and service (in this case the drug) and physical access to the drug itself. Regarding intellectual property rights and the pharmaceutical industry, it is the third and fourth criteria that are of paramount importance. Availability and accessibility are considered in terms of whether there is discrimination between the rural and urban population and between rich and poor. The key determinant to the satisfaction of both of these criteria is the question of affordability. Hence, in considering the question of intellectual property it is to this concern that an organization such as EIPR must turn. For EIPR, the concer n with intellectual property is narrowed to the question of whether its application results in medicine becoming unavailable or otherwise out of reach of those who need it. In the balance are other concerns such as employment and return on investment, which figures announced by El-Hakim with figures of his own, referring to the evident case of HIV AIDS medication which had cost 10, 000 dollars to meet the annual needs of a single patient, a figure that has fallen dramatically to a mere 200 dollars when chemically identical generics became available. The point here is not only the price discrepancy, but that this discrepancy exists with regards to an unsubstitutable life saving drug. Hence, in considering intellectual property rights, Bahgat asserted, an abstract argument cannot stand aloof of a reality whence there are creditor nations and debtors – where a third of the world's population is without access to basic medication. This reality includes other figures: 14 million people die yearly of infectious diseases – of those, 9 out of 10 live in developing countries. The cover of Raouf Hamed’s publication The Structure and Legal Underpinnings of the Egyptian Pharmacuetical Sector in the Context and International Trade Agreements: A Strategic Vision are the avenue of those who represent other interests, such as Mr. El- Hakim. Those concerns must always be weighed against the availability and accessibility of drugs. This, explained Bahgat, represents a significantly different approach to the question of intellectual property rights and their impact on Egyptian pharmaceuticals. The theory outlined by El-Hakim and other representatives of multinational firms is a form of contract between those who discover a drug and the public. The former agree to grant access by the public to the drug in return for remuneration over and above that which they would have received had they not been in possession of a patent. That is the theory and accounts for the historical development of intellectual property leading up to the TRIPs agreement, which, Bahgat added, is essentially an organizing mechanism for this process in the form a commercial contract. In the real world no argument can be made against the assertion that patents raise the price of drugs. An inquiry about the degree to which that price elevation affects the availability and accessibility of vital medication must then be made. The unique characteristic of medicine as a product – insofar as its consumption is seldom a manner of qualitative choice but of urgent need – must be made clear. Bahgat offered to counter some of the Bahgat proceeded to supply more figures. The first was a demonstration of the portion of national budgets spent on medication, which in the developed world is never more than 20 %, whereas the figure is often as high as 66 % in the developing world. Moreover the portion of that spending borne by the population, rather than a state funded welfare system, is between 50 to 90% in the developing world. The figures are inclusive of Egypt but not exclusive to it. The problem is one of North and South, and it is significant that none of the great multinationals that today control the global pharmaceutical industry are located in the developing world. The weight of these figures then makes striking the balance between the private interests of the drug companies and the public interest manifest in the right to health all the more important. Such a balance was struck, in Bahgat's view, in the Doha declaration of 2001 in which the WTO recognized the danger posed by the TRIPs agreement to public health. From that declaration, Bahgat offered the following quote: "The TRIPs agreement does not, and should not, prevent member countries [from] undertaking measure to protect public health". Indeed, the TRIPs agreement provides sufficient flexibilities for member states to intervene when a drug is unavailable or inaccessible to a portion of its population – even when that inaccessibility is due to expensive prices of drugs under patent- by providing "compulsory licenses" to domestic producers to manufacture generic version of expensive drugs still under patent protection. 36 HISTORY IN THE The flexibilities, stressed Bahgat, are not limited to medical emergencies – but to a broadly defined "public health concern". Yet, these flexibilities as soon as they were asserted in Doha came under severe attack from another organization, the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO), a specialized United Nations agency separate from the WTO. This organization introduced Substantive Patent Law Treaty (SPLT), a proposed international patent law treaty in which the room for maneuver available for the governments of the developing world is greatly reduced. Still the SPLT is not the most immediate danger to public health in the developing world, but rather the Free Trade Agreements currently sought by the United States and a number of countries of the South, Egypt among them. A component of this agreement will be legislation on data exclusivity – the data to which El-Hakim had referred to as "undisclosed trade secrets". This, argued Bahgat, would be a deathblow to the production of generic medicine. Under data exclusivity measures and attendant exclusive marketing rights, domestic produces in the developing world would not be allowed to assert the clinical safety and efficacy of generic versions of out-ofpatent products unless they conduct their own clinical trials similar in scope to those originally conducted by the multinational. They will not be allowed to cite the original drug's approval by regulatory bodies to produce a generic version. Hence even after the patent protection is removed the production of a generic version, given the costs of clinical trials and testing, will become economically unfeasible in the developing world. These measures are now part of a “TRIPs Plus” package included in all proposed bilateral Free Trade Agreements. They do not only point to the medically unethical practice of conducting test on human subjects even when the results had already been established many years earlier but amount, in practical terms, to a patent for drugs whose patents had already lapsed. Finally, Bahgat cast doubt of the oftmade assertion that patent protection is vital for the funding of multinational's research and development – an assertion he described as a "lazy argument". The African market, which accounts for little more than 1 % of the global market, would not significantly affect profit margins of multinationals that spend 37 MAKING more on marketing than on research and development. Moreover, evidence from organizations such as "Doctors Without Borders" suggests that the criteria of return on investments is the primary mover behind the allocation of resources of such companies. This organization's "Working Group on Neglected Diseases" concluded that the most common diseases to the African continent receive little or no attention from global pharmaceutical industry given the low purchasing power of its population. Ahmad El-Hakim denied the existence of TRIPs Plus provisions. He was not, however, aided in his defense by Professor Mohamed Raouf Hamed of National Organization for Drug Control and Research who, citing his own studies and others, challenged the costs multinationals claim to bear in the development of new drugs. The figure suggested by Hamed is indeed a little less than 10 % of the figure announced by multinationals i.e. around 70 million dollars rather than the 800 million stated by El-Hakim. He pointed to the role of combinatorial chemistry (the synthesis of molecules in a combinatorial fashion can quickly lead to large numbers of molecules) in exponentially increasing the amount of possible compounds from which new drugs are developed – the result is an overstated number of new compounds to which a firm lays claim. The exaggerated claims of the technical difficulty in the development of new drugs and the inflated costs declared by dominant multinationals is part of an organized effort to construct a psychological barrier to potential competition from smaller firms in the South. Yet, as critical as he was of companies such Pfizer, and their claims, Hamed also criticized the vision – or lack thereof – on the part of local “... The frequency of commentary on the subject [of TRIPS] was such that it was indicative of important changes in Egyptian pharmaceuticals...” industry. Egyptian pharmaceuticals are a conservative sector still imbued with the 1960s mentality of import substitution, which, appropriate then, is out of sync with the requirements of an era of exposure. The very nature of the industry mandates that the approach be progressive, that it aim to generate the greatest possible value added or otherwise fade to oblivion. Hamed likened the Egyptian pharmaceutical industry to a lone King piece of chess board, continuously being checked by a vast ly superior force, moving from one square to the next hoping only for the most ephemeral stay of execution. In 2000, Hamed was summoned by members of the National Academy for Scientific Research to advise its members on their negotiations of intellectual property rights with several foreign parties. Hamed conditioned his participation on the Egyptian side presenting an alternative plan to ignite the domestic pharmaceutical sector. When this demand was disr egarded, Hamed declined to participate – concluding then, and now, that Egyptian pharmaceuticals are in a state of "strategic retardation". Hamed's damning judgment of local industry brings to fore some of the unexamined elements of this narrative. In considering the state of uncertainty to which Egyptian phar maceuticals and the masses that depend on them have sunk in 2005, perhaps a more traditional consideration of the development of this industry in Egypt is now in order. One could perhaps account for the odd pensiveness of local drug companies – and the vagueness of the position of some of the larger firms. A follow up to this seminar must include a representative of local industry. It is noteworthy that much of the protest against the implementation of the TRIPs agreement and the prospective TRIPs Plus provisions has come from the Pharmacists' Syndicate and patients rather than local firms. This anomaly is likely to lead us back to the political economy of Egypt – and the accelerated frenzy with which businessmen, who now hold all of key ministerial posts in government, have veined the executive and legislative apparatus. It may well be the case that the local pharmaceutical industry is part of the portfolio of the very same interests who ar e now pushing to topple the last remaining chess piece. That is the big picture. Let us now consider the details. HISTORY IN THE MAKING Chinese Boom The Real Estate Lee