Comments
Description
Transcript
I N R E V I E W
36 / Regulation / Spring 2015 IN REVIEW A Liberal Heretic Contradicts Piketty ✒ Review by Ike Brannon I s Peoria, Ill., special? Of course it is, says I—along with the thousands of other people who, like me, hail from the central Illinois community. It’s a great city with wonderful people, as well as a rich culture and heritage that belies the common perception of it being provincial bore or a totem of flyover country. I’m being facetious in positing such a banality, of course. As a public policy writer with precisely one shtick—being from Peoria—I’ve laid a foundation for its specialness in myriad ways, mentioning it in over a dozen articles in 2014 alone. Subtle I’m not. What I’ve been wondering the last few months is whether Peoria is somehow economically special. I’ve been trying to reconcile my knowledge of the town and the people who live there with the research of Thomas Piketty, Emmanuel Saez, and various other top-drawer academics purporting to show that the plight of the middle class—the folks who people Peoria—has been getting worse over the last three decades. It’s now conventional wisdom that any economic growth we’ve seen in the last 30 to 40 years has gone mainly to the wealthy. Piketty’s recent book, Capital in the 21st Century (see review, Fall 2014), attributes over 90 percent of all income gains from improvements in productivity to the top 10 percent of income-earners, leaving the rest of us to fight over scraps. Esteemed Brookings Institute scholar Isabell Sawhill has written that the plight of the working class hasn’t improved since the 1960s. When Greg Mankiw suggested that their situation might not be as morose as it’s Ike Br a nnon is a fellow at the George W. Bush Center and president of Capital Policy Analytics, a consulting firm in Washington, D.C. being made out to be, he was heckled and shouted down—at an academic conference. It’s now become politically incorrect to dare contradict the notion that life’s getting more precarious for people who aren’t at the top of the income ladder. The suggestion that living standards for most households are worse today than in the 1970s is absurd to anyone who remembers that era of unreliable Country Squire station wagons, music on AM radio, a broadcast universe of precisely three television stations that signed off at midnight, and a narrow offering of movies, music, restaurants, literature, and culture that represent a minute fraction of what any American with access to the Internet can find today. There are childhood cancers that few survived 40 years ago that are now easily curable—an improvement for both rich and poor households that’s not quantified in most articles about living standards. But the other experience that makes me question whether things are getting worse for the middle class is that my friends who have chosen to remain in Peoria— largely blue-collar workers without college degrees—seem to have the world on a string. Steve Rose is the rare economist willing to question the conventional wisdom. In two recent monographs he methodically lays out the postwar income and spending patterns, and by doing so systemati- cally destroys the axiom that the greater income dispersion since 1980 implies that the lower and middle classes are worse off. Rose is in a unique position to question the accepted wisdom: He is the author of Social Stratification in the United States, a fact book and poster he has been updating since 1978. Few would dare question either his liberal credentials or his empirical chops, which have of late led him to places where other Democrats would rather he didn’t go. Small-town living / Last summer I took leave of my wife and children and spent a few weeks with my parents back home. With a lot of free time and no familial obligations, I managed to catch up with a host of old friends and classmates who never left town. What I found was that most of them—many of whom are in their 40s, married, with kids at or approaching college age—have a lifestyle I cannot afford in my big-city neighborhood and with an income several times higher than theirs. One friend—who’s now my hero—has a motorboat, a Harley, a country club membership, and two kids in college that he’s paying for—all of which he’s doing on a family income of $110,000. Over several nights of beers at a cozy bar on the Illinois River in nearby Mossville, we bought drinks for a number of former classmates, neighbors, and friends while chatting about their careers and financial situation. The career path for blue-collar workers in my hometown is almost formulaic: the guys who went on to get some post–high school training end up being welders or pipefitters or in some other occupation that pays somewhere around $75,000. A few do better than that—more than one of my friends spoke enviously of our friend known about town as the “Picasso of the backhoe,” who commands a premium and is never without a job because of his speed and deftness with his implement. People assumed he cleared $100,000. There are a Spring 2015 few who are commercial truckers and earn Dicing the data / That my central Illinois a bit below $75,000 as well as a few guys friends are doing well and are not so difwho started businesses and are a good step ferent than other blue-collar workers in above this, but the distribution is bunched. their cohort is comforting, but also a What’s more, these guys almost all mystery. How does Rose get such a difhad spouses working and earning decent ferent result than Piketty? Rose begins pay. A number of the spouses were nurses, by pointing out that the bottom quintile making around $50,000 a year themselves, of “earners” that Piketty spends so much and those without any college tended to time worrying about in his work reprebe receptionists and earned sent, in fact, not households about half of that. It adds Was JFK Wrong? Does at all but rather the children Rising Productivity No up to an average household Longer Lead to Subof other earners, living at income for my blue-collar stantial Middle Class home. There’s a big differfriends of roughly $100,000 Income Gains? ence between the median a year in a community where By Stephen Rose income of Piketty’s bottom nice homes cost $150,000 and 28 pp.; Information 20 percent of earners, at a public schools are fine. That Technology and Inno- mere $2,000, and that of the vation Foundation, makes for a very nice life. 2014 Congressional Budget December 2014 I assumed that my town or Office report on U.S. income, group of friends was anomawhich reckoned their income lous. Not so, says Rose, who in the five-figures, or an order reports a median household The Economy Goes to of magnitude higher. College: The Hidden income for married families The difference isn’t perPromise of Higher of ages 48–59 to be nearly Education in the plexing: the CBO—correctly, $90,000, a number so out of Postindustrial Service in most people’s eyes— line with the implied blue- Economy excluded the millions of tax collar poverty of Piketty and By Stephen Rose filers who are school-age Saez as to be unbelievable. Georgetown University dependents or else are retirees Part of what’s going on, of Center on Education collecting Social Security. The course, is that there remain and the Workforce, former are not who we typiforthcoming. significant life-cycle differcally think of as “the poor,” ences in earnings, and there and retirees—who depend on is a very real fear that today’s pensions, saving, and Social struggling twentysomethings will never Security—are not nearly as poor as their be able to get a solid hold onto the career reported income would lead us to believe. track anywhere. By excluding such households, the CBO’s It’s a fear my friends shared when they universe consists of 118 million U.S. were starting out. Few of them made much households versus Piketty’s 157 million. money in their 20s. The 1980s were a tryThe other important difference in ing time for Caterpillar, which is by far the the two data sets has to do with definarea’s largest employer, and the burgeon- ing income. Piketty chooses to use pre-tax ing baby boomer generation entering the income and ignore all transfer payments, job market conspired to create high unem- both of which have the effect of narrowing ployment rates in Peoria throughout that the income distribution. The CBO, on the decade. Few in my crowd who remained other hand, is more focused on actual livin Peoria got married before the age of 30 ing standards and thus includes those in simply because they didn’t earn enough the mix. The result is, again, a vast differto support a family. But a decade of gain- ence between the incomes of the bottom ing skills and building connections in the quintile and those at the top. job market and an improving economy Rose agrees with the CBO, arguing eventually opened up opportunities that forcefully in his recent studies—Was JFK my friends were able to exploit. Wrong? and The Economy Goes to College— / Regulation / 37 that living standards need to be the focus of the debate. The former study, which is to some degree an updating of his forceful 2010 book Rebound, shows that, when measured properly, living standards for the poor and middle class have risen steadily over the past 40 years and that trend shows no signs of dissipating, even after the financial crisis and accompanying recession. Rose’s data show that real median household income went up 33 percent from 1979 to 2007. Other research has called into account the very notion of a growing gap between the rich and poor. For instance, the difference in consumption patterns between the top quintile and bottom quintile is much narrower than the income data would suggest. Gene Steuerle, an economist at the Urban Institute, has pointed out that even the widening of the income gap depends on how both income and dispersion are measured, observing that the gap between the person at the precise 20th percentile and the precise 80th percentile (which is different than the mean of the bottom and top quintile, as is typically presented) has not changed over the last few decades. Every piece that dares question the claim that life is growing more onerous for everyone who’s not at the top of the income pyramid conditions such heresy with various caveats, averring that we still need to do more about the scourge of income inequality and the plight of the poor and whatever else might suffice as a bone to the attack dogs on the left. To his everlasting credit, Rose—a man who arguably has thought longer and harder than anyone else about this issue—largely dispenses with such banalities. The difference between the rich and poor is the wrong metric for discerning the plight of the poor. If we look at their living standards from a historical basis, it’s clear that their life is much better today than 20 or 30 years ago. We live in a society where many poor households have cell phones and computers that are far better than any that existed a decade ago and that can be had for less than $100. To be clear, Rose isn’t a fan of rising income inequality, but he argues 38 / Regulation / Spring 2015 in review that the living standards of the poor, not their relative income, needs to be the focus of our public policy machinations. In The Economy Goes to College, Rose marshals up a wealth of evidence to support the claim that living standards are improving. For this, he uses data from the Commerce Department’s Input–Output Accounts to measure the proportion of consumer expenditures that go to various categories. The biggest change the data reveal is that food and clothing—two necessities that took almost half of all consumer spending in 1947—today require just 18 percent. So what do people spend money on today? Recreation (which went from 8 percent of spending to 14 percent) and health care (which quadrupled to 20 percent in 2007). And while the reflexive response of many to this latter statistic is to lament that “rising cost,” it’s helpful to remember how much better health care became over this period—we spend more for health care, but we also get more from that spending. In 1947 the typical doctor’s advice to the survivor of a heart attack was to get one’s affairs in order. Too good to fact-check / Despite Rose’s ped- igree and his meticulous, thoughtful studies pointing out that the supposed stasis in living standards for the poor and middle class doesn’t hold up, a contrary narrative has taken root in the media and few dare to contradict it. Nobel-winning economist Joseph Stiglitz, who followed Rose on a panel at an academic conference devoted to inequality in January, remarked that he had no idea that people found flaws with Piketty’s data. When someone widely regarded (by himself and others) as the smartest economist in the profession can’t be bothered to read anything contrary to what he declares to be the most important issue of our time, it’s clear that an intellectual battle is over, and those who want to continue it can’t expect to be treated politely. Journalist Rod Dreher garnered much attention with his 2013 book The Little Way of Ruthie Lemming, a moving portrait about his hometown’s embrace of his sister as she fought cancer. The warmth he felt for the town led him to reject the big-city rat race and move back to the town later in life to raise his family. It’s a story that those of us who’ve abandoned our hometowns can empathize with from time to time. But my fleeting pangs of longing for home aren’t because I’m trapped in some big-city rat race. The notion that it’s harder to make friends and be a part of one’s community or that we all work harder in a big city is nonsense. Rather, I’m jealous of the lifestyle my blue-collar friends back home have achieved. My friends who stayed married and aren’t afraid of hard work have created good lives for themselves in our blue-collar hometown. The march of progress hasn’t cost any of them their jobs, either; rather, it’s made living in a pleasant community even better than it was a generation ago. Their televisions, pickup trucks, and telephones are miles ahead of anything the richest of the rich could have obtained just 20 years ago, let alone in the halcyon days of our youth. Peoria and Mossville are not unique, Rose has shown. While blue-collar jobs these days may require more training and experience than they did a generation ago, the notion that people who don’t finish college are doomed to penury is greatly overstated. If we’re going to begin the debate over how to raise living standards with an empirical story in which the data used bear little resemblance to the real conditions and that cannot be questioned, the prospects of reaching some sort of agreement are slim. And that’s probably for the best. Piketty’s prescription of greater income redistribution isn’t going to do much for my blue-collar friends back home, let alone the rest of us. More than a Principal Deputy Assistant ✒ Review by Pierre Lemieux R obert Litan is an economist and lawyer who has moved between think tanks (the Brookings Institution and Kauffman Foundation), the private sector (Bloomberg), and numerous government jobs. This book, one of the two dozen he has authored or coauthored, pursues two broad goals: showing that “economists and their ideas have made important contributions to the world of business” and to better public policies. They have created benefits worth trillions of dollars—hence the title of the book. / Economic ideas, Litan claims, “have directly made money for firms” (emphasis in original). For instance, the idea of price discrimination (charging a lower price to the most price-sensitive consumers) comes from economists. The book gives many other convincing examples. Economics at work Pier r e Lemieux is an economist affiliated with the Department of Management Sciences at the Université du Québec en Outaouais. His latest book is Who Needs Jobs? (Palgrave Macmillan, 2014). Consider the proliferation of auction practices in today’s business activities. In the 1960s, Julian Simon conceived the idea of auctioning overbooked seats on planes—specifically, using a reverse auction, which would pay the minimum price necessary for passengers to happily switch to another flight. Today, this idea is only imperfectly applied, as airlines typically offer vouchers to passengers who volunteer to be “bumped.” Another example is Google’s auctioning of online ad space, which company executives initiated without apparently realizing that they were using a sort of auction previously designed by Nobel prizewinning economist William Spring 2015 Vickrey. Google later hired Hal Varian to requests and men, therefore, were getting improve its auctions and data processing. too few replies to their approaches. The Although Litan does not put it in these economists’ solution was to increase the terms, economists naturally think in terms cost of men-to-women communications by of auctions because they understand that limiting their number. Another dating site, free-market prices are, in fact, the result of Whatsyourprice.com, openly put a money continuous silent auctions. price on communications and dates. Another example of the usefulness Economists have contributed much to of economists is the recent explosion of the financial industry. They have shown “data mining” or “Big Data,” which has that, for any given level of risk, a diversibeen made possible technologically by the fied portfolio brings higher returns. This growth of computing power and the pro- discovery led to the 1970s creation of index liferation of data available on the Internet. funds, mutual funds made of diversified Statistical techniques are essential for pro- stocks or other financial instruments. cessing these data (on prices, Index funds have consistently choices, consumers, other generated higher returns than businesses), but economists actively managed funds. The are useful to interpret the staEfficient Market Hypothesis, tistical results—and to know which claims that no stockwhat to look for in the first picker can consistently outplace. perform the market because Perhaps the best example all available information is of Big Data is the increasing incorporated in the prices use of statistical analyses in of financial instruments, hiring players and devising formalized this idea. Eugene strategies in sports. Michael Fama won the 2013 Nobel Lewis’s book Moneyball, about Prize in economics for his Trillion Dollar Econothe statistical work used by mists: How Economists work in this area. Billy Beane and the Oakland and Their Ideas Have Although options (tradA’s front office, was turned Transformed Business able contracts to buy or sell into a (good) movie with By Robert E. Litan commodities or, now, other Brad Pitt. Big Data is espe- 400 pp.; Wiley & Sons, financial instruments) have cially prominent in adver- 2014 existed for centuries, three tising and marketing: “Do financial economists—Fisher customers respond better to Black, Myron Scholes, and solicitations in blue or white envelopes?” Robert Merton—contributed to the growth Similarly, Litan tells us that “there is no of this market by developing a famous single Google website”; instead, visitors options pricing formula to determine what are presented a number of different Google an option should be worth. homepages so that their reactions can be Public policy implications / Economists have measured in order to optimize the site. Another field where economists have also contributed much to public policy. helped business is matchmaking between Litan emphasizes the importance of entresuppliers and demanders where prices do preneurship and blames economists for not provide a sufficient signal. Examples “failing to recognize how increasing bureauof this include sectors where pricing is cracy and regulation are stifling American forbidden, like in organ transplants, or entrepreneurship.” But economists have the good is subject to information asym- also been instrumental in the deregulation metries (the seller knows more than the experiments that began in the 1970s. At the time, transportation was heavily buyer), like in online dating. Cupid.com hired two economists to solve a vexing regulated. Litan reminds us that “airlines problem: women were receiving too many could not transport air cargo by truck / Regulation / 39 beyond 20 miles of an airport.” Like airlines, truckers were subject to rate fixing and route controls. He notes, “Economists from across the political spectrum were well ahead of the politicians and regulators in advocating deregulation.” Without deregulation, much of the online commerce revolution and just-in-time delivery systems we know today could not have happened. And airline fares would probably be double what they are now. Starting with Jimmy Carter’s administration, oil prices were also deregulated thanks to the advice of economists. This was “yet another example,” writes Litan, “where a Democratic president and a Democratic-controlled Congress did what free market Republicans had long been associated with—letting the market, rather than the government, set prices.” This deregulation paved the way for the ongoing shale oil revolution. What is surprising about all these regulations is that they were imposed in what was supposed to be the country of free enterprise. The same paradox was apparent in telecommunications. The deregulation movement in telecom, with economists at the forefront, also started in the 1970s. First, AT&T was broken up into regional entities by the Antitrust Division of the U.S. Justice Department. Litan properly criticizes AT&T’s longtime monopoly and the ongoing power that the regional “Bells” have over the “local loop,” but he does not emphasize enough the paradox that these monopolies were creatures of government itself. Also in the telecom section, he discusses the partial deregulation of the electromagnetic spectrum that got underway in the 1990s with the auctioning of frequencies by the Federal Communications Commission. The idea for those auctions had been advanced by Ronald Coase three decades earlier in work that would help earn him the Nobel Economics Prize. The attentive reader of Trillion Dollar Economists will notice that the economists credited for innovations were often not holders of economics Ph.D.s, but instead were statisticians, mathematicians, engi- 40 / Regulation / Spring 2015 in review neers, and others who “[think] like economists.” Yet economics remains essential. The advance of Big Data has made empirical work easier, but theory has become even more necessary because aimlessly fishing for data easily leads to misleading correlations. Regulation / Litan is careful not to blame the Great Recession on economics or finance. He recognizes that “politicians promoted home ownership” and thus they deserve much of the blame for the real estate bubble and subsequent collapse. But he is still too soft on the federal government. He thinks that financial regulators did not regulate enough prior to the recession; they “got too cute, or too complicated.” He believes that government can and should manage the macroeconomy. He is persuaded that “Bernanke’s extraordinarily innovative easy-money policy helped save the U.S. economy from a far worse recession than actually happened.” Perhaps blinded by the limited experience of deregulation of the last decades of the 20th century, Litan seems to overlook the generally growing trend of regulation. Since the end of World War II, the Code of Federal Regulations (which annually consolidates all existing federal regulation) has grown from less than 20,000 pages to more than 130,000; state and local regulations have also mushroomed. Even with the late-20th century deregulation era, overall government regulation has continued to grow. (See my “A Slow-Motion Collapse,” Winter 2014–2015.) Consider finance. It is true, as Litan argues, that some deregulation occurred— brokerage commissions were decontrolled, for example. But the whole industry is quite certainly more regulated today than at any time in American history. Even before the Great Recession, the regulatory burden was heavy; for example, the New York Fed had hundreds of regulating bureaucrats working on the very premises of large banks. Regulation has become so omnipresent that we do not see it anymore. Nor, seemingly, does Litan. He is sympathetic to cryptocurrencies but he does not seem to realize that they are being crushed by regulations (many emanating from the war on drugs). He explains well the efficiency of prediction markets (they predicted the 2004 presidential election better than opinion polls) but is soft on the government’s attempts to regulate them out of existence, including with the DoddFrank financial legislation. He seems to buy wholesale the necessity of antitrust laws. Litan is an intelligent and well-informed economist. He knows his classics, from “the great Austrian economist Friedrich Hayek,” to Milton Friedman, not to forget Joseph Schumpeter and Israel Kirzner. He is familiar with public choice theory. He generally believes in the efficiency of markets: “the alternative to allocation by price is allocation by queue.” He is well aware of the disagreements among economists, including on redistribution, even if he himself favors it for equity reasons and as “a form of social glue.” And he understands that in a free economy, what matters is the satisfaction of consumer demand, not the success of producers. Values and analysis / I find in Trillion Dollar Economists the same disquieting contrast I contemplate every week in reading The Economist. (Interestingly, the review of Litan’s book in The Economist blames him for being too obsessed with economic efficiency.) On the one hand, one sees a generally good understanding of markets and their efficiency. On the other hand, one is struck by a constant deference toward those who run the government and interfere in markets. How can they miss that inconsistency? Or is it just me? The problem is, no doubt, partly attributable to differences in values. Contrary to my view, Litan, like The Economist, is willing to call on government coercion to skew in favor of different people the distribution that would otherwise result from the working of free markets. In their perspective, there exists some public goal or purpose to which individual ends must be subordinated, but they realize that this subordination is done at a lower cost if the market is put at the service of public policy instead of being crushed. This approach is very different from the classical liberal— or, at any rate, the libertarian—approach where only individual preferences, goals, and happiness matter. But, contrary to what Hayek argued, libertarians and socialists probably also have analytical differences besides differences in values. One such analytical disagreement lies in the social democrats’ belief in the omnipresence of market failures. The fact that Litan was at one time “principal deputy assistant attorney general” in the Antitrust Division reveals something not only about how embedded he was in the monstrous federal bureaucracy, but also about his belief that economic freedom is impossible without constant government threats and meddling. In this perspective, the mildest conditional prejudice in favor of some economic freedom looks like freemarket ideology. How else could we understand his claims that the George W. Bush administration was “a Republican administration committed to free markets”? Another sort of analytical disagreement is probably traceable to the influence of John Maynard Keynes. It is true that Litan shows some skepticism toward macroeconomic management. But he seems to agree that a free-market economy is inherently unstable, as if any other economic system were better. In a more general way, I suspect that Litan would agree with Keynes that, in a society that “thinks and feels rightly”—a society where, probably, the government regularly consults him—politicians and bureaucrats can be trusted to take risks with other people’s liberty. Trusting government / The author of Trillion Dollar Economists does not distrust government. He talks fondly of “government service” and “public service.” He does not appreciate that political solutions are generally more risky than the market failures they are (officially) meant to correct. Information asymmetries are potentially more damaging in the political market, where bureaucrats use the information they control to manipulate politicians while the latter use their own privileged information to defraud citizens. Litan argues that a carbon tax or a cap-and-trade system “is really a Spring 2015 matter of prudence,” but he forgets that protecting citizens against Leviathan is a much more serious matter of prudence. Another sort of reason why our trust in government should be very limited lies in the fuzziness of the very notion of public interest. Society is the locus of private interests resulting from individual preferences that cannot be aggregated into nondictatorial “social preferences.” Government action nearly always overrules some individuals’ preferences in favor of other individuals’. On the contrary, Litan believes that “the best interest of society as a whole” requires constant attention and meddling with cost-benefit analysis. Perhaps, like many economists, he has just not thought through issues of social choice and welfare economics, but he should have. The reader of Trillion Dollar Economists will appreciate that Litan has worked with many of the most important economists of our time, but the name-dropping gets a bit tiresome. Everybody seems to be his “good friend.” Is there any liberal economist with whom Litan has not rubbed elbows? Perhaps he is just a sociable guy who has problems finding faults with his fellow citizens. But he may also be much too close to the establishment. As any author knows in his bones, nothing is perfect. If a good book is a book in which one learns something, Trillion Dollar Economists is a good one for me, both for what it contains and for what it underplays. Peter Wallison Dissents Again, with Feeling ✒ Review by Vern McKinley E ver since it became clear in 2008 that we were in the midst of a financial crisis, we have been hearing dueling narratives over who or what was primarily to blame for the crisis: either greedy capitalists or government housing policy. One of the most important voices in this dispute has now weighed in with the book Hidden in Plain Sight. Since the late 1990s, Peter Wallison of the American Enterprise Institute has been one of the most prolific commenters on the build-up of the housing bubble, the ensuing financial crisis, and its underlying cause. Back in the late 1990s, long before most people understood precisely what Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac did, he was raising red flags (including several articles in these pages) and warning that the market and political dominance of the pair would one day end badly. Wallison was a member of the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission (FCIC), the 10-member body that was tasked with V er n McKinley is a visiting scholar at the George Washington University Law School and author of Financing Failure: A Century of Bailouts (Independent Institute: 2012). examining the causes of the crisis, among other duties. The final report of the FCIC split along partisan lines, with the six Democratic Party members supporting the final report and the four Republicans dissenting. Wallison distinguished himself as a lone dissenter with his arguments that government housing policy was at the core of the causes of the financial crisis. In 2013 AEI released his book Bad History, Worse Policy as an initial response to the FCIC majority’s findings. However, the book was simply a re-release of multiple policy pieces he had penned from 2004 to 2012, with some limited explanatory text integrated in. Hidden in Plain Sight, on the other hand, is all original writing, albeit citing much of the same source materials he has cited over the years, organized into / Regulation / 41 a coherent summary of his arguments on the precise cause of the crisis. The depth of the research in the book is nothing short of extraordinary as he addresses all the potential causes, provides an amazing number of on-point documents to support his thesis, and responds to the arguments of his critics who cling to the idea that government housing policy played no or only a small role in the crisis. / Wallison’s first chapter sets forth the overarching arguments that he develops later in the book: Government and NTMs The financial crisis was the result of the government’s own housing policies or, more precisely, “the crisis would not have occurred without those policies.” ■■ The “seeds of the crisis were planted in 1992” when Congress enacted affordable housing goals for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, the government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs) that purchased loans in the secondary market. ■■ Fannie and Freddie reduced their underwriting standards not only with regard to low-income borrowers, but also to high-income borrowers. ■■ Because of the deterioration in underwriting standards, by 2008 half of all U.S. mortgages were “subprime” or “Alt-A,” which means they were of below-prime quality (more on this below). Some 76 percent of the lowerquality loans were held on the books of government agencies or the GSEs. ■■ The GSEs did not disclose the full extent to which they held such lowerquality loans. ■■ When the bubble deflated, the financial crisis put at risk many of the largest financial institutions in the country. ■■ Right out of the box after laying out his thesis, Wallison digs down into the data to support his core arguments, and his use of data, tables, and graphs bolsters his arguments throughout the book. The source of the data is research demarcating traditional and non-traditional mortgages (NTMs) undertaken by Edward Pinto, an AEI col- 42 / Regulation / Spring 2015 in review league. Traditional mortgages adhere to standards as adjudged under three key elements: a loan-to-value ratio of 90 percent or less, which indicates a material down payment; a debt-to-income ratio of 38 percent or less, which indicates the amount of a borrower’s income committed to debts; and a borrower’s credit record, which is the history of the borrower’s meeting of prior debts and should indicate no late payments (or, in rare cases, one). An estimated 85 percent of sampled loans met those standards between 1988 and 1991. Growth in the segment of the market dedicated to NTMs—what Wallison derides throughout the book as “flexible” or “innovative” lending standards—was a good indicator of the deterioration in credit standards. At bottom, Pinto estimates the number of troublesome NTMs outstanding as of mid-2008, just at the onset of the major stress and panic of the financial crisis in the fall of 2008. Under Pinto’s analysis, the NTMs numbered 32 million of the total (balance of over $5 trillion) or 58 percent of the total 55 million U.S. mortgages as of mid-2008. Government agencies as a group were exposed to 76 percent of the NTMs, with Fannie and Freddie exposed to over half. Those data are especially significant because Fannie and Freddie did not begin to report their full exposure to NTMs until after they were taken into conservatorship by their regulator, the Federal Housing Finance Agency, in 2008. As a result, “analysts, regulators, academic commentators, rating agencies, and even the Federal Reserve were seriously misled about the scope of the NTM problem, believing that it was much smaller, and the number of traditional prime mortgages outstanding was much larger, than in fact they were.” Finding what they wanted to find / Wallison settles a few scores with those who have criticized his analysis over the years (primarily those he derisively refers to throughout the book as being “of the left” or “on the left”) or that came to different conclusions than he did regarding the genesis of the crisis (primarily his fellow commission members and select staff of the FCIC). Wal- Federal policy / Wallison traces through lison holds those “on the left” in greatest an exhaustive review of the history of the contempt and ire, noting that “they have build-up of the bubble, from the state no data, no policy arguments, just a viru- of housing finance before the affordable lent denial that anything other than the housing goals were implemented; the private financial sector could possibly be ratcheting up of the goals; the political calculations regarding taking credit for responsible for the financial crisis.” Turning his attention to the FCIC, the homeownership increases (both during the Clinton and George official arbiter of the causes W. Bush administrations); of the crisis, he cites a range through the steady deterioraof sins visible to him as an tion of credit standards durinsider to the process: just ing the 1990s and how that one staff member from a total ultimately precipitated the staff of almost 80 was procrisis. The breadth of research vided to support the minorthroughout this history is ity’s research; the executive incredible, including matedirector was on loan from the rial from a Federal Housing Federal Reserve and thus was Authority underwriting manpotentially