Nunley, Economics major, University of Colorado. ne of the hottest trends in real estate investment today has become the Chinese urban market. There are manifold reasons for this shift in investment but as with most booms, this one is motivated by one factor: money. With cities like Shanghai becoming some of the most expensive real estate markets in the world it is not surprising that foreign and domestic investment is high and that new high-rises are springing up all over urban China. O This real estate boom may be good news for the Chinese economy, but it does raise many questions for the developmental economist. With the prices of houses rising in cities, can ordinary Chinese citizens still afford to live in urban centers? Furthermore what sort of implications does this real estate boom have for those living in rural areas? Will the Chinese economy become more dichotomous with soaring real estate prices? What role do foreign investors and businesses play in this real estate expansion? Where does all of the money for the development of these areas go? Essentially, what is the effect of this boom on ordinary citi zens? And, just as important for the financier lying dormant inside every developmental economist as for the developmental economist himself, is this boom a bubble? To answer the preceding questions it is necessary to delve into many periphery aspects of the Chinese economy. Also, since this boom is still being played out it is important to look at the economies of other states that have undergone similar changes in output, that is to say some of the NICs (Newly Industrialized Countries). Let’s begin with a brief history of real estate and the market in China. “... Of New Fortune Magazine’s list of the 500 richest Chinese citizens, 94 of them are in the real estate business...” A Recent History of Real Estate in China Though it is now possible for people to own their own homes in China (or at least practically own them through long term land leases that allow tenancy on land which is all owned by the state), such was not always the case. Private ownership of homes in both rural and urban China was legal until the Cultural Revolution during the late 1960’s. After the Cultural Revolution, a split developed between the rural and urban real estate markets and forms of ownership. In the rural areas, private ownership continued as the normal means of land tenancy. The cities switched to two other paradigms of tenancy, neither were private ownership. One was employer-provided housing, which is pretty self-explanatory - a person’s employer owned their housing and in return the employee paid a small rent, which was hugely subsidized by his or her employer. According to Yanrui Wu in China’s Consumer Revolution, this method was extraordinarily inefficient because of issues involving labor mobility, retired workers and the subsidies paid for housing employees (1). The other provider of urban housing was the government, which “it is estimated provided about 15 to 20 percent of urban housing.” In the urban centers in China, a series of developments in housing reforms took place starting in the late 1980’s when China was shifting to a more market based economy. Most of these reforms were aimed at changing from employer and state provided housing market to an individually owned private property market. By the mid 1990’s, most of China’s housing in the urban market had been converted to private property, with some of it going to employees where employers formerly provided housing and some of it being sold to the public by the state. What these market reforms led to was a booming real estate market. The boom was augmented by the substantial lack of appropriate housing demanded by the Chinese; especially after the market system took over and helped to 38 HISTORY IN THE increase the income of urban Chinese citizens. In fact, “the average living space per capita in urban China increased from 3.6 to 7.1 square meters during the period 1978-92. This figure has increased to 8.5 in 1996.” (2). Such a large change over a period of just 18 years is significant enough to imply that a boom must have occurred After all, a three-fold increase in the amount of housing real estate is indicative of significant growth in construction. Rural housing, which was consistently privately owned throughout the 20th century, continued developing while urban housing stagnated due to inefficient distribution. In 1996 the average amount of housing in rural China was 21.7 square meters per capita, three times the per capita housing in urban China in 1996 (3). The reasons for this discrepancy are not very well documented in the literature on development but one of the major components is the value of space in rural versus domestic situations. Since urban space is limited, thusly more expensive (in terms of opportunity cost since the state owned all the land), it was more effective to build smaller dwellings, which in the context of the free market China with higher incomes, were less appealing for citizens. So part of the housing boom is a result of the lag in housing size and quality that was borne of the inefficiencies of the Communist regime’s housing policies in urban China. Also private owners in rural areas had incentives to increase home sizes whereas renters in urban areas did not, given that in the long run any investment they made would not be returned. Commercial real estate was also underdeveloped up until the early 1990’s, “non-residential buildings in urban areas have accounted for more than a half of the total floor space of buildings completed during 19851996.” (4) This growth is indicative of an increased business sector in need of office space, which makes sense given the privatization of industries during the conversion to a market-based system in the early 90’s, when the government privatized 60% of industry throughout the country. The trend of office building has however diminished somewhat in the last 10 years. “The share of nonresidential buildings over the total floor space completed by the urban nonstate sector in 1995 was less than 50 percent for the first time. This declining 39 MAKING trend is to continue in the future partly because of the government’s desire to develop residential housing. As the office and luxury apartment market becomes more crowded, the residential housing sector will gradually become the dominant player in the Chinese real estate market. ”(5) Wu’s prediction may have just recently started coming true. Other Trends Contributing to the Housing Boom Besides housing reform, other trends in China’s economy have helped to create the current real estate boom that is prevalent in Chinese cities. Key to the real estate boom has been the inexpensive mortgage rates kept low by high savings rates in China (45% of income by some estimates). Of course, without the increase in income for the Chinese citi zenry the high savings rates that have helped fuel this boom wouldn’t be possible, and for the income to have increased so much the economy had to grow at an extraordinary rate. Currently, the Chinese economy’s GDP is growing at a rate of around 8% per year, a rate similar to that of South Korea and other NICs during their rapid development in the early 1990’s (6). This has helped push the average per capita income up over 16% in just the last 10 years. Much of this income has been saved in banks, which has helped to lower the semi-free-floating inter est rate to about 5%, near the stated goal of the People’s Bank of China (PBC). This low interest rate has allowed many Chinese to purchase their own homes. In some urban areas home ownership is around 60% for newly developed commercial housing (7). Domestic migration from rural to urban centers has also spurred an increase in the demand for urban housing. It is estimated that by 2020 up to 220 million rural Chinese will move to towns and cities (8). Foreign direct investment (FDI) is also having a serious impact on the Chinese real estate market. With the prices of urban apartments jumping by as much as 40% per year for some luxury units, it’s no surprise that foreign busi nesses and individuals are investing billions of Yuan into the housing markets of major urban centers like Shanghai. In fact some 15% of all money invested in the Chinese real estate market is FDI. Some cities, like red-hot Shanghai have even higher FDI versus total investment ratios, in Shanghai, 23.2% of money in the real estate market is FDI, up from 8.3% in 2003 (9). With all of these factors and the possibilities opened up through housing reform it is easy to see how the Chinese real estate market has gone from non-existent only 20 years ago, to the newest trend in international real estate investment. But the more important question, the one about how this recent growth in the real estate sector has affected the Chinese people is more difficult to answer with historical evidence and data. The Current Boom Margaret Pearson put it best at the beginning of her book China’s New Business Elite when she wrote, “The transition from planned to market economy that was initiated in China in the late 1970s unleashed one of the most rapid economic transformations ever to have occurred, with changes that have spilled over into the social and political realms.” The implications of China’s explosive GDP growth and the accompanying changes that resound throughout the Chinese economy are generally viewed in a good light by economists, investors, the PRC government and the people of China. And growth rates that are as immensely high as those that have been produced in China for the last 10 years are certainly reason to celebrate. Especially for those who have made fortunes off the expansion - particularly the real estate boom. “... By the mid 1990’s, most of China’s housing in the urban market had been converted to private property...” HISTORY Of New Fortune Magazine’s list of the 500 richest Chinese citizens, 94 of them are in the real estate business(10). At the same time, “Some researches speculate that [the true profit margin] could be 20% to 30%, or even higher,” per property for real estate developers. For those invested in the real estate market there was more good news, “China’s property prices rose by 12.5% [in 2004] …. Among its major cities, Shanghai's prices grew the fastest, by 19.9%. (11)” Indeed, there are a plethora of business opportunities for the entrepreneur in China, and the fact that real estate is the second biggest market in China today, behind manufacturing, doesn’t seem to be stopping many investors from entering the fray. But for a substantial number of ordinary Chinese workers it is impossible to even consider purchasing the luxury apartments that make up much of the gains in the market. The BBC News Online recently covered the story of Song Yu and his wife, a prime example of the Chinese who are being priced out of the real estate market amid the boom and investments. “Song Yu, a physician in a Shanghai hospital, and his wife are looking to buy their first home. Song Yu earns $1000 (£582) a month, which is more than 10 times the average Chinese salary. Nevertheless, he's had difficulty finding an affordable property in the city. ‘Five years ago we looked at buying a terraced house for 3,000 Yuan ($371; £216) per square meter but the deal fell through,’ he says. ‘Now that same house costs four times the price, so we are now looking at apartments instead.’” (12) Similar sentiments are being echoed throughout the country as millions of Chinese experience the hope of owning their own homes being taken beyond their reach. Stories like that of Song Yu are the unfortunate consequences of real estate booms all over the world, but in a developing state where the per capita income is $5,600 at purchasing power parity (PPP), it’s hard to believe how expensive real estate has become (13). The new Tomson Riviera towers, which are by no means the standard of residential properties in Shanghai, nevertheless, do represent a startling new trend in China. The Tomson Riviera apartments are extremely expensive even by the standards of developed countries like Japan. At the Tomson Riviera, apartments are priced at around $13,564 per square meter. That means that the smallest apartment available (and the cheapest) at the Tomson Riviera is approximately $5 million. At the upper end, prices top out at $25 million. These are prices in a country where most people earn less than $1,000 a month(14). Disparity is quickly becoming the burgeoning topic of the Communist party’s concerns on development. Switching to a market based system has enabled the accumulation of vast amounts of wealth by Chinese capitalists during the economic boom that China has been experiencing .This contrasts starkly with the development of urban unemployment and poverty, and most of all, with the lack of development in rural areas. Economic Disparity The economic disparity in China, while still not as significant as in many less developed countries (LDCs), is growing rapidly. This has forced China’s Ministry of Finance to issue statements regarding the tribulations that the Chinese economy faces during the process of expansion and development. An excerpt from one of these statements published in the People’s Daily follows: Five major problems in China’s Income Distribution 1. A ceaseless widening of the gap in income distribution and the aggravated division of the rich and the poor This mainly manifests in the following ways: First, the difference of the population income in general is getting wider and wider from year to year as indicated in the Gini Index, which has already exceeded the standard line as internationally acknowledged. The index rate has seen an increase of 1.62 times within a span of 10 years with that for 1991 indicating 0.282, IN THE MAKING in 1998 0.456, in 1999 0.457 while the year of 2000 an index rate of 0.458. Second, incessant widening of the income differences between the urban and rural population. 1990 saw an income proportion of 1: 2.2 between the urban and rural population; 1995 a rate of 1: 2.71 and 2000 1: 2.79 while the year of 2001 it rose to a proportion of 1: 2.9; Third, the income differences are expanding from region to region. In 2000, the average population income in China's east was 2.26 times that of the west and it saw a three times difference between the highest and the lowest. (15) The Chinese government is fully aware of the problems that introducing a market-based economy has created for China. What are also notable are the steps the government has taken towards reducing disparity, mostly in the form of policy implementations. Regarding urban/rural disparities the Chinese government has taken steps to reduce the amount of money invested in real estate, which represents a large percentage of all gains made by the urban populations over the rural ones. Those policies are also meant to keep the Chinese economy from overheating and to prevent a bubble from forming in the Chinese real estate market - one that many economists fear that this bubble already exists. Policies are also going to be a tough way of making up the large difference between urban and rural populations in terms of income. Another article from the People’s Daily about the discrepancy between urban and rural workers had this to say about the year 2004: According to gover nment statistics, the per capita disposable income of urban residents stood at 9,422 Yuan (1,338 US dollars) and the net income of farmers per capita reached 2,936 Yuan (355 US dollars), an annual increase of 7.7 percent and 6.8 percent, respectively, in real terms. (16) 40 HISTORY While official statistics show that the rural segment of the population’s income is increasing at a rate only one percent less than that of the urban population’s, there is a significant gap to be made up which the government will be hard pressed to do without implementing policies that would likely have disparate effects on the GDP growth created by urban sectors. Currently, Beijing’s social economic policy, aimed at increasing the income of farmers in rural China who represent about two-thirds of the population, is restricted to reduced or abolished taxes on rural farmers and workers. This policy is having an effect, “Per capita disposable income of urban residents and the per capita net income of rural residents in China are expected to increase by about 6 percent and 5 percent respectively in real terms this year [2005]”(17). To eliminate the disparity in income and wealth however, it would take more radical policies including wage redistribution which, as stated above, would have disastrous effects on the Chinese economy. Already the PBC is instituting policies with negative effects on the urban middle class because of fears of a housing bubble. Recently the PBC told banks they could require a 30% down payment to grant a loan, up from 20%, an amount meant to help urban residents purchase their own homes. Urban disparity in wealth is increasing too and it is proving harder for the government to target and alleviate . The Ministry of Finance report on income discrepancy had this information: 2.Concentration of amassed wealth is more and more increasing with the difference of family fortunes tending to become bigger and bigger The latest statistics indicates that the 10 percent of wealthy families accounted for 45 percent of the total properties of the urban population. That of the 10 percent families with the lowest income only came to 1.4 percent of the total properties and the rest 80 percent of the population own 53.6 percent of the total family properties. In the meantime, the financial property of the urban population tends to concentrate 41 IN THE MAKING among those families with higher incomes. The families of 20 percent of population owning the most financial properties accounted for some 66.4 percent of the total financial properties of the urban population while the lowest 20 percent owning only an average of some 1.3 percent of financial properties. This goes back to Wu’s prediction in 1999 that after the commercial and luxury apartment markets were developed, the mid range-housing sector would dominate. Indicators of Wu’s trend are starting to be realized by the Chinese real estate market though there is debate on whether or not the current cooling of the market is just a slow down or the beginning of a shift in the structure of the market. The Gini Index shows 0.51 for family properties among the city dwellers at present in China, an index indicating a much higher than 0.32 the average income of urban population. (18) Increases in disparity of wealth or property in cities is probably caused in large part by the huge increases in property prices in cities during the past 15 years. Furthermore the government officially ended its welfare housing program in 1998 While there is still housing for the poor, the era of state-subsidized housing for those working in the government, public-institutions and nationalized industries has ended (19). Similar moves by private employers have led to an increase in the number of people seeking housing and some of these people have become rental tenants. Increases in the number of people renting has contributed to the disparity in wealth in cities and towns because the landowning class tends to be dominated by a small wealthy group The existence of this group in China is confirmed by the excerpt from the People’s Daily. Since the price of housing has increased so markedly in recent years more money has been flowing from the hands of renters to the hands of landlords. Meanwhile the properties owned by landlords have been steadi ly appreciating, thus contributing further to their wealth. Concurrently, many Chinese are being priced out of the real estate market and therein shut out of some of the gains being made in real estate. There is a secondary problem of supply not matching demand in many cities as well, which has increased the price of middle and lower range residences. The reason for this is that much of the housing boom has been oriented towards the luxury apartment market, while a shortage of housing for lower income groups, including segments of the middle and upper middle class, has developed. The China Towers. Courtesy of www.pilotguides.com/.../ c_china_towers.jpg Prospects for the Future The New York Times recently ran an article that drove home the size and scope of the Chinese real estate boom. In “China Builds its Dreams, and Some Fear a Bubble,” David Barboza detailed the true extent of the boom in a manner that makes it more approachable on a human level, if that’s really possible: “This year alone, Shanghai will complete towers with more space for living and working than there is in all the office buildings in New York City. That is in a city that already has 4,000 skyscrapers, almost double the number in New York. And there are designs to build 1,000 more by the end of this decade.” The sheer size of this real estate boom in terms of pricing and development is truly unprecedented, that’s why it’s so difficult to determine whether this is really a boom or a bubble. It’s also hard to tell where all the money from this development will end up. Certainly much of it is in the hands of the wealthy Chinese investors and entrepreneurs who got into the market early, but will they spend this money in the Chinese economy or will it make its way abroad and HISTORY IN THE nineties. The silver lining for China however is that it has both the experience of the NICs to study, and a tighter control on speculation and investment. The question is whether or not the Chinese government has done what is necessary to prevent the formation of a bubble. reinforce dualism and the underdevelopment of China? That question is the one that haunts the Chinese government, in part because some theorists believe that the current Chinese regime will not be able to maintain power if the newly formed dreams of industrialization and the modernization of China are unreachable for the majority of the population. After all, it is difficult to justify a Communist state (China actually bills itself as a socialist free market state) where there is an increasing disparity in terms of wealth between a small urban elite and everyone else. What Now For Chinese Real Estate? A major concern among economists and investors are the similarities between China and NICs like South Korea and Japan. Writing on “Shanghai’s Cautious Property Buyers”, James Cotton had this to say in the Asian Journal of Public Adminstration back in 1999: “Meanwhile in Japan, the erstwhile power-house of the regional economy, the investment of surplus funds in real estate had become an engrained habit, a habit which was copied especially in Korea during the real estate boom of the 1980s. While it was recognized that real estate was not generally a productive asset, years of