conflicted in her ual from the 1930s; internal investigation of that agency’s Housing and Urban Developrole in the crisis; the chair of the commission did not Hidden in Plain Sight: ment Department memos, What Really Caused reports, speeches, and testisolicit the views of the minor- the World’s Worst mony; homeownership stratity or keep them informed on Financial Crisis and details of the FCIC investiga- Why It Could Happen egies; and Fannie and Freddie 10K and 10Q reporting. tions; and Pinto’s work was Again One truly unique chapter never formally made available By Peter J. Wallison 386 pp.; Encounter in the book is on fair-value to the other members of the accounting and its role in the FCIC and the majority essen- Books, 2015 dissemination of information tially dismissed his research regarding the financial posiout of hand. I have always been of the opinion that tion of financial institutions. I don’t recall the FCIC’s report included some useful any other book on the financial crisis going information and that the interviews it into such detail on this issue and it is an conducted and the never-before-released excellent summary of the topic. A discusemails it made available were some of the sion of each of these historical issues and few avenues to get detailed information related documents cannot be undertaken out of the financial agencies (which were in this brief book review, but Wallison not willing to release much information always seems to find just the right docuvoluntarily). But Wallison’s conclusion mented evidence to support his argument. The last section of the book details the about the politicization of the FCIC’s government response to the crisis, or what policy conclusions seems about right: Wallison calls the “panic and bungling of As far as I could tell from the witness the officials who handled it. Then, in trying interviews I was able to get, no one to minimize or justify their own mistakes, conducted any cross-examinations, and these officials claimed that they had insufno one used any documents to question ficient authority to deal with the crisis.” He the witnesses’ statements or otherwise walks through a number of the narratives test their veracity. The process simply put forth by the authorities to justify their validated the conventional view of the response. The interconnectedness fallacy financial crisis that the media had that was used to justify the bailout of Bear already accepted and repeated. Stearns? He rightly speculates that it was Spring 2015 “dreamed up in either the Federal Reserve or the Treasury to justify saving Bear Stearns, and it was easily swallowed by the media at the time.” The Federal Reserve’s authority to rescue Lehman? “It does not take much detailed analysis … to find that the story Paulson and Bernanke used to explain their failure to rescue Lehman has no basis in fact.” The dramatic zigs and zags of different and inconsistent policy responses? “Instead of a sense that the U.S. government knew what it was doing and had settled on a policy, there was now a sense that the government was winging it or simply incompetent.” I believe this will be one of the best policy books of 2015, and one of the best books on the crisis since it ended. For readers who have been critical of government housing policy and response to the crisis, Hidden in Plain Sight will provide you with more ammunition than you can ever hope to use. For readers who bought into the narrative of the media and the FCIC and are in denial that government policy caused the crisis, get ready to become so frustrated by Wallison’s mountain of contrary evidence that your head may explode. / Regulation / 43 and even maintenance of the existing capital. The population began to decline, as did the median income. Curley’s political success came at the price of setting his city on a downward spiral. Boston kept sinking until Massachusetts voters enacted a property tax limitation measure, Proposition 2.5, in 1980. The measure had been frantically opposed by both city and state politicians because they were certain that tax limits would “starve” the city. But instead of starving Boston, Prop 2.5 breathed life into it. Ambitious people and investment quickly returned. Walters emphasizes that Boston’s revival didn’t occur because politicians had solved any of the usual problems that are blamed for urban decay: racism, poor education, crime, and so on. All that changed ✒ Review by George Leef was a tax limitation measure that kept Boston from strangling itself with high taxes. Is that a unique case? No; the same scehy are some American cities thriving, growing in populanario has played out in quite a few other tion, investment, and incomes, while others are in decline cities and San Francisco is a good example. with shrinking populations, crumbling buildings, and “Progressive” politicians there had played businesses fleeing? the same redistributive game as Curley For the answers, read Boom Towns by Loyola University Maryland in Boston, with the same results. By the economics professor Stephen Walters. imposing high property taxes. The wealthy 1970s, San Francisco was a dysfunctional Based on his years of study of cities, he owners will have no choice but to pay and the mess, mainly because of militant unions concludes that the key to a successful city increased revenues can be used for projects that kept striking for higher pay, which is to protect property rights and otherwise and programs most of the voters like. These the politicians funded with higher taxes. leave people alone. “The record is clear,” programs can also help to buy favor with But in 1978 California voters passed he writes, “cities grow and prosper when important interest groups. Proposition 13, despite Calithey encourage the formation of capital fornia liberals’ declaration in its many forms by securing the returns Boston and San Francisco / that it would be utterly ruinOne of America’s most notothat flow from it.” ous. Almost immediately, What causes cities to go into decline is rious practitioners of the capital began flowing back equally clear: it happens when government redistributive strategy was into San Francisco and other stops protecting property rights. People Boston mayor Michael Curcities in the state. As Walters and capital don’t stay where they are poorly ley, who governed the city for writes, “Prop. 13 increased the treated. Walters strongly argues his the- four nonconsecutive terms return on investments and sis with cases showing the various ways (between terms in Congress, protected [investors] against politicians—often in league with private the governor’s mansion, and further Robin Hood raids.” As prison) between 1914 and interests—have turned growth into decay. with Boston, San Francisco’s Probably the most widespread threat to 1950. The masses adored this Boom Towns: revival had nothing to do with a city’s continuing success is redistributive “man of the people” who kept Restoring the Urban the discovery of “solutions” to American Dream taxation. Accumulated wealth in the hands increasing property taxes on any of the presumed causes of of business people and professionals is a the rich, but few could see the By Stephen J. K. urban decay. Walters tempting target for politicians who figure slow-motion deterioration 210 pp.; Stanford Busithey’ll gain far more votes than they’ll lose by of the city produced by his ness and Finance, 2014 Baltimore and Detroit / Baltimore serves as an instructive redistributive policies. High George Leef is director of research at the John W. Pope Center for Higher Education Policy. case for precisely the opposite taxes repelled new investment Property and Cities W 44 / Regulation / Spring 2015 in review reason. It’s a city where there has never been a reduction in taxes. For decades, city leaders have placed their bets on big, splashy government-led projects to revive it, but those “investments” have been failures. Walters writes about one of them, the Charles Center development: “Upon its completion in the early 1960s, press coverage was adulatory and opinion leaders praised those behind the thirty-three-acre project for their good intentions, brilliant vision, bold artistic sense, and deft political touch.” Over the decades, city officials kept pouring money into similar “renaissance” projects, but “few noticed that [Charles Center] is actually a failure both within its borders and beyond them.” Because of the high-tax, governmentcentered philosophy that has held sway in Baltimore (and the state of Maryland), most of the city is decaying. Instead of encouraging small capital investments that really would radiate jobs and prosperity, city officials have tried to use big government as a catalyst, and failed. Baltimore’s unhappy experience strongly supports Walters’ overarching point that cities do well when spontaneous, bottom-up development is not discouraged and they do poorly when politically planned, top-down development takes over. Redistributive taxation isn’t the only way that cities turn against the sources of prosperity. Another is to embrace the union movement, whose short-sighted actions siphon away a large portion of the return to invested capital and thereby set in motion private responses that slowly de-capitalize a city to the detriment of nearly everyone. Detroit is, of course, the prime example. Walters gives readers an intriguing history of the city that became the center of the auto industry. It grew at a dazzling pace from 1900 to 1950, by which time it was the nation’s fourth-largest city, boasting a median family income second only to Chicago. A true boom town, the good wages available in its many industries attracted people of all races. During Detroit’s fabulous growth, unions represented no more than 10 percent of the workers in the city’s many factories—a strong refutation to the frequently only a little at the margin. But the right-towork law is a signal that public policy is not dominated by the redistributionists, and that is a very important signal. Speaking of signals, a bad one that cities can send is that they are willing to use eminent domain to seize property from homeowners and small businesses, and redistribute that land to big companies. Walters writes that there has been a “hundred-year war” between eminent domain and private property, with private property constantly in retreat. When cities play that game, he writes, For decades, Baltimore leaders have “The mere threat of such bet on big, splashy, government-led takings will have a chillprojects to revive the city, but ing effect on private owntheir “investments” have been failures. ers’ plans to upgrade residences and businesses in areas targeted for ‘rescue’ intriguing back-story on the reason for by planners.” Also, eminent domain–based Henry Ford’s capitulation.) Unionism now development tends to misallocate capital seemed to be an easy way for workers to get because it distorts price signals and substitutes the tastes of the planners for those of higher wages and it spread rapidly. The long-run effect of the alliance market participants. Another way cities can damage thembetween unions and politicians was similar to high tax rates. Investors stopped putting selves is by caving in to “green” interests. money where the returns were expropri- Portland, Ore., is the best illustration, with ated. Between 1947 and 1958, manufactur- its Urban Growth Boundary. The ratioing employment fell by 40 percent; Detroit nale behind the meddlesome law is that went into a tailspin from which it has never saving space for nature is so important recovered. Although Walters does not cite the that the city’s growth has to be walled in. work of economist W. H. Hutt (his 1973 book The consequences might please the enviThe Strike-Threat System [Arlington House] ronmentalists, but affordable housing for in particular), his argument dovetails with lower-income families has disappeared. Boom Towns is full of helpful ideas for Hutt’s that unions can only exploit capital in the short-run, after which it departs for officials who would rather preside over a growing, increasingly prosperous city than greener pastures. Detroit is proof of that. one they could milk for short-run political Inviting signals / Walters includes an analbenefits. For example, Walters focuses on ysis of the effects of right-to-work laws. the pro-competition, pro-market policies He argues that they mainly are a signal to implemented by a line of mayors in Indiabusinesses that they will find a welcom- napolis, which is one of America’s most ing climate. States that allow compulsory successful big cities. unionism hurt their cities’ ability to comUrban theorists in the “progressive” trapete for investment by sending the oppo- dition insist that the problems that plague site signal. I think he’s correct. our cities can only be solved through masBy themselves, right-to-work laws don’t sive infusions of government money and change matters much. They can’t forbid expert planning. Walters’ book persuasively unionization, but only allow workers to makes the opposite case: protect people’s refuse to pay union dues. That doesn’t save property rights, then leave things to the companies any money and costs the unions spontaneous order of the free market. made claim that unions created America’s middle class. But that was in the days when unions were treated no differently than other voluntary organizations under the law. That changed with the enactment of the National Labor Relations Act in 1935 (upheld against constitutional challenge by the Supreme Court in 1937). The United Auto Workers promptly used their muscle to organize General Motors and Chrysler in 1937; Ford held out until 1941. (Walters provides the Spring 2015 You Had Me at Page One ✒ Review by David R. Henderson “I ’ve always had trouble succeeding along traditional Bush family lines.” So writes Jonathan Bush on p. 1 of his book, Where Does It Hurt? With that one sentence, he had me. Bush is a nephew of George H. W. Bush and a cousin of George W. Bush. I’m not a fan of politicians and those two, especially George W., rank low on my list. So when a Bush tries to make it in the private sector rather than in government, I’m already somewhat of a fan. Of course, Jonathan could have blown it by having nothing important to say in his book. But on the nuts and bolts of health policy, and even on what his uncle called the “vision thing,” he has a lot to say. I have been around health economics a long time, having been the senior economist for health policy at the Council of Economic Advisers under Ronald Reagan from 1982 to 1984. I’ve tracked the issues since then, and so I’ve read a lot of health care studies. Bush’s book, co-authored with Stephen Baker, is one of the best I’ve seen in a long time. new markets.” That last sentence got me thinking back to Austrian economist Israel Kirzner’s discussions of “entrepreneurial alertness.” In this digging, Bush does not disappoint. In chapter after chapter, he and Baker not only show how dysfunctional the health care system is, but also discuss ways that entrepreneurs can make it better. For example, after noting that a magnetic resonance imaging scan (MRI) at Massachusetts General Hospital would be billed at $5,315 to an insured patient, Bush runs the numbers and concludes that a business that did three images an hour and was open 12 hours a day could charge $99 per MRI and make huge profits. Entrepreneurial alertness / Where Does It Hurt? He goes beyond such stoBush is cofounder and CEO By Jonathan Bush with ries of possibilities and tells of Athenahealth; Baker is a Stephen Baker of actual successes. A doctor 224 pp.; Portfolio/ former senior writer for Businamed Arnold Milstein, for ness Week. They bring a deep Penguin, 2014 example, had worked with appreciation of the entreUnite Here, a union reprepreneur to their analysis of senting Las Vegas hotel and health care. “Entrepreneur” and “health casino workers. After analyzing the data, he care” in the same sentence? Really? eliminated the most expensive 10 percent Yes, really. They write, “From an entre- of doctors from the union’s health plan, preneur’s point of view, there’s something resulting in a $55 million reduction in highly appealing, almost intoxicating, health care expenditures. Amazingly, many about waste and dysfunction in the indus- of those doctors picketed the hotels where try.” They continue, “Those who can dig the union members worked! Milstein down through the morass of rules, paper- believes that the $55 million reduction work, and bureaucratic obstacles can find was due partly to the disciplining effect on the doctors who remained in the plan. Dav id R . Hender son is a research fellow with the Hoover Institution and an associate professor of economics And after being stuck at $13 an hour for at the Graduate School of Business and Public Policy at the Naval Postgraduate School in Monterey, Calif. He is the the previous few years, the workers’ average editor of The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics (Liberty Fund, 2008). He blogs at www.econlog.econlib.org. wage rose by $1.10. This shouldn’t be sur- / Regulation / 45 prising because, as economists well know, the cost of benefits is borne largely by the beneficiaries in the form of lower pay. Birthin’ babies / Bush’s first big entrepreneurial venture was in birthing. He calculated that more extensive use of midwives could save a lot of money and that if he set up a string of birthing centers, he could split the gains with insurers. So he and a business partner named Todd Park started Athena Women’s Health and set up some birthing centers in San Diego, with the plan of ultimately going national. The system worked—for the pregnant women. Bush writes: Only 10 percent of our births were delivered by C-section, about one-third of the national average. Ninety percent of the mothers who gave birth in our centers breast-fed their babies, compared to the 67 percent national average at the time. (Now it’s close to 80 percent.) We avoided the common widening incisions called episiotomies, which are expensive, horribly uncomfortable for the mother, and statistically counterproductive. Unfortunately, it didn’t work for Athena. Why? Their popularity hurt them. Such is the weird structure of health care and health insurance. Bush writes: It was the opposite of the way a sane market operates. Because we were popular, we attracted customers for what to most women is the most expensive medical procedure of their pre-Medicare years. Increasingly, health plans that offered Athena would receive three or four months of premiums and then pay claims that averaged $12,000—and