inflating real estate values led investors and banks to assume that it would always yield a generous return. This assumption was transferred to investments in Asia. This system unraveled when doubts emerged that the loans advanced would be repaid.” (20) There are already murmurs about the amount of money that banks have loaned to real estate developers. “Housing loans, including those to property developers, stood at 2.6 trillion Yuan (US$310 billion; euro250 billion) at the end of 2004, accounting for about 15 percent of all Yuan-denominated loans” (21) and “Currently, commercial bank loans account for more than 55% of all funds raised in real estate development(22).” With so much money invested in the housing market real estate investors can barely afford a setback. And the less well off would be hurt by a bubble bursting. Unfortunately for MAKING The Shanghi Towers. Courtesy of mishuna. image.pbase.com/ 34/pnd1/large/313112... them, there are indicators that the current boom will end just in this way, a bubble bursting, a crash. . According to the BBC, housing prices in Shanghai are down by 10 to 15 percent, and in some luxury buildings prices are down by as much as 30%. Moreover, and perhaps more salient is the fact that “sales volumes are down by 70%”(23). According to some, this decrease is just the government’s new policy, aimed at preventing a bubble by raising some taxes associated with property investment rather than long term home purchases and increasing the interest on mortgages, but others believe that this is the sign of the end of China’s real estate housing boom because of an outstripping of demand. The concern is that a situation like that in South Korea and Japan in the early nineties will develop and it will cause a major recession, akin to the Asian financial crisis in the late nineties. Here again there is apprehension that a lack of demand will lead to an excess of vacant properties, which in turn will result in a lot of unpaid loans- exactly what a rapidly developing state with a dependence on FDI does not want. Unfortunately for China, there are many similarities between its current situation and what the NICs experienced in terms of financial problems and over investment in real estate during the late China will continue to be a major powerhouse in the world econo my so long as other countries, particularly the US, continue to consume its goods at an unprecedented rate. But domestically China still has many issues to deal with particularly the disparity of wealth that is gaining momentum. With that in mind it’s important for the Chinese government and central bank to keep a watch out for an impending real estate bubble. If the current trends continue however, the market should realign with the demands of the majority, i.e. the middle class and lower class “... A major concern among economists and investors are the similarities between China and NICs like South Korea and Japan. Writing on “Shanghai’s Cautious Property Buyers”, James Cotton had this to say in the Asian Journal of Public Adminstration back in 1999...” 42 HISTORY IN THE MAKING “... At the Tomson Riviera, apartments are priced at around $13,564 per square meter. That means that the smallest apartment available (and the cheapest) at the Tomson Riviera is approximately $5 million. At the upper end, prices top out at $25 million...” Chinese consumers, particularly as the demand for luxury apartments falls and the return on smaller homes becomes r elatively higher. So long as a loan crisis is avoided it seems unlikely that the housing boom will result in any longterm negative effects for the urban Chinese. For the time being however, they will have to suffer through the high price of real estate, but the free market should eventually correct this and create housing in line with people’s income. Important in the short term is whether or not this increase in housing price has eroded the standard of living of the middle class Chinese consumer. There is little information available on this subject, but it is true that inflation has been stable at just about 5% and it doesn’t seem to be hurting the economy. For rural residents of China, the housing boom may be more of a harbinger of an increased economic disparity to come. As income in China increases, it is likely that urban housing prices will continue to increase disproportionately to rural housing prices, augmenting inflation and wealth in urban China relative to rural China. 43 The question is whether or not this will create “two Chinas” one rich and one poor, or if it is a sufferable problem that will present itself in any developed economy with a large agricultural sector. After all, there is a dichotomy of wealth even in the rural versus urban United States. In terms of a boom, it doesn’t look like China is going to have a severe bubble on its hands, mostly because of policy implementation aimed at preventing one. It does however look like overheated markets, like Shanghai, are going to stagnate for a long while to come. One last thing about the Tomson Riviera apartments, as of midNovember they had not sold a single unit. It looks like the endless success of the boom has finally come to an end. ENDNOTES: 1. Wu, Yanuri, “China’s Consumer Revolution,” Cheltenham, Uk: Edwards Elgar Publishing 1999. 2. Ibid 3. Ibid 4. Ibid 5. Ibid 6. People’s Daily online (17/5/2004) 7. Wu, Yanuri, “China’s Consumer Revolution,” Cheltenham, Uk: Edwards Elgar Publishing 1999. 8. People’s Daily online (17/5/2004) 9. Edge Malasia (26/10/2005) 10. Ibid 11. Ibid 12. “Shanghai’s Cautious property Buyers.” BBC News Online (16/11/2005) 13. CIA World Fact Book Online 14. See: “Shanghai’s Cautious property Buyers,” BBC News Online (16/11/2005) and Wen, Xue, “Foreign Investors Eye Commercial Properties.” Shanghai Daily Online (18/10/2005) 15. “Five Major problems in China’s Income Distribution,” People’s Daily (19/6/2003) 16. “ China Expecting Rising Income for Citizens, Report,” People’s Daily (7/3/2005) 17. Ibid 18. Ibid 19. “Preventing a Bubble in China’s Real Estate ” The Edge Malaysia, (17/10/2005). 20. Cotton, James, “The Effects of the Financial Crises in the Mature Asian NICs: Enterprise Association and its Modifications.” Asian Journal of Public Administration, Vol. , No. 1. June 1999. 21. “China Tightens Lending Rules to Slow Boom,” Associated Press (17/3/2005) 22. “Preventing a Bubble in China’s Real Estate ” The Edge Malaysia, (17/10/2005). 23. “Shanghai’s Cautious property Buyers,” BBC News Online (16/11/2005) IN THE PIPELINE Egypt’s Trade Unions: Reason for Hope or for Hopelessness? * Jano Charbel, Freelance Journalist gypt has witnessed the liberalization of certain aspects of civil society over the year 2005 which has, in effect, widened the nar row margins of civil and political freedoms. In most cases these freedoms were seized and reclaimed by activists. Public gatherings, street demonstrations, and the monitoring of presidential and parliamentary elections by NGOs and the judges’ club are all novel phenomena that have surfaced throughout the year. E Nasser’s corporatist military regime which traded unions’ rights to organize in return for job security, impr oved wages and working conditions – a new authoritarian-populist social contract was thus established. This new social contract served in subjecting the grassroots nature of Egypt’s trade union movement to state control and in setting the guidelines for future manipulation for the next half century. Having resisted trade unions’ /attempts to Facing the odds: workers contemplate the future at the outset of union federate and confeder elections. Photo by Sherif Sonbol, courtesy of weekly.ahram.org.eg. ate their organizations, Egypt’s trade union the military regime finalmovement, however, has not directly benefited from this sequence of the events of 1952 and ly agreed to the establishment of the wave of civil and political freedoms. The have applied since then, notwithstand- Egyptian Workers’ Federation (EWF) in liberalization of civil society has not ing the recent emergence of move- 1957 (2) following the purge of all oppo translated into the liberalization of the ments such as Workers for Change (an sition forces from the ranks. Nasser had trade union movement which remains intellectual-led labor activist movement been won over to the argument that fettered to the state’s restrictive, inter- and one of several offshoots from the “one hierarchical union structure is less ventionist, and manipulative legislation. Egyptian Movement for Change or of a threat than many small ones since it Egypt’s trade unions continue to be Kifaya/Enough) and Railway Workers for is easier for the government to keep dominated by the state and by the Change (a movement organized and undesirable elements out of a single confederation, and since a handful of National Democratic Party’s agents in led by railroad workers). leaders is easier to manipulate than the gover nment-controlled Egyptian Trade Union Federation (ETUF), which is Civil society fell victim to the 1952 mili- many”(3). Since 1957, Egypt’s trade the only trade union confederation tary coup, and has stagnated for over unions have been contained within the allowed for by law(1). All unions must fifty years under emergency law. confines of a single top-down oriented affiliate to the ETUF, and cannot organ- Political parties, NGOs, professional syn- power structure. In 1961, ETUF was ize themselves independently outside dicates, and trade unions all lost their founded as the successor to EWF, and the framework of the ETUF hierarchy. independence. In the case of trade inherited the same centralized organiThese restrictions came about as a con- unions, the freedom to independently zational hierarchy. organize their affairs was smothered by 44 IN THE PIPELINE “... ETUF is not a federation of trade unions, but rather a pyramid-shaped hierarchy by which the NDP-controlled leadership at the pinnacle of the pyramid manipulates the base and keeps it in-check according to the guidelines and policies of the ruling party...” Today, the nationwide hierarchy of unions is based on a three-tiered pyramid-shaped structure composed of approximately 1,900 local unions at the base, with twenty-three general unions/federations in the middle, and a confederation council at the summit of the structure. The ETUF has total of about four million members (most of whom are employed in the public sector). 