then lose the customer. The insurers began to view us as toxic. A s**t magnet. Growing numbers of health plans fired us by kicking us out of their networks. The result: most of their remaining clients were on Medicaid or were uninsured and paid cash. What Bush doesn’t tell you, perhaps because he doesn’t know, is that in a world without insurance regulation, Athena 46 / Regulation / Spring 2015 in review probably would have made money. Why? Because without insurance regulation, most insurers would probably not have covered delivery, and people who wanted babies would have paid for birthing directly. As actuaries can tell you, for something to be an insurable event, it must typically have two characteristics: large loss and low probability. Because delivering a baby is expensive, the first criterion is covered. But in this era of birth control and legal abortion, a very large percentage of pregnancies brought to term are planned. So baby delivery does not fit the second criterion. Insurers started to cover it in states in which the state government required such coverage. Insurers not in those states started to cover it only when the federal government started requiring it in employer-provided health insurance with the Pregnancy Discrimination Act of 1978. Without that law, most people would do what my very modest-income parents did: save money to pay for delivering a baby. Under that model, Athena might have been a roaring success. Beyond birthin’ babies / Of course, that decades-old law was not something that Bush could change, even had he known about it. But, true entrepreneur that he is, he realized his mistake. In building the business, Bush’s firm had developed software to help the company get paid by insurance companies. Specifically, Park’s brother Eddie built software that incorporated each insurer’s idiosyncratic rules. The software worked well. A venture capitalist to whom Bush was appealing for funds to save his birthing business cut him off. “I’m not interested in your birthing business,” he said. “But I can get you $11 million for rights to your software.” So Bush’s company pivoted. In 1999, when the dot-com boom was at its height, “the new Athenahealth was reborn as an Internet company.” Put the Uzi away / The company moved back to the Boston area and did great, even after the dot-com bust. But there was one fly in the ointment: President George W. Bush. Jonathan writes, “My cousin, the forty-third president of the United States, was about to sign a bill that could destroy us.” How? A long-time “antikickback law” prevented hospitals and doctors “from exchanging services, information, or products of value with each other,” considering all such exchanges to be unethical. In 2004, a bill started working its Care Act.” Kocher went all Milton Friedman on the skewed incentives in the medical system that existed before the ACA and then admitted that the ACA didn’t do much to make that better. I wish that Bush had asked him whether he thought the ACA made it any better. Unfortunately, amidst all his great insights and stories, Bush forgets everything he learned on his trip to Washington and wimps out. “I don’t intend,” he writes, “to spend this chapter pounding on the government, or proposing a rapid shift A single detail in a law, he writes, “can to a private health care throw lives or entire companies into economy.” While, to his a tailspin.” Elsewhere he writes, credit, he wants “only a “Government is like a giant with an Uzi.” fraction” of the regulations we have today, he does want “smarter” way through Congress that would give regulations. “safe harbor” from that law to hospitals He does understand that the more comso that they could provide doctors with petition there is in health care, the better. digital technology. But it didn’t give safe How do you get more competition? One harbor to hospitals that bought Internet way is to get more insurance companies in services. the business. But he claims that this “is one So Bush flew to Washington to lobby area where the government could help, perCongress. It won’t surprise anyone who haps the way it does with Fannie Mae and has seen complex laws being made that Freddie Mac in real estate.” Really? Because few members of Congress even knew what Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac worked so was in the bill. In the office of Rep. Nancy well? Say it ain’t so, Jonathan. Johnson (R–Conn.), chair of the health There’s a much more straightforward subcommittee of the House Committee way to get more competition in insuron Ways and Means, Bush watched the ance, and it’s one of the few good ideas congresswoman page through the bill and that many of the Republicans had durfind the relevant section. He pointed to ing the ACA debates of 2009 and 2010: where it said “computers and software” allow people to buy insurance across state and asked her to add “and Internet ser- lines, with the rules dictated by the state in vices.” He writes, “She did.” which the insurer is located. This is done Bush got to see the ugliness of govern- with credit cards now, which is why it’s ment up close. A single detail in a law, he so much easier to get a credit card than it writes, “can throw lives or entire compa- was in the early 1970s. Such a solution is nies into a tailspin.” In one of the most not only good economics but also good memorable lines in the book, he writes, federalism. State governments should not “Government is like a giant with an Uzi.” be able to restrict interstate commerce. I was disappointed that, although Bush Conclusion / There is so much more of earlier had recognized the problems with value in the book. One striking section state regulation of interstate commerce, he is five pages of excerpts from a conversa- failed to apply that insight here. tion that Bush had with Bob Kocher, who Still, this is a great book. I’m glad that “worked for the Obama administration Jonathan chose his career rather that of his and wrote most of the original Affordable uncle and cousin. Spring 2015 Do Good Names Bring Great Riches? ✒ Review by Art Carden S ome great artists work with oils. Some work with stone. Gregory Clark works with data. The Son Also Rises is an excellent example of careful and creative inference from an incomplete historical record, namely the history of family social mobility. Clark offers detailed studies of the modern United States, modern Sweden, medieval and modern England, India, China, Taiwan, Japan, Korea, and Chile to show that patterns of social mobility are remarkably similar across societies. He deals with exceptions and anomalies toward the end of the book, and while there are unanswered questions and clear directions for further research, his treatment of the subject is impressively comprehensive. widely in their institutions—from modern Sweden to medieval England to Maoist China—exhibit remarkably similar patterns of social mobility: slow regression to the mean over generations. His findings are robust to different measures of status like income, education, and representation in high-status professions like law and medicine. He explores this empirically by looking at the changing positions of surnames across Track i ng s u rn a m e s / He different markers of status diverges from the usual (income and education, for studies of social mobility example) for different societby using a novel approach. ies. The surname Pepys, for He “estimates social mobilexample, is over-represented ity rates by measuring the in the medical field and rate at which surnames that in Oxford and Cambridge The Son Also Rises: originally had high or low Surnames and the His- admissions, though ironisocial status lose that status tory of Social Mobility cally the most famous Pepys connotation.” That idea was By Gregory Clark, of them all—Samuel Pepys, the inspired by a New York Times with Neil Cummins, diarist—left no heirs. reviewer of his 2007 book Yu Hao, and Daniel Clark argues for “a law of A Farewell to Alms (Princ- Diaz Vidal social mobility” whereby a eton University Press). Clark 364 pp.; Princeton family’s position in society is University Press, 2014 does this by assembling a determined by its members’ wide range of data sources underlying “social compeand looking to see whether tence.” It is an attractive and names that appear in high-status probate intuitive theory, but while this is distinct records and income tax lists later appear from inherited wealth or inherited ability, among lists of people in high-status occu- he nowhere defines exactly what this social pations (like doctors and lawyers), lists of competence is. At this stage in the research students enrolled at elite universities, and program, “social competence” is an X facother measures of status. tor (literally—see the equation on p. 125) One of his most impressive contribu- that explains trends in social mobility but tions is his finding that societies differing that so far remains undefined and unmeasured. Rather, it is inferred from the patArt Car den is an assistant professor of economics in the Brock School of Business at Samford University terns Clark identifies in the first half of the / Regulation / 47 book for Sweden, the United States, and England and then tests in the second half of the book for India, China, Japan, Korea, and Chile. He claims to have discovered an element of “social physics” governing social mobility over time. If we may extend the analogy to the physical sciences, “social competence” is his Higgs Boson: predicted by the theory and essential to the argument, but not actually observed. The story would be much more complete if he had defined and described social competence in greater detail, but this failure is an opportunity for further research rather than an irremediable flaw in his overall argument. Social competence will necessarily be a moving target, dependent on economic, political, social, and cultural contexts in society that are always shifting. Identifying the characteristics of the highest status people in a particular data set and then constructing a social competence index that measures a family’s social competence as a weighted average of the differences between a particular family and the highest-status family strikes me as something Clark could try, but such a measure is likely beyond the capacity of currently available data (and, for me, certainly beyond the capacity of a book review). Resistant to manipulation / People who appreciate the dismal aspects of economics will welcome some of the book’s conclusions. First, social mobility patterns are basically the same across the societies Clark studies and are stubbornly resistant to attempts to create new societies through social democracy (as in Sweden) or violent communist revolution (as in Mao’s China). Second, attempts to redress historical injustices through programs like the reservation system in India that reserves spots in universities and public jobs for people from historically oppressed castes actually work to the detriment of the poorest people in society. Clark’s work suggests there is more than political will standing in the way of greater social mobility. It is not clear, however, that social mobility should be at or near the top of 48 / Regulation / Spring 2015 in review the public policy agenda. In a rhetorical flourish, he refers to the bottom of a society as a “squalid netherworld.” If incomes and educational opportunities up and down the rungs of the social ladder were fixed, then social mobility would be a cause for great concern; that a person could be mired in a squalid netherworld through nothing more than an accident of birth offends many people’s sensibilities. Incomes and educational opportunities are not fixed, however, and there is no reason the bottom of the income status distribution should be squalid or a netherworld. In a growing economy, people up and down the income distribution will have more and better opportunities for flourishing and self-authorship even if we hold the income distribution fixed and completely eliminate social mobility. If people are confronted with ever-expanding opportunities to obtain food, clothing, shelter, and enlightenment, I don’t see why we should treat social mobility as an issue that requires corrective public policy even if we could do something about it. This isn’t to say that people should accept that they are like George Lucas’s droids or Akira Kurosawa’s peasants—“made to suffer”— but it isn’t clear that desire for status is a morally praiseworthy trait or a legitimate demand upon society. Our demand for status raises another important issue that was not necessarily germane to medieval English peasants and lords, but that is becoming more important with the rapid improvement and diffusion of communications technology. We get to choose our own “societies” in ways that were impossible to previous generations. This isn’t just because we can sort into political jurisdictions that best match our preferences with our constraints. The Internet has given us the ability to join or even form an infinite array of new societies. At the margin, the physical, material, and political societies in which we live become less relevant when we can choose to spend less time interacting with a society centered around geography (say, people who live in the United States) in order to spend more time interacting with a society centered around common interests. Here’s an example: Andrew Reams is one of my 6-year-old son’s heroes. To most people, Reams is just a guy who lives in Roanoke, Va. To people like my son who love elevators, though, he is YouTube celebrity “DieselDucy,” who takes followers on tours of landmark elevators, carwashes, arcades, and other mechanical marvels. People have always had hobbies and have always sought out others with common interests, but the Internet has made it much easier for people to craft their own societies centered around common interests or common networks. For instance, Reddit contributors who earn more “upvotes” than “downvotes” for their submitted links and comments earn “karma” that cannot be redeemed for anything, but that measures one’s standing within that community. The caption on one of my favorite xkcd cartoons reads, “Human subcultures are fractally nested. There is no bottom.” As better communications technology makes it easier for new subcultures to emerge, it will be interesting to see the degree to which people value status within the different “societies” to which they belong. And in 2115, I expect that one of Clark’s academic descendants will write a dissertation about it. In fact, I anticipate that a lot of future dissertations—probably from Clark’s academic home at the University of California, Davis—will extend his insights and methods to other cultures, contexts, and data sets. Clark-inspired investigations of the former Soviet Union and African countries, for example, would be extremely useful complements to this book. And some interesting debate about the minutiae of his data and methods will find homes on the specialized pages of journals like the Journal of Economic History, Economic History Review, and European Review of Economic History (which Clark edits). Finance According to Non-Academics ✒ Review by Vern McKinley O ver the past year, my reviews in Regulation have concentrated on books by academics expounding their views on the causes of and responses to the 2007–2008 financial crisis. This time, I’m reviewing three books on the crisis and other financial policy issues that have been written by non-academics: Nomi Prins, a journalist and former Wall Street analyst currently affiliated with Demos, a progressive public policy group; Steve Forbes, chairman and editor-in-chief of Forbes Media, and co-author Elizabeth Ames, a communications executive, speaker, and author; and Michael Lewis, a former Salomon Brothers bond salesman and best-selling author of the books Liar’s Poker (W. W. Norton, 1989), Moneyball (W. W. Norton, 2003), and The Big Short (W. W. Norton, 2010). V er n McKinley is a visiting scholar at the George Washington University Law School and author of Financing Failure: A Century of Bailouts (Independent Institute: 2012). Presidents and bankers / There is much to be said for Prins’ book, All the Presidents’ Bankers. It is a well researched and annotated history of the interconnections between U.S. presidents and private bankers from the days of President Teddy Roosevelt and the Panic of 1907 through President Obama and the Great Recession of 2007–2009. The book’s endnotes reveal a painstaking journey through a wide range of contemporary books, articles, and original documents drawn from the deep bowels of the archives of numerous presidents. Spring 2015 Much of the book and events, domestic or foreign, focuses on the “Big where the strongest associations Six,” a group of leadwere apparent over time. (McCloy ers of the largest banks is a perfect example of this.) This that first came together is probably not how I would have in 1929 with represenapproached this history, as I would tatives from Chase have tended to focus more on key National Bank, Bankers domestic banking events and the Trust Company, Guarbankers’ influence upon them, but anty Trust Company, such decisions are the prerogative National City Bank, of the author. Morgan Bank, and First One reason I would have focused National Bank. Prins All the Presidents’ on key domestic banking events very ably traces the Bankers: The Hidden would be to give more attention evolution of this group Alliances That Drive to important financial events of American Power over time all the way the past century that Prins largely through the megamerg- By Nomi Prins ignores or treats only superficially. ers of the 1990s and 521 pp.; Nation Books, For instance, in her book the War the financial crisis of 2014 Finance Corporation—a bank bailthe 2000s into today’s out program during World War I— “permutations of the only rates a very brief reference to original Big Six”: J.P. Morgan Chase, Mor- its chairman, Eugene Meyer. The saga of gan Stanley, Citigroup, Goldman Sachs, Continental Illinois and its near collapse Bank of America, and Wells Fargo. and rescue by the federal government durPrins chose to undertake an unbroken ing the mid-1980s does not even get a menhistory of modern U.S. banking. The upside tion. And Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are of this approach is that, with a few excep- only briefly discussed as part of the string tions, there is a feeling of completeness to of bailouts in 2008–2009. the work spanning over 100 years. HowIn some cases the analysis of the book ever, to me a downside of this approach is appears to be