45 and appointments. Workers at the base of the hierarchy may only vote for their own local union council; beyond this level they have no say (4). Egypt’s legislation on trade unions contradicts with its obligations according to international treaties which the state willingly signed and ratified. Many of the provisions of Egypt’s labor laws and trade union legislation are in direct vio lation of the ILO conventions including those concerning the Right of Association & Combination of Agricultural Workers (5), Freedom of Association & Protection of the Right to Organize, the Application of the Principles of the Right to Organize (6) & to Bargain Collectively (7), Protection & Facilities to be Afforded to Workers’ Representatives in the Undertaking(8), and Tripartite Consultations to Promote the Implementation of Inter national Labor Standards(9). Egypt’s legislation is also in direct breach of article 8 of the International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights (10), and of article 22 of the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights (11). Egypt’s domestic legislation also restricts the freedom of association, notwithstanding the responsibilities to which it committed. For example, according to Trade Union Act 35/1976, workers may not organize unions, federations, or confederations outside the realm of the official ETUF structure. Furthermore, other regulations stipulate that a minimum of fifty employees are required in order to establish a local union council. This prohibits many workers, in the private and informal sectors, from the ability to organize (12). Labor affairs expert, Rahma Refaat, of the Helwan-based Center for Trade Unions’ & Workers’ Services, argues “ETUF is not a federation of trade unions, but rather a pyramid-shaped hierarchy by which the NDP-controlled leadership at the pinnacle of the pyramid manipulates the base and keeps it in-check according to the guidelines and policies of the ruling party.” The right to strike, although it is allowed under articles 192-201 of Unified Labor Code 12/2003, is practically impossible to exercise. To begin with, a total of fourteen out of twenty-three general unions and their constituent local unions which are engaged in strategic and vital enterprises (including bakeries, public transport, public utilities, and pharmacies, amongst a host of others) are forbidden from striking under any circumstances. The provisions of Trade Union Act 35/1976 and 12/1995, together with those of Labor Law 137/1981 and Unified Labor Law 12/2003, govern the powers and functions of the unions. Article 37 of Trade Union Act 35/1976 stipulates that federation and confederation councils are to be chosen through a series of indirect elections Those unions falling under the nine remaining general unions which are allowed to strike may do so only if the respective general union authorizes a strike by a two-thirds majority of the general union council. According to Kamal Abbas, the director of the Center for Trade Unions’ & Workers’ Services, “not a single strike has ever been authorized by any of the general unions; and the provisions of the law guarantee that no future strikes will ever be authorized by the NDP-dominated general unions.” Despite the ban on unendorsed strikes, a large number of “wildcat strikes” – viz. those unauthorized by general unions/federations – occur each year. The most notable in 2005, were the ESCO Textile workers’ strike (13), the air traffic controllers’ strike (14), the metro workers’ strike (15), and the Torah Cement workers’ strike (16). Other forms of workers’ protests, apart from strikes, included the Alexandria Port workers’ sit-in protest (17) and the Ura-Misr Asbestos workers’ protest(18). According to the statistics of the Center for Trade Unions’ & Workers’ Services, nearly 100 other cases of strikes and workers’ protest have occurred throughout 2005 (19). There were other acts of defiance by workers and unionists who have attempted to organize themselves as independently as possible from the ETUF structure. Redda Arabi, a spokesman for the Railway Workers for Change claims, “we established our movement in July (2005) following Prime Minister Ahmad Nazif’s announcements regarding plans to privatize certain sectors of the railways. We know that the unrepresentative and unresponsive Railway Workers’ Federation shall not assist us if privatization becomes a future reality.” Arabi added “The Federation and the ETUF are merely a façade for an organized gang which seeks only its personal benefit; this dysfunctional system responds only to the requests of the NDP and its affiliated businessmen. It neither sees nor hears us.” “... not a single strike has ever been authorized by any of the general unions...” IN THE PIPELINE Throughout the month of May 2005(20) the “Workers for Change” movement raised demands regarding the right to establish a new trade union federation independent of state interference and free from the Labor Ministry’s intrusions. The then Minister of Labor, Ahmad el Amawi, and the President of the ETUF, al-Sayyed Rashid, however, openly rejected this demand on the basis that it would divide the national trade union movement. Rahma Refaat, is of the opinion that “a small number of independent unions may be more valuable than a large number of unions which are organizationally paralyzed. Compare the few autonomous unions that existed prior to 1952 with the many ineffective unions of today. “The number of unions is not an indicator of their quality.” Refaat added that “the establishment of unions that are organizationally independent of the ETUF and/or the creation of a new autonomous union confederation are currently unlikely, however. There are no political parties demanding union independence, and unionized workers are usually too caught up in the grind of their labor to strategize for the creation of new federations. Thus, there is virtually no pressure being applied on the state to alter the status quo, nor are there even demands for parliament to draft new trade union legislation in place of 35/1976.” What then is the forecast for Egypt’s unions? Currently, with privatizations and early retirement programs in effect since the 1990s, the booming private and informal sectors of the economy employ about 75% of Egypt’s workforce while public sector’s share has shrunk to nearly 25%. However, nearly 75% of the existing trade unions are those organized in the public sector. Khaled Ali, a lawyer with the Hisham Mubarak Law Center, claims that the current dynamics of Egypt’s trade union movement are leading towards a situation where “there are unions without workers” in the upper echelons of the ETUF structure by virtue of privatizing the public sector, and “workers without unions” in the private sector. In a surprise result al-Sayyed Rashid, president of the ETUF and of the Textile Workers’ Federation, and a labor MP since 1990, lost his bid for a seat in the 2005-2010 Parliament. The recently concluded parliamentary elections produced a number of unforeseen results (21). Similarly the 2006-2011 trade union elections (22) may also hold a number of unexpected surprises (23). “... one hierarchical union structure is less of a threat than many small ones since it is easier for the government to keep undesirable elements out of a single confederation, and since a handful of leaders is easier to manipulate than many...” END NOTES: * The contents of this article are based primarily on the findings contained in Jano Theodore Charbel,Trade Unions & Professional Syndicates of Contemporary Egypt: Regulations, Rights and Violations (The American University in Cairo, Department of Political Sciences: MA Thesis, February, 2005) 1. Specifically by Trade Union Act 35/1976 2. The Egyptian Workers’ Federation was founded one year following the establishment of the International Confederation of Arab Trade Unions in 1956 which was headquartered in Cairo until 1978 – the new ICATU headquarters are based in Damascus, Syria. 3. Posusney, Marsha Pripstein: Labor and the State in Egypt: Workers, Unions, and Economic Reconstruction, (New York: Columbia University Press, 1997) p. 67 4. In contrast to professional syndicates’ elections in which members are able to vote for their regional syndicate councils as well as for their general syndicate council. 5. (ILO Convention No.11 - Ratified by Egypt as of 07/03/54) 6. (ILO Convention No. 87 - Ratified by Egypt as of 11/06/57) 7. (ILO Convention No. 98 - Ratified by Egypt as of 07/03/54) 8. (ILO Convention No. 135 - Ratified by Egypt as of 03/25/82) 9. (ILO Convention No. 144 - Ratified by Egypt as of 03/25/82) 10. (Egypt’s signature of the ICESCR: 08/04/67; Ratification: 01/14/82) 11. (Egypt’s signature of the Signature: 08/04/67; Ratification: 01/14/82) 12. This requirement may be considered prohibitive in comparison, for example, to the situation in the UK and in a number of Commonwealth states where the old provision allowing any seven persons to form a union is still in force. World Labor Report (Geneva: International Labor Office, 1985) p. 11 13. Lasting from March – August 2005, and involving 400 workers protesting the privatization of their factory 14. May 2005 – involving 150 controllers in Cairo International Airport demanding pay raises; the strike wave spread to other airports including Hurghada 15. November 24, 2005 – involving hundreds of metro workers demanding the release of an imprisoned co-worker 16. Ongoing since December 13, 2005 – involving 2,000 cement workers demanding a more equitable share in profits 17. October 23 - 25, 2005 – involving over 3,000 workers demanding their annual Eid bonus which had been cancelled 18. September 2004 – September 2005 –involving fifty-two workers protesting against unpaid wages, the loss of three coworkers to cancer and asbestosis, and numerous maladies amongst the remaining workers. 19. Strikes, protests, and other cases of workers’ unrest are usually not covered by the official Egyptian media – whether TV, radio, or printed media. If covered, they are usually condemned. 20. The demands for the establishment of a new independent trade union federation were first raised at a demonstration in front of the Journalists’ Syndicate on May 7, 2005. Most of those raising the demands were intellectuals, professionals, and labor activists – only a minority of those present were actually blue-collar workers. 21. Including the victories of eighty-eight Moslem Brotherhood candidates 22. Due to be held in October-November 2006; the Minister of the Labor Force is to determine the exact dates of the elections. 23. Historically the Moslem Brotherhood has not been a significant force within the trade union movement – although the Brotherhood is certainly a major force within the realm of professional syndicates. It may be far too early to speculate about the results of the upcoming union elections. 46 BUSINESS NOT AS USUAL Traditional Crafts an untraditional source of income Karim El-Sayed, Young Scholar, EBHRC “The life of my family now hangs by the thread I embroider” – Ramba Behn, Dastkar Society for Crafts, Rural India. ith the abolition of most state-sponsored development projects in the less economically developed countries, the burden to satisfy the needs of the world poor and marginalized came to rest on the shoulders of the civil society organizations. Development agencies and volunteer organizations faced the challenge of filling the gap between the demands of an ever-increasing population in the developing world for employment and social services and the shrinking efforts provided by their governments. W Those governments’ concessions to the World Bank’s incessant demands for reform and restructuring meant that the meager budgets presently allocated for subsidized education and health services are insufficient. Increases in the cost of delivering those services often mean that the quality of the services provided constantly declines not to mention that the number of people benefiting from those public plans falls due to budget limitations. More importantly, the dismantling of the ambitious public sector cost many people their sole source of income. Private investors strive to find 47 creative means to turn uneconomical public enterprises that they acquired through government-sponsored privatizations into profitable ventures, but the most common recommendation made by global consultancy firms is to cut down on unnecessary costs and to lay off staff employees. This means that hundreds of thousands of able-bodied employees lose their livelihoods; those are also joined each year by files of fresh graduates whose education does not qualify them for a position in the capital-intensive business environment. While some of the civil society and non-governmental organizations that evolved in the developing world attempt to fill the void created by the government’s withdrawal by providing subsidized health services and basic education programs, an increasing number of NGO’s have turned towards income generating activities as a more sustainable solution to that problem. The direct link between income growth and development is debatable in development discourse; nonetheless, many people still share the viewpoint that the vast inequality in income distribution is the crux of the development question. In addition, they argue that many of the problems plaguing the vast majority of the world population, like illiteracy, poor access to health services, unemployment, even racial unrest, are mere manifestations of that reality. Income generating activities, therefore, become a key element in triggering the development process and ensuring the empowerment of marginalized communities. Professor Muhammad Yunus, “the inventor of micro-credit”, developed an income-generation framework that comprised “giving tiny loans … to the poorest of the poor in rural Bangladesh without any collateral” to assist entrepreneurs who could not qualify for traditional bank loans to start their own projects. This system, which is now known as the Grameen Bank model, has five million borrowers in Bangladesh alone, and Professor Yunus has helped export his model to dozens of other developing countries. The Social Fund for Development in Egypt, which operates under the direct supervision of the Prime Minister and under the umbrella of the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP), works closely with NGO’s to finance small and very small enterprises and projects adopting the Grameen Bank model. BUSINESS NOT AS USUAL “... While some of the civil society and non-governmental organizations that evolved in the developing world attempt to fill the void created by the government’s withdrawal by providing subsidized health services and basic education programs, an increasing number of NGO’s have turned towards income generating activities as a more sustainable solution to that problem ...” Today, micro-credit borrowers venture into almost every conceivable business sector, even software development and telecommunication enterprises. The majority of the micro-credit entrepreneurs, however, continue to favor the traditional sectors for their projects. This can be attributed to the fact that the early beneficiaries lived in rural areas where the micro-credit system was first introduced, but it could also be because there was a trend to document and preserve traditional crafts at the time the Grameen Bank experiment began. The two schemes were soon married. One of the projects that exem plify how income-generation activities were closely linked to traditional crafts “Fair Trade Egypt aims to empower local communities by offering disadvantaged arti sans marketing and support services” (Courtesy of Fair Trade Egypt Online). was the “Craft as a window to job opportunities for the poorest youth” project championed by the UNESCO under their ten-year plan for the Development of the Crafts in the World (1990-1999). This project sponsored young craft workers, especially women, to receive formal training “to enhance their skills in producing and marketing traditional crafts” with the objective of “using creativity to alleviate poverty … [and] to enable the youth to generate their own income”. Grameen Uddog is another example; this initiative combines the micro-credit system of the Grameen Bank with an objective to preserve handloom techniques of producing textiles and rugs. Rural communities have traditionally used their craft skills to supplement their incomes, especially during times of lean harvests. Traditional crafts do not require expensive investments in capital goods or infrastructure and can be produced using material from the environment and skills that are passed through the generations. The early 1990s witnessed the infiltration of the consumerist culture into almost every corner of the world; with the fall of state-capitalist regimes in Eastern Europe and Asia and the spread of television broadcasting and advertising to the remotest villages. Mass-scale production quickly replaced utility items that were made by local artisans for daily use. In Egypt, this process started a little bit earlier. The relaxation of the trade laws in the late 1970s allowed for the introduction of foreign luxury goods and western taste. More importantly, the seasonal migration of large numbers of Egyptian workers and farmers to the Gulf countries strongly influenced the taste of the Egyptian village, and detrimentally affected the livelihood of many artisans. Those who had not adopted the western taste could not fight the temptation of the superior quality of the machine-made utensils and factory-produced linens and textiles making local crafts a thing of the past. The philosophy of Fair Trade Egypt attempts to counter that trend. Fair Trade is a concept in trading practice that was conceived in the Netherlands 50 years ago and represents an alternative trade movement which attempts to empower local artisans from the developing world “[by ensuring] that at the very least 25 to 30 percent of the net profits go back to the artisans themselves”. Fair Trade Egypt, a non-profit organization, is the local chapter among more than 200 members worldwide all working under the auspices of International Fair Trade Association (IFAT.) It proclaims “[their] goal is to assist the talented but struggling Egyptian artisans, who have been particularly hardhit by massive industrialization and globalization … by safeguarding techniques and products that were on the brink of extinction because of their mass-produced counterparts”. The last decade has witnessed the evolution of other agents who have been active in preserving local crafts, without so much of the “non-profit” dimension. Nagada presents itself as “a company for design and crafts”. 48 BUSINESS “... the designers, also in an effort to appeal to the consumers’ taste, have intervened in the indigenous creative designing process and have introduced their own new motifs to the textiles...” The business venture, which gets its name from a small village on the east bank of the Nile between Qena and Luxor, has a showroom in Dokki, and is involved in “textiles, fashion, soft furnishings and pottery”. Michel Pastore, a Swiss artist, was sponsored by the Canadian government in 1991 to study the feasibility of developing the textile and weaving practices of the artisans of Nagada, which have been constant for over a thousand years. The Canadian project lasted for only one year. Pastore, however, partnered with Sylva Nasrallah, a Lebanese fashion designer, and formed a company under the same name of the Canadian-sponsored project. They work on improving the quality of the finished goods and the production techniques to be more attractive to the consumers. Unfortunately, however, the designers, also in an effort to appeal to the consumers’ taste, have intervened in the indigenous creative designing process and have introduced their own new motifs to the textiles. Dastkar (one who works with his hands: artisan or craftsperson in the Hindustani language) is the name of a registered society that “aims at improving the economic status of craftspeople thereby promoting the survival of the traditional crafts”. Six women founded the society in 1981, and today it has fullfledged craft development activities all over India. As the name of the society suggests, and as they often assert, the emphasis of their activities is on the artisan and not the craft. They admit that 49 NOT AS USUAL production for home consumption, which used to be the only outlet for traditional crafts, is quite different from commercial sale. Therefore, they emphasize that “traditional craft skills, however beautiful, needs sensitive adaptation, proper quality control, correct sizing and accurate costing”. When it comes to the creative process of design, however, they remain quite adamant about preserving the freedom of the artisan. They question the problematic role of “the designer” and even that of “the client”. Whose taste should the final product express? That of the consumer “who wants an exciting product at the most competitive price” or the artisans “who need a market for [their] product as similar to the traditional one as possible, so it does not need constant alien design inventions, or conflict with the traditional social, aesthetic and cultural roots it has sprung from”. Significant efforts also go towards the documentation of not only the production process but also the traditional design process and the developments introduced. They are building an archive of photographic design and product reference with actual samples of the traditional products. More importantly, Dastkar does not have any qualms about being involved in “a commercial activity like marketing” in order to assist the artisans in infiltrating the market. Their stance on positioning or marketing the traditional products, however, remains quite steadfast. Since they operate with the mindset that traditional artisans produced utility goods that could compete with mass-produced goods in terms of quality, prices and functionality, they strongly oppose the idea that “craft should be purely decorative” and they find “the current much-used terms ‘exclusive’ and ‘ethnic’” as misleading and inappropriate. In order for the traditional crafts to survive and maintain a sustainable track of development, the motivation should be to deliver those goods to a much bigger consumer base than just the tourists or the urban elite who find them “exotic”. This, unfortunately, is not the approach used by Egyptian agents. An article in the 16th of November 2005 issue of ilMasri il-Yum, entitled “il-Khiyamiyya: an Egyptian creation only the foreigners respect”, does more than just tell the well-known story about the art form that came to rely solely on tourists; but it also shows how much that mindset has influenced the development strategies. Asala is an NGO concerned with the preservation of traditional and contemporary art forms, and through a grant from the Agha Khan Foundation, they designed a project for the training of 80 young artisans. Mr. Seif il-Rashidi, Executive Director of the training project, pointed out that the primary objective of the NGO is to target a specific segment by marketing the products abroad and in tourist bazaars. Similarly, the December 2005 issue of Cairo Agenda, a monthly publication addressed primarily to the expatriate community in Egypt, chose Siwa Creations as their pick of the month. A shop in Zamalek that “gives you the opportunity to buy a variety of exquisitely embroidered textiles and finely crafted jewellery locally made and internationally desired”. The business venture employs Italian fashion designer Ermanno Scervino who designed the collection of jewellery, clothes and bed furnishings. The designer “commissioned workshops in Siwa to perform the intricate embroidery for his new