based on innuendo rather that some of the narratives are far afield than fact. For example, during the Panic from matters of banking, finance, and the of 1907 a number of significant financial financial industry. For example, the author institutions were on the brink of failure chronicles a range of foreign policy issues, after experiencing a run on their deposits. oftentimes simply because a key banker is Ultimately, the authorities facing tough involved in them in some official or unoffi- choices on New York institutions closed cial capacity. An example of this is a section down Knickerbocker Trust while other on the Shah of Iran seeking political asylum institutions such as Trust Company of in the United States, which was included America were bailed out by a consorbecause it involved bankers John McCloy tium of banks. One history of the crisis and John Rockefeller. explains that these decisions were based This approach made me curious about on a detailed review of the financial posiwhat methodology Prins used to choose tion of the firms, overseen by J.P. Morgan the hundreds of topics that she covers in and undertaken by Benjamin Strong (who the book. She explained to me that the would later become the first president of process started with each of the presi- the powerful Federal Reserve Bank of New dents and key administration figures and York). Strong’s analysis determined that worked outward to the individual bankers Knickerbocker was insolvent; Trust Comwhose names appeared in the presidential pany of America was solvent and worthy archives. Because this search led to an enor- of backstopping. (For more on this, see mous amount of material, the analysis was Robert Bruner and Sean Carr’s The Panic then narrowed down to those individuals of 1907 [Wiley, 2007].) Prins implies that / Regulation / 49 the Trust Company of America decision was not based on an objective analysis of solvency, but rather that the firm was saved because it had “more substantive ties to the major banks” and “had been blessed by the sponsorship of the Morgan team.” In contrast, Knickerbocker “had not garnered similar banker support.” The precise meaning of those phrases, as well as any underlying analysis, is not well documented by Prins. In other cases, she makes very clear her views of the lucrative nature of the connections between bankers and their presidents: During the postwar phase of the 1940s, [Winthrop] Aldrich traveled the world in a triple capacity: as chairman of the Chase Bank, president of the International Chamber of Commerce, and chairman of the Committee for Financing Foreign Trade. The impact on the bank’s bottom line was substantial…. The volume of business handled in all divisions of the foreign department increased enormously. Chase commercial loans in London doubled that year. Aldrich’s dual work as public servant and private banker was reaping rewards for his firm, and for his status as a diplomat. His partnership with [President Harry] Truman assured him of both. Like many progressives, Prins repeatedly stresses the deregulation bogeyman at numerous points throughout the 1980s, 1990s, and 2000s under presidents Jimmy Carter, Ronald Reagan, George H. W. Bush, and Bill Clinton, and blames this phenomenon for the “meltdown” of 2007–2008. Yet she offers little consideration or scrutiny of the bubble-inducing housing and loosemoney policies in the lead-up to the crisis. The detail on the 2007–2009 recession and financial crisis is not very deep. In a mere 4.5 pages, Prins addresses the full range of bank bailouts, from Bear Stearns in March 2008 through TARP and the bailout of Bank of America in early 2009. In her preface, she cites the information challenges of modern times and that the relationships 50 / Regulation / Spring 2015 in review between George W. Bush and but we have a pitiful and fragBarack Obama and the leadile recovery as evidenced by ing bankers of today are just feeble growth, misallocation not as readily available because of credit through government of the nature of modern compolicies, skyrocketing debt, munications. (“Bankers don’t and ongoing economic and put much in writing anymore, financial volatility. and there have been no tapes Forbes and Ames lay much of White House conversations of the blame for this state of since Nixon.”) She also notes affairs on unstable money: that a number of Freedom Unstable money is a little bit of Information Act requests like carbon monoxide. It’s at the Reagan, George H. W. Money: How the odorless and colorless. Most Bush, and Clinton libraries Destruction of the Dollar Threatens the were not responded to in time Global Economy—and people don’t realize the damage it’s doing until it’s very for the release of the book. As What We Can Do nearly too late. A fundamental someone who has filed many about It principle is that when money FOIA suits to undertake my By Steve Forbes and is weakened, people seek own writing projects, I can Elizabeth Ames 250 pp.; McGraw-Hill, to preserve their wealth by bear witness to these facts investing in commodities and on information availability. I 2014 hard assets. Prices of things would add that the Obama like housing, food, and fuel administration, which had start to rise, and we are often slow to vowed to be the “most transparent adminrealize what’s happening. istration in history,” is not really very transparent after all and its immediate predecesThe authors offer detail in rapid-fire sors would also not be in the running for succession on a number of diverse topics that honor. If you are drawn to the concept of a at the core of our financial and monetary century-long walk through the relation- system: ships between U.S. presidents and bankers, ■■ A detailed look at money and its three I think you would enjoy All the Presidents’ roles: measure of value, instrument of Bankers. If you are looking for a history trust that permits transactions, and of those events with extended analysis of a system of communication. Most of the policy-based decisionmaking process, this is basic Economics 101 and can be I think you would be disappointed. skimmed by most readers. Glory of gold / Money: How the Destruction of ■■ Money and trade: The authors assess the Dollar Threatens the Global Economy—and the distortive approach that many ecoWhat We Can Do about It is predominantly nomic analysts take in addressing this a blend of history and economic policy topic by focusing solely on the level of analysis on the state of money, which the merchandise trade deficit. Again, includes a detailed analysis of a proposed this is basic Economics 101, updated gold standard for the 21st century. Near for many of today’s monetary and the end, it morphs into a personal finance financial events. ■■ Why inflation is not a good thing: book à la Suze Orman, diving down into addresses the phenomenon of quandetail on what the discussion of money titative easing (“The biggest monetary means for investors on an individual basis. stimulus ever had produced the weakThe initial chapter of Money is an exploest recovery from a major downturn in ration of our current state of affairs with American history”) and the question regard to the economy: we may be over of why there has not been more inflathe so-called “Great Recession” for now, tion, notwithstanding all of the monetary easing. The authors’ answers to these questions focus on weakness in the methodology for the calculation of inflation; recent increases in the prices of commodities, in particular gold; and the fact that we are now in “uncharted territory” with regard to quantitative easing. The last point is the most important, as the jury is still out on the risk of inflation. Forbes and Ames properly focus on the economy in 2000 and the recession that began in 2001 as an inflection point for the monetary strategy that has so greatly contributed to the churning and volatility in the economy for the past 14 years of uncertainty. They end this chapter with the right question, “Should the Federal Reserve really be in the business of finetuning the economy?” ■■ Money and morality: chronicles the social unrest and instability that historically flows from debasement of currencies. Forbes and Ames note the oft-told story of the German Weimar Republic and draw from John Locke to support their contention that “the debasement of money drives a fissure into the core of society by defrauding both lender and borrower.” They then bring the moral issues to the most recent financial crisis, citing the social unrest in countries throughout Europe, tensions in the Middle East during the Arab Spring protests, the Occupy Wall Street movement in the United States, the expansion of government corruption, and the breakdown in what they call “trust assurance mechanisms” like credit review procedures and bond credit ratings. The authors complete this chapter on an ominous note by returning to a historical example: By 476 A.D., when barbarians wiped the empire from the map, Rome had committed moral and economic suicide. Romans first lost their character. Then, as a consequence, they lost their liberties and ultimately their civilization. Will that be us? Spring 2015 For those who regularly follow the economic and financial industry (through the Wall Street Journal, Bloomberg, CNBC, etc.), most of this early analysis will be familiar and not particularly earth-shattering. But it represents a good review in preparation for the core of the book, which is the argument for a 21st century gold standard: We need gold because, as we’ve emphasized throughout this book, gold is the best and the only way to achieve truly stable money. Relinking the dollar to gold would eliminate the economic volatility and monetary crises that have been the consequences of fiat money. It would stop the erosion of our wealth that is taking place today as a result of Fed-engineered inflation. With a gold standard, there would be no inflation. The authors then summarize their ideas for a gold standard in list format, addressing in turn: four options for the gold standard, the recommended features for a gold standard for the 21st century, and some myths and misconceptions about the gold standard. The last section is probably the most useful as it counters gold standard critics by addressing one-byone many of the common criticisms of the gold standard: the extent of price volatility for gold, limitations on the supply of gold to sustain a gold standard today, the gold standard being among the causes and prolongation of the Great Depression, and the ability of speculators to undermine a gold standard. I should note that some of the authors’ responses to those concerns are not completely satisfying. For example, they lay the blame for the Great Depression on the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act, which is a tremendous oversimplification. The most convincing of their arguments for a gold standard relates to politics: Gold takes decisions about the value and supply of money out of the hands of bureaucrats whose judgment is too often in error or driven by politics…. A gold standard puts the lid on the shenanigans politicians like to use for / Regulation / 51 algorithms to trade securities and, according to Lewis, “front-run” the trades of others—this is where traders are tipped off to the demand for a stock on one exchange and buy it at a lower price on another and arbitrage. Those who follow this strategy A few final comments on the overall style make mere pennies per trade, but cumuof Forbes and Ames are in order at this point. latively make massive profits in essentially It is hard to measure with any risk-free trades. Lewis argues type of metric, but the authors through his storytelling that rely on the opinions of others because of HFTs, the market a great deal, quoting them at is “rigged” and is essentially length and to what seems an a “fraud.” He puts the story outsized extent. As a reader in an “us against them” conI generally expect authors to struct, where “ordinary invespredominantly present their tors” are getting screwed by own interpretations and opinthe HFTs. This is ominously ions on the topic at hand. stated on the book jacket, Additionally, the topic of which warns “if you have any money itself can be dense. contact with the market, even Presenting the material in a Flash Boys: A Wall a retirement account, this variety of formats—not only Street Revolt story is happening to you.” with words but also with By Michael Lewis According to Lewis, HFTs tables and graphs blended 274 pp.; W. W. Norton, dominate the market, not in—is ideal. Economist Alan 2014 because they are doing a betBlinder effectively uses graphs ter job of delivering their serand tables, although I do not vices like true capitalists, but agree with him on policy. However, Forbes because of the convoluted business model and Ames almost exclusively describe mat- and technological basis for HFTs’ tradters of money through words. In fact, I ing. That supposedly gives an advantage could find only one graph and not a single to those firms who figure out how to cut table in their book. milliseconds off trading times through time-staking placement of servers and fiber Tales of HFTs / Flash Boys: A Wall Street Revolt optic cable wires. As Lewis summarizes it: is another in a series of Michael Lewis’s The U.S. stock market was now a class trademark genre of financial journalsystem, rooted in speed, of haves and ism. Like his classic book The Big Short, he have-nots. The haves paid for nanosecabsorbs himself in a topic by interviewing onds; the have-nots had no idea that a myriad of people working in the industry a nanosecond had value. The haves segment under scrutiny and then weaves a enjoyed a perfect view of the market; the narrative of the most interesting characters have-nots never saw the market at all. into an entertaining, humorous, gripping, The heroes in Lewis’s one-sided saga and profanity-sprinkled read. It should be noted that Lewis’s stories are not heavy on are a motley crew of characters who work financial sector policy; in fact, I purchased on putting together a platform to counterand began reading The Big Short back in act the convoluted strategies of the HFTs 2010 when I was writing my own book on through a competing stock exchange: the financial crisis, but abandoned Lewis’s ■■ Brad Katsuyama, the book’s lead charbook less than halfway through. acter and a former trader for Royal His new book places the strategy of Bank of Canada (RBC), who after years “high frequency traders” (HFTs) in the of working in the market had an epiphworst of lights. HFTs are traders who use political gain. We’ve all seen the effects of leaving monetary and fiscal discretion in the hands of politicians and their appointees: chronic inflation and chronic government debt. 52 / Regulation / Spring 2015 in review any regarding the inherent unfairness in the market: That’s when I realized the markets are rigged. And I knew it had to do with the technology. That the answer lay beneath the surface of the technology. I had absolutely no idea where. But that’s when the lightbulb went off that the only way I’m going to find out what’s going on is if I go beneath the surface. He later led the creation of the IEX in 2012, an exchange that is now competing head-to-head with the other exchanges tainted by HFTs, by leveraging its distinct business model. ■■ ■■ Rob Park, a former co-worker of Katsuyama’s when they developed RBC’s trading algorithm. He was hired by Katsuyama to help him investigate what was “beneath the surface.” Ronan Ryan, an Irish immigrant, who stayed behind in the United States after his dad returned to Ireland following a work stint here. A self-described “tech guy” who always had a desire to work on Wall Street, he joined Katsuyama’s cause because of his knowledge of “the frantic competition for nanoseconds.” An additional featured character not connected with Katsuyama is Sergey Aleynikov, a Russian computer programmer who immigrated to the United States and ultimately worked at Goldman Sachs, patching up their old trading platform. He departed Goldman to work for a new hedge fund in order to develop an entirely new trading platform. He was later arrested by the Federal Bureau of Investigation and charged by the government with stealing code from Goldman Sachs. Lewis explains his focus on Aleynikov I’d thought it strange, after the financial crisis, in which Goldman had played such an important role, that the only Goldman Sachs employee who had been charged with any sort of crime was the employee who had taken something from Goldman Sachs. Lewis does not directly delve into the policy implications for HFTs, but it is clear from his narrative that he thinks something needs to be done about them. Throughout the book he takes shots at HFTs on a number of fronts: the two-tiered system that they reveal, the role of HFTs in causing so-called “flash crashes” where there is a dramatic drop in the stock price of a single firm or the market as a whole, and their role in undermining market integrity. Despite his complaints, I find Lewis less convincing than Holly Bell’s July 2013 Cato Policy Analysis (“High Frequency Trading: Do Regulators Need to Control this Tool of Informationally Efficient Markets?” #731) argument that HFTs in general are not bad things and they cannot be blamed for Lewis’s list of market ills. Not surprisingly, Lewis’s book has caused a divide on Wall Street. The response of William O’Brien, president of BATS Global Markets, in a debate with Lewis and Katsuyama is typical (“The Great HFT Debate with Michael Lewis on CNBC,” available on YouTube): “The first thing I’d say is, Michael and Brad, shame on both of you for falsely accusing literally thousands of people and possibly scaring millions of investors in an effort to promote a business model.” But Katsuyama gets it right when he responds that the “market [is] providing the solution,” as demonstrated by his IEX. If HFTs really are a problem, IEX will prosper and be copied; if not, it will fade away. For me, the policy divide over HFTs is much ado about nothing. As a small, individual investor, I don’t feel like I have been cheated by the HFTs, as I am in the market for the long run. The best way to look at Flash Boys is that it is an entertaining read— but not an important policy analysis. Adam Smith’s Guide to Living ✒ Review by David R. Henderson T he great 18th century economist and moral philosopher Adam Smith published two major treatises during his lifetime. The better-known Wealth of Nations (WN), published in 1776, is one of the first landmark economics books and some claim that it was the start of political economy. In it, Smith