collections” which are marketed in international fashion magazines around the world. The pictures of runway models, accompanying the article, fail to prompt any connections with Siwa. We can save the purely intellectual debate about cultural imperialism, the exploitation of native cultures for monetary profits, and the negative effects of the commercialization of those native cultures on the identity of the people themselves for another forum. But on a more grounded note, it is very unclear how much of the profits actually go back to the artisans themselves with the popularity of Fair Trade projects which market themselves by the uniqueness of the traditional crafts. RESEARCH IDEAS The Laws of Competition The Debut of Antitrust Legislation in Egypt; A Proposal for a Comparative Study Dina Waked, LLM candidate, Harvard University fter more than a decade of debate, Egypt passed its first antitrust law on 15 February 2005. As of the 16th of May 2005, the law has come into force. Policy makers argue that this law should take Egypt to a new regulatory era where competition is protected and superiority in the market is the outcome of commercial and technical creativity, and not the result of anti-competitive conduct or structure. Many economists, lawyers, and perhaps the entire business community were wondering when this longawaited, overdue law would finally pass. Most developing countries by the mid-1990s had adopted antitrust laws and Egypt continued to lag behind. However, it is important to note that protection of competition was not absent from the Egyptian legal domain since various provisions in the civil and criminal code deal with the antimonopoly in one way or the other – this, importantly, was never under the auspices of an antitrust umbrella. A The new legislation has been intensely debated, both in support and condemnation, while it was still a draft law and after it became adopted by parliament as law. Fuelling the debate is a growing understanding that antitrust law is a cornerstone in any economy whose administrators wish to guarantee the efficient allocation of resources and its operation within the boundaries “... Egypt has been anticipating the antitrust law for almost a decade and a lot of debate has surrounded the issue of whether the law will actually promote or discourage investment...” of Pareto efficiency. The most intriguing characteristic of antitrust law is that an economy can regulate the direction of its market within the extremes of laissezfaire with minimal government intervention on the one hand, and in planned economies with state involvement in the form of dosages of antitrust applications on the other. The argument hence is that antitrust legislation is the backbone of any legal order designed to regulate a market and assure an effective welfare system where market failures are prevented. In order to assess the implementation of antitrust law in any country, one must consider the implementation of the law as the foundational determinant of the way it will impact on an economy. In order to investigate the implantation mechanism one must look towards the competition agency/authority responsible for implementing the law. Here is where the newly passed antitrust law is most intriguing, hence the focus on the Egyptian Competition Authority-- hereinafter called “Authority”--that is created as the regulatory body supervising the implementation of the law and its procedural enforcement mechanism. Article (8) of the Law no. (3) Ofof 2005 for Protection of Competition and Prevention of Monopolistic Practices establishes the competition agency as “a public corporate body. […] [that] shall report to the appropriate minister who shall [in this case] be the primeminister.” The agency, which shall play a pivotal role in regulating markets and enforcing law, needs to be independent and impartial in order to be able to undertake such regulatory functions. However, there are doubts concerning its true independence from the state given the fact that it is a public body that reports directly to the Prime Minister, who in turn appoints its own board of directors,(Article 8) Moreover, it could represent an inherent flaw in the regulatory structure proposed by the law. However this specific relation 50 RESEARCH IDEAS with the executive branch is implied in the Egyptian constitution, which requires any body to be politically responsible in front of Parliament. In its turn, the Parliament requires that a member of the government (i.e. the Prime Minister, his deputy, the ministers, their deputies, etc.) must oversee this body, since only government members are politically responsible in front of Parliament. Thus, to assure the compliance with constitutional requirements this formation of the competition authority has taken shape. The law excludes the direct intervention of the judiciary in enforcing the antitrust provisions, in cases of violations, by allowing only the Prime Minister to raise the violation to court. It restricts the agency’s punitive enforcement mechanism and prevents recourse to private litigation. Again, this is a result dictated by the Egyptian constitution where no punitive damages or fines may be enforced by any other body than the Egyptian courts. Thus, a question that arises in this respect is not only the independence of the agency but also the balance of power between the judicial and the executive body in implementing the regulations set forth in the adopted antitrust law. As can be seen from the wording of the law, the competition agency reports directly to the executive body, hence excluding the judiciary from the supervision of the implementation of the law. An analysis of the impact of this enforcement mechanism of the authority becomes crucial to determine the extent this structure is expected to affect the regulatory approach of the authority. In other words, one must consider whether this specific procedural enforcement mechanism dictates a certain type of regulation that is different from that adopted by other competition agencies. It would also be rewarding to analyse whether this law, especially with the current structure of the authority, would not merely substitute the direct intervention of the state that prevailed in earlier decades with a new system of intervention disguised under the mask of the current antitrust law; i.e. whether the antitrust law of Egypt sets up a regulatory system that only serves to mask a revisited state intervention. This is an important investigation, especially as Egypt has been anticipating the antitrust law for almost a decade and a lot of debate has surrounded the issue of whether the law will actually promote or discourage investment. The literature on this topic has theo- 51 retically anticipated the outcome thus taking more or less hypothetical approaches in analyses. Since the law has passed and its repercussions are currently available for assessment, it offers some ground to start a thorough analysis of the topic. Nevertheless, since the outcome of the law cannot be yet fully assessed, some parts of the analysis must follow the same approach undertaken by the preceding writers on this specific topic. In order to draw conclusions about the impact of the law, its study cannot be restricted to Egypt. It must entertain a general view of how the structure of the competition authority and its regulation affects the investment and economic atmosphere in different countries. To offset the drawbacks attributed to hypothetical analyses, one must use a combination of a Policy Analysis and a Comparative Approach. Perhaps it would be rewarding to look into the US antitrust law and compare the procedural enforcement mechanism of the competition authority in the US to the one established in Egypt. Moving on from there, one should look into the EU antitrust law and compare it to its Egyptian counterpart with respect to “... Many economists, lawyers, and perhaps the entire business community were wondering when this long-awaited, overdue law would finally pass. Most developing countries by the mid-1990s had adopted antitrust laws and Egypt continued to lag behind...” enforcement procedures. The aim of any comparison is to investigate the differences between the US, EU and the Egyptian antitrust law with special emphasis on the procedural enforcement mechanism of the agency and to asses whether these differences affect the economy differently. In other words, a comparison will illuminate the differences in terms of economic performance that result through the adoption of different systems of regulation. Taking into consideration the issue of comparability, other developing countries that have adopted antitrust laws should be compared to Egypt as well, in order to be able to conclude whether the adoption of antirust laws had a positive or negative effect on the economic performance of their country and whether differences in the competition authority’s enforcement mechanism had any role to play in such differences or similarities between respective countries. Summarizing the questions raised by this article, the study must focus on the procedural aspect of the competition agency established under the newly passed Egyptian antitrust law and to assess, through a comparative study, to what extent this specific enforcement mechanism of the authority will affect an efficient implementation of the law in Egypt. In order to do so, the following questions play more than a guiding force for the research in general: Is the Egyptian antitrust law in line with the benchmarks set by the advanced economies and the Model Competition Law? How does the Egyptian antirust law compare with the emerging markets antitrust laws? Is the lack of punitive powers a fatal problem? Is there something wrong with the Egyptian antitrust law’s enforcement mechanism of the antitrust authority? Does the minimal role granted to the judiciary have any effect on the implementation of the law? If yes what are they? What could be the effect of these differences/similarities? Do these similarities/differences prove that developing countries need other antitrust laws than developed world countries? Is development correlated with the antitrust law? Is there evidence that these are questions that the current administrators and legislators have posed before passing the law? What are the implications of the answers of such questions? *This article is part of the author’s LLM thesis proposal. BOOK REVIEW The Story of an Arab on Wall Street The biography of Alwaleed Bin Talal Wael Ismail, Project Officer, EBHRC t is hard to review a biography. Biographies are about human lives and real people. Their appeal to the reader is due to their ability to make certain people more accessible. The degree of accessibility and accuracy will usually change from one biography to another depending jointly on the subject of the biography and its author. In 2005 Riz Khan, former CNN journalist, added a new biography to this ever expanding and changing form of writing in the book, titled, Alwaleed; Billionaire, Businessman, Prince. I Book: Alwaleed; Billionaire, Businessman, Prince Author: Riz Khan Publisher: Harper Collins Arabic Translation: Arab Scientific Publishers The seventeen chapter book is supposedly an attempt to bring to light the elusive figure of Alwaleed to both Arab and international readers. Alwaleed according to Khan is one of the less known members of the notorious Forbes’ 10 richest men list. Unlike individuals, like Bill Gates or Warren Buffet, Alwaleed is not that widely known to the general populace. Khan’s interest in Alwaleed supposedly began in 2002 when he met him for an interview, but then things progressed to the current book, which is also accompanied by a documentary. The book is hardly just an attempt to bring to light one of the world’s richest men, but is actually more like a presentation of the credentials of Alwaleed to a vast audience. 52 BOOK REVIEW The book reconstructs Alwaleed’s life through the author’s observations and the testimonies of his closest friends, family and business associates. The outcome of the compilation of these various accounts make the biography a rather dull text to read. Alwaleed’s life was turned into his daily routine of waking up and going to sleep and everything in between. Such details might have been what the author considered to be essential observations of his subject’s lifestyle that might reflect how hard the prince works. That is not, however, what generally attracts readers to such a book. It is worth noting that other chapters dealt with Alwaleed’s family ties and relationships, but the statements made were put in a rather general form without touching upon anything particularly peculiar in Alwaleed’s character. Khan attempts to truly glorify the character of the prince, an attempt that really causes more harm than good. Through out the book, Khan wanted to underline the fact that the prince was a self-made man, which is true to a large extent, but his ties to the royal family “... The book reconstructs Alwaleed’s life through the author’s observations and the testimonies of his closest friends, family and business associates. The outcome of the compilation of these various accounts make the biography a rather dull text to read....” 53 can not be kept out of the equation. Unfortunately, Khan only mentions them in passing; maybe in anticipation of just such criticism.As a an example, the picture at the back of the book shows the prince leading heads of vari ous Arab states, Hosni Mubarek (Egypt), King Abdullah (KSA), King Abdullah (Jordan), Mahmoud Abbas (Palestine), and the president of the United States. This prestigious status is a right of his royal standing and not something that money can easily buy. Alwaleed’s connections are a central component of his success story. The fact that he refused to be just another Saudi royal dependent on oil revenues does not negate this fact. The biography of Alwaleed Bin Talal, the only Arab to make the Forbes 10 richest men in the world list could have been produced with better craftsmanship. However, it sill remains an insight into the life of one of the world’s richest men;a window into the life of a Saudi businessman who is currently the biggest foreign investor in the US. The life of Alwaleed, further highlights the fact that business and politics at the end of the day are two faces of the same coin, this could not be more apparent than when Alwaleed’s contribution to the city of New York after 9/11 was rejected by its mayor due to some of Alwaleed’s statements about US foreign policy. Biographies such as Alwaleed help us better understand the mentality of businessmen or, in purely gender free bias, business agents. The ability to truly understand how these people think and act is paramount to understanding the ways firms operate especially in an age where firms are literally playing a larger than life role. In this matter, life history accounts, whether through biographies, autobiographies or oral history records, will take center stage. Each of these forms has to be taken of course with its own pinch of salt. Such records are not the Holy Grail that will easily tell us how or why firms operate or act the way they do. But they will help us make more informed and educated conclusions and create assumption based on reality rather than fiction. In a field like business history and its larger context, economic history, individuals have for so long been kept out of the literature. It is about time that we bring them back in again. The use of life “... former CNN journalist added a new biography to this ever expanding and changing form of writing in the book, entitled, Alwaleed; Billionaire, Businessman, Prince...” history accounts will not only help us learn more about firms and the business community, they will help us better plan and formulate economic policy. If economists truly understand the agony of a father with children caught in a recession without work, they will no longer use with ease certain market economy jargon, where the invisible hand will work its charm yet again. The role of scholars hence lies in producing more biographies, using more accounts based on the reality that lies there outside our window, not buried deep in libraries in remote and inaccessible places. It is amazing how we write about our past without taking into account the people who lived in it. People of all status, central and marginal, should be brought back to the rightful places at the heart of any historical exercise. Alwaleed remains a biography with its flaws, but one that can truly tell us something about an era of business expansion in Saudi Arabia after the oil boom, the reaction to the reversal of this boom, the role of multinational companies in the Saudi economy, and the role that the royal family can play in enhancing the life of its subjects away from the king and his heir. The biography is filled with untapped topics that could have been explored in a much deeper way, with the prince at its center stage. However, for the time being at least, we have to settle for an interview that ended up being a book. OUR ARCHIVES T he following are samples of the documents contributed to EBHRC to be part of its archival depository. Donors of documents vary from individuals to institutions. In addition documents received vary from original to copy forms and some old documents were purchased from a collector of old papers and artifacts in downtown Cairo. Donor name followed by a description of the documents will be found below : Aziz Sidqi: Ministry of Industry Publications: 1.“al-Thawra al-Sina’iya fi ‘ahad ‘ashar ‘aman 1952-1963.” ( Eleven Years of Industrial Revolution). 2. “Dalil al- Sina’a fi Misr fi thalathin sana 1952-1982” ( Guide to Industry in Egypt in 30 years). Banque Misr Publications 1. Sixtieth Anniversary 1920-1980. 2.Diamond Jubilee 1920-1995. 3.Golden Jubilee 1920-1970. 4. Part 3 of Talaat Harb’s collection of speeches 1939. Café Riche Documents, Official Douments: 1. Maslahit il-Dara’ib il-‘Aqariyya records 1905 2. Official copy of Maslahit il-Dara’ib il‘Aqariyya records 1907. 3. Récépissé de déclaration pour un étab lissement public: 16 October 1914. 4. Formal Declaration to the Office of the Assistant to the Chief of Police: 9 May 1916. 5. Déclaration pour l’ouverture d’un étab lissement public: 9 May 1916. 6. Inspection Report: 16 May 1916: Chief of Abdin Police Precinct. 7. Internal Note: Cairo City Police: For/Commandant C.C.P.: 8 July 1919. 8. Internal Note: Confidential: Commandant C.C.P.: For/Acting Commandant C.C.P.: 20 July 1919. 9. Contract: 14 July 1921, Déclaration pour l’ouverture d’un établissement pub lic: 4 November 1942. 10. Petition submitted by Mr. Abdel Malak Mikhail Salib: 22 May 1962, which cites the transaction contract with Avayianos, registered in 1962. 11. Letter from Russell Bey to Camp Commandant of the British Officers, Head Quarters: 26 February 1918. Mohammad AbdelAziz Zayed Papers/Reports: 1. Muzakira bi-Sha’n ’usus al-Tijarah alDakhiliyya wa al-Kharijiyya fi al-Mujtama‘ al ’Ishtiraki al-Dimukrati al-Ta‘awuni (Memo Re: Foundations of Internal and External Trade in the Socialist Democratic Cooperative Society 1959). 2. Bahth ‘an Wasa’il Tanmiyyat al-Tijara alDakhiliyya wa Mada al-Nuhud Biha (Paper on the means for Developing Internal Trade and The Extent of Promoting It) 1961. 3. Taqrir ’an Rihlat Mohammad AbdelAziz Zayed Ra’is Majlis al-’idara lil-kharij ’an al’Mudda min al-’usbu’ al-’akhir min ’uktubar hatta al-’usbu’ al-Thalith min December Sanat 1965 (Report on Mohammad AbdelAziz Zayed’s [Chairman of The Alexandria Commercial Company] Trip Abroad [Duration: Last Week of October 1965 – Third Week of September 1965]). 4. Taqrir ’an Rihlat Mohammad AbdelAziz Zayed Ra’is Majlis al-’idara ila al-Yaban wa al-Wilayat al-Mutahida wa al-Miksik (Report on Mohammad AbdelAziz Zayed’s [Chairman of The Alexandria Commercial Company] Trip to Japan, The United States and Mexico [Duration: October/November 1966]). 5. Taqrir ’an Rihlat Mohammad AbdelAziz Zayed Ra’is Majlis al-’idara lil-’aswaq alQutniyya fi ’urupa al-Gharbiyya (REPORT Mohammad AbdelAziz Zayed’s [Chairman of The Alexandria Commercial Company]Trip to The Cotton Markets in Western Europe [Duration: June 1968]). 6. Taqrir ‘an Ma‘rad Suq Bari b-Italya (REPORT The Bari Exhibition, Italy [September 1970]). 7. MINESTERIAL ORDER: The order is the permission granted to Zayed to attend the Bari Exhibition as Deputy Governor of the Central Bank. Dalil al-Wukala’ alTijariyyin bil-Iqlim al-Misri, 1960 (Directory: Trade Agents in the Egyptian Province, 1960.) The directory is published by “The General Union of Chambers of Commerce” Purchased Documents: 1. Land Contracts: Three land contract registered in the court of Alexandria in 1889, 1890 and 1893 under the Khedives’ government. 2. Stock Certificates: Credit Foncier Egyptien 1951, Societe de Biere “Les Pyramides” 1956, Egyptian Federation for Agricultural Products 1943. Receipts: Three receipts from the Piastre Project for the Revival of Egyptian Industries (mashru’ il qirsh). 3. Letter from Michel Politis to Assistant to the Chief of Police: 9 May 1916. ORAL HISTORY RECORDS: elow is a list of EBHRC’s oral history interviewees. The list excludes the interviewees of theYoung Scholars projects. B INDUSTRY Eng. M. Abdel Wahab Eng. Fouad Abu Zeghla Mr. Louis Bishara Mr. Mounir Ezz El Din Dr. Adel Gazarin Eng. Abdel Moneim Khalifa Mr. Ziyad Nashif Mr. Bahaa Raafat Mr. Hasan Ragab Dr. Rouchdy Said Eng. Ibrahim S. Mohamedein Dr. Aziz Sidqi PLANNING Dr. Ismail Sabri Abdullah EGYPTIAN ENTERPREUNERS Mr. Mansour Hasan Mr. Mohamed Taymour BANKING AND FINANCE Mr. Hasan Abbas Zaki Mr. Mahmoud Abdullah Dr. Salwa El Antari Mr. Ali Dabbous Mr. Mohamed El Barbari Mr. Ali Shahin Mr. Fouad Sultan INSURANCE Mr. Hasan Hafez ACADEMIC , RESEARCH, AND CONSULTANCY Dr. Heba Handoussa SMALL BUSINESSES MAISON PAPAZIAN Mr. Ashod Papazian L’AMPHETRION Mr. Adel To’ma Mr. Henry Francis 54 Young Scholars’ Conference, February 2006 Dates: Feb. 28 Time: 7-9 pm PAPERS TO BE PRESENTED: "Economic Liberalization and Law in 19thCentury Egypt: A Discourse Analysis," By Zeinab Ali Abul-Magd, PhD. Candidate, Georgetown University. “Railroads in the Land of the Nile: Egyptian Railroads and the History of their Development” By Amr Nasr El Din, poltical science, graduating senor, AUC. Third AUC Forum on Economic and Business History of Egypt and the Middle East: T he Third AUC Forum on Economic and Business History of Egypt and the Middle East is due to convene in May 2006. For further information please e-mail: [email protected] “The Arab Bank: A Palestinian National Bank of Jordan” By Amr Ismail Adly, Economic Researcher. The Ministry of International Cooperation. Offices: Rooms 307, 313 A, 314, 315, Old Falaki Telephone: 797 5603 / 5602 Email: [email protected] Copyrights © EBHRC All Rights Reserved