argues that for the well-being of the vast majority of people to improve steadily, the government must play a limited role: providing defense and protection, building some infrastructure, and not much else. He also argues that economic freedom harnesses self-interest, so that by doing well for ourselves, within the bounds of justice, we do good for our fellow man. His earlier book, The Theory of Moral Sentiments (TMS), published in 1759, is different. In it, he discusses how we should behave toward each other. He puts much less weight on self-interest and highlights beneficence toward our fellow humans. Dav id R . Hender son is a research fellow with the Hoover Institution and an associate professor of economics at the Graduate School of Business and Public Policy at the Naval Postgraduate School in Monterey, Calif. He is the editor of The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics (Liberty Fund, 2008). He blogs at www.econlog.econlib.org. Did the 17 years between the books cause him to become less optimistic about the fundamental nature of human beings? One might think so. But in How Adam Smith Can Change Your Life, economist Russ Roberts makes a persuasive case that Smith did not change at all, but was merely addressing two different questions. In WN, Smith explains that an increasingly extensive division of labor, which causes us to depend more and more on the actions of strangers who are more and more distant from us, makes us better off. The self-interest of these strangers causes them to work for us even if they never hear of us. According to Roberts, TMS by contrast “is overwhelmingly a book about the people closest to us, the ones we can actively sympathize with— Spring 2015 our family, our friends, and our immediate neighbors.” George Mason University economist Daniel Klein, whom Roberts references, believes TMS is about political ethics as well as private morals. Nevertheless, they both agree, as did the late Ronald Coase, there is no contradiction between WN and TMS. Roberts’ goal, at which he succeeds admirably, is to elaborate on Smith’s insights in TMS, explaining many passages from the 1759 book and making the insights vivid through contemporary examples from his own life and the modern world. Toward the end, Roberts shows that even in TMS, Smith had some things to say about how intrusive governments can cause problems. elements. The first is to observe propriety. This means, according to Roberts, meeting the expectations of those around us: acting in the way they expect, which makes it easier for them to interact with us. Roberts gives many examples, ranging from saying “please” and “thank you” to sympathizing with people in their moments of grief. But what if people’s expectations of us are improper? Roberts doesn’t raise this question explicitly, but he addresses it using Smith’s conception of virtue. Virtue, for Smith, involves prudence, justice, and beneficence. In modern terms, writes Roberts, prudence means “taking care of yourself”; justice means “not hurting others”; and beneficence means “being good to others.” The prudent man, claims How Adam Smith Being lovely / Roberts does Roberts, does not smoke, is Can Change Your Life a marvelous job of explain“physically active and keeps By Russ Roberts ing Smith’s insights about his weight under control,” humans. Nine of the 10 chap- 251 pp.; Portfolio/ and “works hard and avoids Penguin, 2014 ters are on particular themes debt.” On debt, I must part in Smith’s book, including company. It was by taking on how to know yourself, how what seemed like a massive to be happy, how not to fool yourself, how debt at the time—1986—that my wife and to be loved, and how to be lovely. I managed to buy a house in coastal CaliIn one chapter, Roberts introduces his fornia. I doubt that Roberts would have own law, “The Iron Law of You.” It states criticized our decision even prospectively. that you care more about yourself than you So I think he must mean something like do about others and that others care more “avoids too much debt” or “consistently about themselves than they do about you. spends beyond his means.” We can offset this, Roberts writes, by payBeing just is relatively easy to undering attention to the person whom Smith stand: don’t cheat. It’s important, note called “the impartial spectator.” Who is both Roberts and Smith, not to cheat in this spectator? God? No. Roberts writes even little ways. If we do, there will be, that it’s a kind of human being looking writes Smith, “no enormity so gross of over our shoulder, one who thinks beyond which we may not be capable.” us and our narrow concerns. Beneficence is harder to define. AccordHow do we become happy? Smith ing to Smith, the rules of beneficence are wrote, “Man naturally desires, not only “loose, vague, and indeterminate.” Robto be loved, but to be lovely.” If we figure erts writes that some of its aspects are those two things out, we will be happy. “friendship, humanity, hospitality [and] And by being lovely, Smith meant being generosity.” worthy of being loved. If we strive to be He discusses his challenges in following lovely, Roberts writes, then we will be loved. these rules while raising four children. One That raises the question, how do we beneficent rule he created was always to take become lovely? There are two important his daughter’s or son’s hand when offered. A / Regulation / 53 rule I created for myself before my daughter was a year old was, when she asked me to play with her or do anything with her, to say yes at least 90 percent of the time. Good and bad systems / The two chapters most directly relevant to readers of this magazine are “How to Make the World a Better Place” and “How Not to Make the World a Better Place.” In the former chapter, Roberts discusses a range of phenomena, from the evolution of language, to men wearing hats, to traffic patterns—all of which Adam Ferguson, a Scottish contemporary of Smith, called “the result of human action, but not of human design.” In Roberts’ view, thinking “clearly about the complex interaction of individual actions that lead to unintended patterns of predictable and orderly outcomes” is “the single deepest contribution of economics to understanding how the world works.” Roberts notes the irony that Smith’s most profound thoughts on the ways in which we benefit others without particularly intending to do so are found more in TMS than in WN. The bottom line here is that to make the world a better place, we need to be good people. We are not likely, on our own, to make the bigger world much better, but we should do our share. To take an example from my own life, I don’t believe that the few hundred dollars I give to each of four or five charities every year will have a noticeable effect on the world. And yet I do give because I feel an obligation to give to charities that do good. As Roberts writes, “When you behave with virtue, you are helping to sustain” a system of norms and informal rules. In “How Not to Make the World a Better Place,” Roberts highlights Smith’s criticism of what he called “the man of system” and what I call “the life arranger.” Smith writes that the man of system seems to imagine that he can arrange the different members of a great society with as much ease as the hand arranges the different pieces upon a chess-board. He does not consider that the pieces upon the chess-board have no other 54 / Regulation / Spring 2015 in review principle of motion besides that which the hand impresses upon them; but that, in the great chess-board of human society, every single piece has a principle of motion of its own, altogether different from that which the legislature might chuse to impress upon it. If those two principles coincide and act in the same direction, the game of human society will go on easily and harmoniously, and is very likely to be happy and successful. If they are opposite or different, the game will go on miserably, and the society must be at all times in the highest degree of disorder. Roberts gives examples of “men of system,” ranging from extreme mass murderers—Pol Pot, Stalin, and Mao (I would have added Hitler)—to the less extreme examples we see in the United States: those who decided to invade and try to remake Iraq and those who think the government can achieve good results with the drug war. Roberts writes that people often “have trouble remembering that there are other ways of changing the world than using legislation.” He takes the example of smoking. Per-capita consumption of tobacco in the United States “fell by 50 percent in the last half of the twentieth century.” Admittedly, some of this was due to higher taxes on cigarettes and restrictions on where one can smoke. But most of those restrictions came along within the past 20 years, by which time much of the decline had already occurred. Roberts writes, “Smoking is no longer cool or hip.” Great change happened because individual people decided to change. Men of system, take note. And get lost. From More than Zero to Less than One ✒ Review by Pierre Lemieux P eter Thiel co-founded PayPal in 1998. The intention was “to create a new internet currency to replace the U.S. dollar … [with] a digital currency that would be controlled by individuals instead of governments.” After selling the company to eBay, he became a very successful venture capitalist, including being the first outside investor in Facebook. Another startup in which he has invested is SpaceX, the private space flight company whose reusable rockets are “the key to making human life multiplanetary,” according to the company’s website. He is now a billionaire. Thiel is also an avowed libertarian. He expounded his version of libertarianism in “The Education of a Libertarian,” published in the April 2009 Cato Unbound. Unlike most Silicon Valley entrepreneurs, his political contributions go to Libertarian and Republican candidates. He has financially backed the Seasteading Institute, which aims to Pier r e Lemieux is an economist affiliated with the Department of Management Sciences at the Université du Québec en Outaouais. His latest book is Who Needs Jobs? (Palgrave Macmillan, 2014). create autonomous communities on manbuilt structures at sea. Now he has published Zero to One, a book in which he offers insights into business innovation and economic growth. It is more than the typical billionaire’s ghostwritten book: it is based on the notes taken by a student—Blake Masters, the book’s co-author—in a class Thiel gave at Stanford University in 2012. In the book, Thiel explains how successful startups—those that change the world— are created and managed. He argues that they are monopolies and that, in terms of economic growth, monopolies are preferable to market competition because successful monopolies typically create completely new goods. Instead of merely “adding more to something familiar,” of going from one to some finite number on an allegorical scale of innovation, they go from zero to one, approaching infinite growth. / Business management theory is a very soft field, often based on slogans and fads. Looking over the past decades, think of such management-techniques-cum-mantras as “management by objectives,” “the pursuit of excellence,” “employee empowerment,” “business process engineering,” “core competencies,” and “six sigma,” not to mention the Japanese model, business ethics, “corporate social responsibility,” and corporate governance. Thiel should not be held to standards that full-time management gurus do not reach. Moreover, he is more interested in entrepreneurship and the creation of new businesses than in dry management of established dinosaurs. The entrepreneurship he practices and preaches resembles the Kirznerian type (after Austrian School economic theorist Israel Kirzner), defined as the mysterious alertness and ability to see opportunities that nobody else notices. You need to “have secrets,” writes Thiel— that is, “specific reasons for success that other people don’t see.” It follows that entrepreneurship is not teachable: “The paradox of teaching entrepreneurship is that such a formula necessarily cannot exist.” It is no surprise then that Zero to One has problems explaining it. Thiel’s musings are often original. For example, “a valuable business must start by finding a niche and dominating a small market.” Grand missions and big plans are necessary. Founders should be “unusual individuals” who “lead companies beyond mere incrementalism.” But even if an entrepreneurial company should mimic a cult, “you also need a structure to keep everyone aligned for the long term.” “A bad plan is better than no plan” (emphasis in original). The reader may find some of Theil’s management principles a bit too obvious, like “sales matter just as much as prod- Entrepreneurial reflections Spring 2015 ucts,” or “creating value is that pay chosen students not not enough—you also need to to go to college. There may be capture some of the value you a contradiction here between create.” But perhaps obvious the espousal of populism and things need to be repeated. the implicit elitism of conYet Thiel yields to the trarian entrepreneurs and management guru’s tempthinkers, but Thiel does not tation. He has seven quesexplore the issue. tions that, if all answered Competition and monopoly positively, will ensure that you “master fortune and / Thiel, whose formal training is in law, seems to hold succeed.” His venture capital economics in high suspicion. fund claims to “never invest Zero to One: Notes on He gets many things right in a tech CEO that wears a Startups, or How to when he stays close to what suit.” (Applicants for Thiel’s Build for the Future he knows—when he defends venture money take notice!) By Peter A. Thiel the usefulness of technoIn a new venture, “working with Blake Masters logical progress, for example. remotely should be avoided.” 224 pp.; Crown But economic analysis would He postulates that “a startup Publishing, 2014 have saved him from some messed up at its foundation errors—or, at least, would cannot be fixed.” Obscure rhetoric is just around the corner: “no have helped him argue his case better. Consider his take on competition, company has a culture; every company is monopoly, and capitalism. We can suma culture.” Sometimes, he pushes his ideas too marize his argument in four points: far and spreads them too thin. He seems ■■ Economics puts too much emphasis to favor a very nonevolutionary vision of on competition, “the ideal and the progress: “How can the future get better if default in Economics 101.” no one plans for it?” He criticizes the use ■■ Monopoly, not competition, is the of Darwinist evolution “to build a better goal of business: “Monopoly is the condisociety,” apparently unaware of Hayek’s tion of every successful business [emphasis argument that Darwin borrowed the conin original]. … All failed companies cept of evolution from social scientists, not are the same: they failed to escape the other way around. competition.” It is fashionable to criticize economists ■■ “Most businesses are much closer to and they sometimes deserve it. Thiel falls the extreme of monopoly than we prey to a strand of libertarian thinking commonly assume.” that rejects rational choice. “In econom■■ “Capitalism and competition are ics,” he argues, “disbelief in secrets leads opposites.” to faith in efficient markets.” He ignores that markets tend to be efficient precisely These statements are either incomplete or because intuitive and enthusiastic entre- incorrect, for the following reasons: preneurs go against conventional wisdom, incorporate new information in Not all of economics overemphasizes compeprices, and push the market closer to its tition. Many economists, no doubt, have mistakenly taken the explanatory model equilibrium. He also seems under the influence of of perfect competition as an exact ideal another, sometimes parallel, strand of to be imposed onto real markets, as in populist libertarianism that rejects the antitrust crusades. Yet, there is a positive usefulness of formal, standardized learn- reason for sticking to competition as an ing in favor of practical deeds and tradi- explanatory model: it often provides the tional knowledge. He offers fellowships best model to describe what happens in / Regulation / 55 the real world, just as a Euclidian line with zero thickness is useful to measure real-world lines. At the normative level, competition does have large benefits: the tendency toward a competitive equilibrium allows consumers to get what they want at the lowest possible price. Perhaps it is true that monopoly “can allow a business to transcend the daily brute struggle for survival.” But a free economy works for the benefits of consumers, not producers. Of this, the competitive model serves as a constant reminder. It is because businesses want monopolies that competition exists. Thiel himself seems to understand this: “The dynamism of new monopolies itself explains why old monopolies don’t strangle innovation.” So why the criticism of competition? When “monopolies” compete or face potential competitors, we have a competitive system, not a monopolistic one. There are no monopolies on a free market. The problem with Thiel’s focus on monopolies might be a matter of definition. But some definitions are more fruitful than others. It is useful to view a monopoly as a single firm protected from competition by legal constraints to entry in its industry. Thiel correctly opposes such constraints and emphatically states that the good monopolies he argues for are not the stateprotected variety. But then he tends to forget that there is no monopoly when many firms compete, even if they are not equal. There is a more fundamental argument against seeing monopolies everywhere. As Thiel himself suggests (without following through on the idea), determining whether there is competition or monopoly depends on how one defines the relevant markets. Google has 68 percent of the search-engine market, which it uses for advertising, but only 3.4 percent of the global advertising market and only 0.24 percent of the consumer tech market (the figures are from Thiel). How one defines a market is essentially arbitrary, so each firm can be thought of as either a tiny monopoly or an atomistic competitor in the larger market. What 56 / Regulation / Spring 2015 in review Thiel call “monopolies”—Google, Apple, PayPal, etc.—are only large companies that have dominant positions in some markets. The opposition of capitalism and competition is not useful. One can define capitalism and competition as one wants, including in opposition to each other. But defining capitalism as an economic system where there is no competition easily leads to many errors. One is to forget the consumer in favor of the producer. Another error is to underplay the importance of freedom to enter markets and freedom to compete—those freedoms being what really matters if we are interested in economic efficiency and consumer welfare. Poor economics / In his 1973 book Capital- ism and the Permissive Society, Samuel Brittan expressed dismay at how inefficient capitalists were at defending capitalism, but noted that “businessmen are paid to operate the system rather than understand or expound it.” I would add that great entrepreneurs get their money for the new opportunities they offer to consumers, but their economic and social theories are not necessarily outstanding. Zero to One does have the benefit of emphasizing entrepreneurship, but one would not use the book to teach either political philosophy or economics. Consider the nature of value. Why does something have value? Thiel makes the strange claim that Google creates less value than the airlines. To reach that conclusion, he equates a firm’s value with its revenues or profits. A few centuries of economic analysis teach that value is the “utility” (satisfaction of preferences) that individuals get from exchange. If we use a partial equilibrium framework, we can (conceptually) calculate value as the consumer surplus—that is, the difference between what consumers would have been willing to pay for something and what they actually have to pay. Profits or rents translate into value only because they allow their recipients to get their own consumer surpluses when they spend their money as consumers. It is thus very likely that Google creates much more value than Thiel assumes. To take another example, he compares the revenues of venture capital–backed companies with gross domestic product, of which the companies represent “an astounding 21 percent.” This is only astounding because it compares revenues (total sales) of some companies with value added (profits) in the whole economy, GDP being the sum of the latter, not of the former. Zero to One is a small, easy-to-read book in which the reader will learn about what a great entrepreneur and libertarian visionary thinks. Some of this is interesting but intellectually light. There is not a single footnote in the book, so the reader cannot check sources. On the positive side, Tyler Cowen endorsed the book. But I suggest that it will, at best, only take your social and economic understanding from more than zero to less than one. Sunstein’s Knowledge Problem Review by Phil R. Murray I n the layman’s way of thinking, a regulation that saves just one life is worthwhile regardless of its costs. In the economic way of thinking, a regulation that saves just one life is worthwhile only if it costs less than the value of a life. Cass Sunstein expands on this economic way of thinking in his new book, Valuing Life. In it, he documents his experience overseeing the Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA) in the early years of the Obama administration, explains how the regulatory apparatus works, and shares his views on “humanizing” the process. By “humanizing the regulatory state,” Sunstein wants to accomplish four objectives. The first is to justify a widespread application of cost-benefit analysis. He puts it this way: cost-benefit analysis “should see costs and benefits not as arithmetic abstractions, but as efforts to capture qualitatively diverse goods and to promote sensible tradeoffs among them.” His second objective is to recognize “nonquantifiable” factors such as “dignity,” “equity,” and “privacy.” The third is to incorporate behavioral economics into cost-benefit analysis, and the fourth is “to collect the dispersed information held by a nation’s citizenry” and use that to formulate regulations. OIRA’s work / Sunstein wants to remedy the Phil R . Mur r ay is a professor of economics at Webber International University. “poorly understood” operation of OIRA, which neither originates nor rubberstamps regulations. “It would not be excessive,” in his view, “to describe OIRA as, in large part, an information aggregator.” By gathering this “specialized information” and “dispersed information,” he sees OIRA trying to overcome the “knowledge problem” outlined by Friedrich Hayek. OIRA aims “to promote a well-functioning process of public comment, including state and local governments, businesses large and small, and public interest groups.” Sunstein describes this as “regulatory due process.” There are four essential aspects of OIRA procedure: OIRA incorporates “interagency views.” ■■ The discussion of these interagency views explains why the OIRA procedure may be long and drawn out. ■■ Even though OIRA focuses on costs and benefits, it concentrates more on “interagency concerns, promoting the receipt of public comments (for ■■ Spring 2015 / What circumstances make a problem more challenging? Take a regulation that costs $200 million per year. The agency proposing it estimates that it will save 24 people from dying of cancer, and the VSL is $8 million. Although the benefits in this case Valuing Life is not a manual with detailed in terms of lives saved ($192 million) are instructions on how to calculate costs less than the costs, “it will be acceptable and benefits. Sunstein presents dozens of for the agency to do a sensitivity analysis “highly stylized problems” with the costs in which it increases the VSL because canand benefits given, and tells cer is involved.” This is one us how the process will coninstance in which Sunstein tinue from there. The simadvocates “humanizing” plest problem he presents is regulations. a regulation that costs $200 Consider his reasons million per year and generfor humanizing regulaates $400 million in benefits tions related to cancer. “For per year. “In the process of example,” he reports, “some OIRA review, the numbers evidence suggests that peowill be carefully scrutinized, ple are willing to pay high and many questions will be amounts to avoid cancer asked about their accuracy risks, and hence there is reaand meaning,” he assures us, son to think that people’s Valuing Life: Human“but if those questions have izing the Regulatory VSL is higher for cancer risks good answers, this is an easy State than sudden, unanticipated one in favor of proceeding.” By Cass R. Sunstein deaths.” Perhaps a greater As part of that work, gov- 248 pp.; University of aversion to death from canernment agencies estimate Chicago Press, 201 cer than, say, a heart attack a “value of a statistical life is rational. Sunstein adds (VSL).” Sunstein explains: that “all cancer fatalities are “Suppose that workers must be paid $900, not the same; informed people would on average, to assume a risk of 1:10,000. surely make distinctions between those If so, the VSL would be said to be $9 mil- that involve long periods of suffering lion.” For an alternative approach to reach and those that do not.” Despite people’s the same VSL, suppose that one in 10,000 greater willingness to pay to avoid some firefighters will die on the job and the risks over others, OIRA does not “distintypical firefighter is willing to pay $900 to guish among mortality risks” and never eliminate that risk. Multiplying $900 per has. However, an agency may do “sensitivfirefighter by 10,000 firefighters yields $9 ity analysis,” add a “cancer premium” to million, which is the value of eliminating the VSL, and possibly “conclude that the the risk necessary to save one firefighter’s benefits ‘justify’ the costs.” That would life. The simplest problem Sunstein pres- amount to the same thing as computing ents that involves a life-saving regulation different VSLs based on different risks, costs $300 million per year and saves 40 would it not? lives. Using the $9 million VSL, the benSunstein is well known for using efits of the regulation amount to $360 insights from behavioral economics to million and “the regulation will likely go shape public policies. In Valuing Life, he forward.” Note that if this regulation were describes a behavioral slip-up dubbed to save just one life, it would be a mistake “probability neglect” that relates to canto implement it because the costs would cer risk. “People fall victim to probability exceed the benefits. neglect,” he explains, “if and to the extent proposed rules), ensuring discussion of alternatives, and promoting consideration of public comments (for final rules).” ■■ OIRA’s work is “technical,” relating to economics, science, the law, etc. Humanizing regulation / Regulation / 57 that the intensity of their reaction does not greatly vary even with large differences in the likelihood of harm.” Take the results of an experiment Sunstein and a colleague conducted with their law students. They queried a first group “to state their maximum willingness to pay to eliminate a cancer risk of 1 in 1 million.” They put the same question to another group but increased the risk of cancer to one in 100,000. A third group faced the same question as the first, plus “the cancer was described in vivid terms, as ‘very gruesome and intensely painful, as the cancer eats away at the internal organs of the body.’” The fourth group faced the same question as the second, along with the “emotional description” of cancer. If the subject of cancer causes people to neglect probability, their willingness to pay to eliminate a risk of one in 100,000 will be less than 10 times that for a risk of one in 1 million. That is what Sunstein and his colleague found when asking questions both with and without the “emotional description” of cancer. They also expected that adding the emotional description would cause greater probability neglect, and confirmed that, too. Subjects who heard the emotional description stated a mean willingness to pay of $211.67 to eliminate the one in 1 million risk of cancer, compared to $250 to eliminate the risk of one in 100,000. “When the cancer was described in emotionally gripping terms,” in other words, “people were insensitive to probability variations.” This reviewer doubts that we should attach much weight to a single experiment involving 67 students at Harvard Law School. Nonetheless, Sunstein draws from it “two implications for the public reaction to emotionally gripping events.” One is that “simply because such events arouse strong feelings, they are likely to trigger a larger behavioral response than do statistically identical risks that do not produce emotional reactions.” This is the rationale an agency uses when considering a “cancer premium” along with other benefits of a regulation designed to 58 / Regulation / Spring 2015 in review reduce the risk of cancer. Another implication is “that probability neglect might well play a role in the government’s reaction to emotionally gripping events, in part because many people will focus on the badness of the outcome, rather than on its likelihood.” This point raises the question of what the government should do when events such as terrorism raise the public’s alarm. On the one hand, it would be wise to do nothing. “There is a strong argument that government should not respond,” Sunstein reasons, “if the relevant risks are very small and if the requested steps have costs in excess of benefits.” There is also a role for the government “to inform and educate people” whenever the probability of a tragic event is low. “But if information and education do not work,” Sunstein continues, “government might be willing to consider regulatory responses to fears that are not fully rational, but real and by hypothesis difficult to eradicate.” He is not using probability neglect as an excuse to open the door wide for more regulations. He warns that “a special difficulty here consists in the problem of quantifying and monetizing fear and its consequences.” Quantification and monetization are more ways of “humanizing” regulations. He presents a scenario in which the costs of a regulation “to make buildings more accessible to people who use wheelchairs” exceed the “monetized benefits.” Officials proceed with the regulation, nevertheless, by making a case that the value of “human dignity” to wheelchair users makes up for the deficiency of monetized benefits. Sunstein cites the actual reasoning of Justice Department officials from a document pertaining to the Americans with Disabilities Act: “Dividing the $32.6 million annual cost by the 677 million annual uses [of water closets with doors that open outward, making them more accessible], we conclude that for the costs and benefits to break even in this context, people with the relevant disabilities will have to value safety, independence, and the avoidance of stigma and humiliation at just under 5 cents per use.” It seems plausible that this lower bound on the value of human dignity would justify the costs of modifying such water closets. Sunstein recognizes “objections” to quantifying or monetizing benefits, though he continues to advocate those practices. Moral heuristics / I had suspected that Sunstein was eager to regulate. In Valuing Life, however, his presentation of behavioral economics causes me to reconsider. “Heuristics” are “mental shortcuts” that people use when making decisions. Even though they may be reliable sometimes, they may also produce bad outcomes. For anyone who ever asked whether behavioral economists ever cite the anomalies they are so fond of to make a case against regulation, Sunstein’s explanation of “moral heuristics” is evidence that he, for one, does. Take the “Precautionary Principle,” which according to Sunstein “is designed to insert a ‘margin of safety’ into all decision making, and to impose a burden of proof on proponents of activities or processes to establish that they are ‘safe.’” (See “The Paralyzing Principle,” Winter 2002–2003.) That idea sounds reasonable initially. But Sunstein deems it “incoherent.” “The reason,” he explains, “is that risk regulation often introduces risks of its own.” His critique is so effective that this reviewer wonders why the Precautionary Principle is not less popular. “For example,” he continues, “regulation of nuclear power might increase the likelihood that societies will depend on fossil fuels, which create air pollution and emit greenhouse gases.” The following point not only goes against the Precautionary Principle, but too much regulation in general: “By its very nature, costly regulation threatens to increase unemployment and poverty, and both of these increase risks of mortality.” Heuristics explain the principle’s intuitive appeal. One is the “act-omission distinction,” whereby regulators prohibit endeavors with visible risks (such as the Keystone XL pipeline) even though prohibition entails less visible risks (war over oil in the Middle East). To be clear, Sunstein does not recognize moral heuristics in order to reduce the number of pages in the Federal Register. His goal is to refine cost-benefit analysis. Whether his acolytes show as much restraint when applying behavioral economics to formulate regulations remains an open question. Conclusion / Valuing Life contains no battle stories involving regulators, politicians, and lobbyists arguing over any regulation. There are a few glaring errors that may be excused. Pertaining to “a regulation designed to reduce the incidence of prison rape,” Sunstein writes, “If a single rape is valued at $500,000, the rule would be easily justified if it prevented only 1,600 rapes.” It is safe to assume that he intended to write “if preventing a single rape is valued at $500,000.” Likewise when he wrote “a dollar today is worth less than a dollar tomorrow,” he intended to write “a dollar today is worth more than a dollar tomorrow.” Readers might be surprised to learn that OIRA listens to “businesses and others” who resist regulations on more occasions than it listens to “public interest groups” who favor them. Sunstein claims that OIRA avoids politics. “At least in my experience (and some people will find this surprising),” he admits, “‘politics,’ in the sense of interest-group pressures and electoral considerations, usually does not play a significant role in the regulatory process.” Although he teaches that there may be too much regulation as well as too little, he maintains that “the financial crisis of 2008 and succeeding years was, in part, a product of insufficient regulation, which could have provided safeguards against systemic risks.” Even the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission Report, which faults free-market ideology for the crisis, also blames regulatory forbearance. Sunstein emphasizes his appreciation of Hayek. “The Hayekian theme,” he explains, Spring 2015 “emphasizes the dispersed nature of human knowledge and OIRA’s role in attempting to acquire as much of that knowledge as possible, above all through careful attention to public comments.” In his conclusion he acknowledges that “it is an understatement to say that [Hayek] would not have endorsed all of the arguments in this book (much less all of the regulations that the United States has issued in the name of public health, safety, and environmental protection).” Given the knowledge problem, Sunstein believes that OIRA’s role as “an information aggregator” is an appropriate way to deal with it. One wonders whether Hayek would endorse that approach or judge it quixotic. / Regulation / 59 director’s cheat sheet, and that makes reading his portion of the book a chore for anyone who dislikes hackery. Fortunately, he does ultimately circle back to discussing the idea that data-driven government will make “people’s lives better.” Of course, Madden and Wolfson are right in theory that both parties have incentive to learn more about government programs and regulation in order to drive better policy. The hurdle for applying Moneyball to government—as opposed to just one or two instances that happen to follow party dogma—is that statistical analysis will sometimes indicate that a strongly favored program is failing. Per✒ Review by Sam Batkins haps politicians of both parties can accept “Moneyballing” USAID, but what about Social Security or defense appropriations? eginning in the 1990s, Oakland Athletics general manager Billy Rest assured, Madden, Wolfson, and Beane gained acclaim for using statistical analysis to identify other book contributors are willing to critiundervalued players and baseball strategies, which he then used cize some government programs. But too to turn the small-budget team into a consistent winner. Since then, all often their policy recommendations are sorts of analysts have proposed applying similar “Moneyball” strate- for more government, such as establishgies to other human endeavors, including Howard Wolfson (a Democrat). They argue ing whole new offices for policy evaluagovernment. that both sides of the aisle have incentive tion. There is a call for a “chief evaluation Who could oppose collecting data to play Moneyball with government. officer” in every federal agency, agencies about government spending, building eviRepublicans presumably would benefit setting aside up to 1 percent of each agendence to implement effective programs, by pushing for more efficient government cy’s budget for evaluation, and the estaband directing funds away from failing poli- rather than being labeled “antigovern- lishment of “cross-government prizes for cies? In the new book Moneyball for Govern- ment,” though that distinction may be innovative approaches to evaluation.” Supment, a plethora of writers, policy wonks, lost on some Republican politicians. For posedly, those actions would lead to agency and two former heads of the federal Office Democrats, Wolfson proudly innovation where before the of Management and Budget make the case trumpets their strong record agencies were content with that a data-driven approach to government of fiscal responsibility. He mediocrity. Whether the benand regulation would create better results points out that President efits of the new measuring at a lower cost to taxpayers. Obama has recently been devices are worth the costs is Data and analytics about how govern- reducing the deficit at the up for debate. ment operates could certainly be improved. fastest rate since World War From an agency perspecBut whatever the apparatus that policy- II—though he doesn’t say that tive, the biggest obstacle to makers establish to measure government, this reduction is from the evaluation may be fear. In self-interested politicians must still pay trillion-dollar deficits Obama previous Moneyball initiaattention to the findings and be willing to rang up early in his presidency. tives (and there have been cut failing programs. Bill Niskanen noted If this represents the authors’ previous attempts), agencies that in these pages many years ago (“More idea of an honest use of data proved reluctant to change, in Lonely Numbers,” Fall 2003), and I share then maybe we should forget Moneyball for part because they feared that Government his skepticism about that possibility. the Moneyball endeavor altosuccess would result in budBut that skepticism may be uncalled gether. Wolfson also spouts Edited by Jim Nussle get cuts from appropriators. and Peter Orszag for, claim book contributors and political off standard attack lines on The book devotes sig260 pp.; Disruption advisers Kevin Madden (a Republican) and Republicans that sound like Books, 2014 nificant attention to the disthey were taken straight from tinction between data and Sa m Batk ins is director of regulatory studies at the American Action Forum. a Senate communications evidence. There is plenty of ‘Moneyball for Government’ Needs ‘Moneyball’ Politicians B 60 / Regulation / Spring 2015 in review data on government programs, but as the authors argue, little evidence that demonstrates what is working and what is failing. Initial evidence, through a randomized controlled trial, may reveal that a specific regulation or program is not generating the promised benefits. But even some of the book’s contributors don’t seem willing to heed such findings, as former agency heads caution that the initial results of such analysis should not portend the end of a program. That’s the problem with policymakers. Scores of analysts can point to failing or wasteful programs, but there will always be a constituency or special interest prepared to defend each program, and they have more at stake in that spending battle than good-government advocates. More data on evaluation will only create a more efficient government if politicians care enough about the data, and there is plenty of evidence today that they do not. There are several references to the Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA) as a paragon for good data and program evaluation. Any critical followers of OIRA will question that praise. OIRA reviews less than 10 percent of all federal rules each year and while that review might be extensive, political considerations from OIRA’s White House overseers are common. What’s more, wide swaths of the economy are exempt from its oversight: Dodd-Frank, for instance, is virtually exempt from OIRA review. More faint praise for OIRA is inspired by its “government-wide” retrospective regulatory review that was done in 2011, and is supposedly continuing today. First, the review wasn’t government-wide, as it wasn’t mandatory for independent agencies. And while the book’s authors may claim that “the lookback process yielded scores of measures to update regulatory regimes,” the reality is decidedly different. As Ike Brannon and I have argued in these pages (“First-Year Grades on Obama Regulatory Reform,” Spring 2012), many of those updates were in fact just new regulations implementing new programs rather than an honest review of past regimes. Retrospective review has been successful at increasing the nation’s regulatory tab, all under the guise of “reform.” There are dangers in embracing socalled Moneyball for government. New hires designated for program evaluation could face resistance from agencies, just as the Government Accountability Office does currently. One percent budget set-asides for evaluation could evolve into 1-percent add-ons, with few politicians willing to act on the recommendations. And it’s hard to see how regulatory capture wouldn’t rear its ugly head sooner rather than later in such an arrangement. That’s not to say there aren’t good ideas in this book. For one, interagency data sharing that allows the public to view which programs are failing and which are the most efficient will undoubtedly place additional pressure on legislators. But to expect such efforts to result in a government that functions as well as the private sector is optimistic. The federal government is unlikely to function as efficiently as Beane’s A’s, but performance akin to last season’s New York Yankees is within reach. Working Papers ✒ By Peter Van Doren A summary of recent papers that may be of interest to Regulation’s readers. SEC Regulation “Corporate Governance and the Creation of the SEC,” by Arevik Avedian, Henrik Cronqvist, and Marc Weidenmier. September 2014. SSRN #2498007. “The Costs and Benefits of Mandatory Securities Regulation: Evidence from Market Reactions to the JOBS Act of 2012,” by Dhammika Dharmapala and Vikramaditya S. Khanna. July 2014. SSRN #2293167. D oes regulation of stocks and bonds by the Securities and Exchange Commission, with its regime of registration and mandated information provision, create net benefits for investors? In these pages, Michael Greenstone, Paul Oyer, and Annette Vissing-Jørgensen argued in the affirmative (“The Value of Knowing,” Summer 2006). They analyzed the effects of Peter Va n Dor en is editor of Regulation and a senior fellow at the Cato Institute. the Securities Acts Amendments of 1964, which extended the registration and disclosure regime to stocks traded “over the counter,” and found positive abnormal returns of $3–$6 billion. On the other hand, in these same pages Elizabeth de Fontenay compared corporate bonds subject to disclosure requirements with syndicated loans, which are not subject to such requirements (“Putting Securities Laws to the Test,” Fall 2014). She found the syndicated loan market to be thriving and growing, suggesting that investors found little value from the registration information requirements. Now, two new working papers take up this question. The first, by Arevik Avedian, Henrik Cronqvist, and Marc Weidenmier, analyzes the effect of SEC regulation by comparing stocks listed on the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) with stocks listed on the regional exchanges. The main effect of the 1933 Securities Act was to take NYSE listing standards at that time, convert them into federal law, and apply them to publicly traded firms on regional exchanges. The authors conduct a difference-in-differences analysis of NYSE and non-NYSE firms before and after the act’s cre- Spring 2015 ation of the SEC. Their measure is whether a majority of board members are “independent,” meaning they are neither officers nor family members of officers. The authors find a 30 percent reduction in board independence of the regional firms post-SEC, but no change in firm valuation by investors. Firms traded off private and public provision of reassurance. As government supply increased, the private supply of reassurance through board independence was reduced. The second paper, by Dhammika Dharmapala and Vikramaditya Khanna, examines the effects of the JOBS (Jumpstart Our Business Startups) Act of 2012. The law relaxed disclosure and compliance rules for “emerging growth companies” (primarily those firms with less than $1 billion in revenue)—whose initial public offering (IPO) of stock was after December 8, 2011. The authors conducted an event study comparing small firms with IPOs between July 2011 and December 8, 2011 to small firms with IPOs between December 9, 2011 and April 5, 2012, when President Obama signed the bill into law. Some 87 firms conducted IPOs between July 2011 and April 5, 2012. The control group contains 33 firms with less than $1 billion in revenue whose IPO was prior to December 8, 2011. The authors calculate whether differences in returns between treatment and control firms (so-called cumulative abnormal returns) exist in the event window (February 29 to April 9, 2012) surrounding a prominent March 15 statement by Senate Majority Leader Harry Reid’s (D–Nev.) about the importance of the bill. The event window starts with House Financial Services Committee’s approval of the bill, which included an explicit relaxation of the rules for all IPOs after Dec. 8, 2011, and ends four days after the presidential signing on April 5, 2012. The central result is positive abnormal returns of 3–4 percent for treatment relative to control firms during the event window. Investors reacted as if elimination of the SEC reporting requirements for small firms created net benefits that were reflected in positive abnormal returns. Cash Transfers and Educational Attainment “Human Capital Effects of Anti-Poverty Programs: Evidence from a Randomized Housing Voucher Lottery,” by Brian Jacob, Max Kapustin, and Jens Ludwig. May 2014. NBER #20164. W hy do poor parents have children who also grow up to be poor? One possible explanation is that poor families do not have access to credit that would allow parents to invest more in the human capital improvement of their children. The policy solution that results from this notion is to increase transfers to poor families in order to remove their credit constraints. The expansion of the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC)—which uses the tax system to transfer money to low-income households— / Regulation / 61 has been shown to increase standardized test scores. But critics argue that factors unobservable to researchers but correlated with EITC receipt are responsible for children’s success, not the EITC transfers. In this study, Brian Jacob, Max Kapustin, and Jens Ludwig use the 1997 housing voucher lottery in Chicago (the first opening of voucher lists in the city in 12 years). They examine the outcomes 14 years later for children whose families won housing vouchers versus children of families that did not. Families that won the lottery received a very large positive income shock—the equivalent of $12,000 a year—relative to the average income in the sample ($19,000 a year). The authors find very few effects on schooling, crime, or health outcomes and none are significant. “Our estimates imply that extra cash transfers beyond the current level provided in the United States are likely to have a smaller impact per dollar than the best-practice educational interventions explicitly designed to improve children’s human capital,” they write. Their results are consistent with the findings of sociologist Susan Mayer, who concluded in What Money Can’t Buy (Harvard University Press, 1997) that there is “little reason to expect that policies to increase the income of poor families alone will substantially improve their children’s life chances.” Air Pollution Regulation “Toward a More Rational Environmental Policy,” by Richard L. Revesz. December 2014. SSRN #2534018. R ichard Revesz, professor of law at New York University, describes five principles that should govern environmental policy: Environmental restrictions on emissions should be governed by cost-benefit analysis and maximize net benefits. ■■ Environmental objectives should be achieved at minimum cost. ■■ Environmental policies should be implemented with market instruments such as emission prices or tradable emission permits. ■■ Grandfathering of emission sources introduces fatal arbitrage problems into environmental regulation and should be severely constrained. (See “New Source Review: What’s Old Is New,” Spring 2006.) ■■ The most compelling case for federal regulation is the control of interstate externalities. ■■ From a libertarian perspective, the fifth principle is the most important. And yet one ironic response of states to the passage of the Clean Air Act amendments in 1970 and 1977 and their requirement that states enact plans to reduce stationary source emissions was to mandate taller smokestacks—a cheap solution that solved 62 / Regulation / Spring 2015 in review the intrastate problem by creating an interstate problem. Rather than just reverse course and require the shortening of smokestacks to revert an interstate problem back into a local matter that the states would have to address, the federal courts, Congress, and the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency have been wrestling with the upwind–downwind problem ever since. The record of the courts and the EPA in tackling interstate pollution (at least partially created by the Clean Air Act itself) has not been very good. In 1984 the Sixth Circuit Court of Appeals ruled that an upwind Indiana power plant with no emission controls emitting six pounds of sulfur dioxide per million British Thermal Units (BTUs) of coal combustion had not violated the law even though it contributed almost half of the ambient pollution in downwind Jefferson County, Ky., and the power plant in Jefferson County emitted only 1.2 pounds of sulfur dioxide per million BTUs of coal combustion after investing $138 million in pollution control. The EPA did not attempt to deal with interstate air pollution until 1998, during Bill Clinton’s second term. That effort was halted by the George W. Bush administration, which instead asked Congress to amend the Clean Air Act and explicitly expand the cap-and-trade market for sulfur dioxide (created by the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments) to include other pollutants such as nitrogen oxides. The congressional reform attempt ended in 2005 when the bill failed to be approved by the Senate Environment and Public Works Committee on a 9–9 tie vote. Revesz tells the story of how the courts finally allowed the EPA to implement a pollution reduction plan that minimized costs (specifically an emission rights trading regime) even though Congress failed to explicitly grant such permission through an amendment of the Clean Air Act. (See “An EPA War on Coal?” Spring 2013.) Shortly after the failure of the Senate committee to approve the Bush initiative in 2005, the EPA issued the Clean Air Interstate Rule (CAIR) to implement the Bush proposals administratively. In 2008 the D.C. Circuit Court of Appeals struck down CAIR because a strict reading of the statute was thought not to allow a trading program that reduced emissions based on the cost of reduction rather than the amount of pollution generated. In 2011 the EPA responded with the Cross State Air Pollution rule, which again allowed the trading of emission reduction quotas, but with constraints so that all upwind states would have to reduce emissions rather than simply buy emission rights sufficient to allow their emissions. In 2012 the D.C. Circuit Court of Appeals struck down the Cross State rule because state emission limits were established on the basis of the cost of reduction rather than how much each state’s emissions contributed to the downwind ambient result. In 2014 the Supreme Court reversed the D.C. Circuit and concluded reductions could be allocated in a way that minimized aggregate costs. For Revesz the story is positive because the courts finally allowed policy to be more rational. But that conclusion is possible only if one thinks that the courts rescuing the legislature from its enactment of “bad” statutes is a good thing and that interstate conventional pollution, itself, was not the unintended result of national attempts to make localities have “better” environments. Bank Credit Supply and the Great Recession “Do Credit Market Shocks Affect the Real Economy? Quasi-Experimental Evidence from the Great Recession and ‘Normal’ Economic Times,” by Michael Greenstone, Alexandre Mas, and Hoai-Luu Nguyen. November 2014. NBER #20704. B en Bernanke’s work on the causes of the Great Depression concluded that bank failures were an important contributor to the Depression’s length and depth. According to his research, lending was highly localized and the supply of credit to businesses was reduced by local bank failure. Small firms, which are more reliant on bank lending, suffered disproportionate employment losses during the 2007–2009 “Great Recession.” Mindful of his findings on the Depression, Bernanke and Alan Krueger have both suggested that impaired bank credit markets were a major cause of overall employment losses in the recent recession. Hence, the Bernanke-led Federal Reserve implemented various direct lending programs to financial institutions to “fix” impaired credit markets for firms. Despite the emergence of a national banking market in recent decades, small businesses still rely heavily on local lenders. The median distance between firms and lenders is only about three miles and only 14.5 percent of firms borrow from a lender located more than 30 miles from the firms’ headquarters. During the last recession, banks reduced their lending to small businesses in widely varying degrees. For example, Citibank reduced small business lending by 84 percent while US Bankcorp reduced its lending by only 3 percent. Michael Greenstone, Alexandre Mas, and Hoai-Luu Nguyen exploit small firms’ reliance on local lenders and the differential lending cutbacks among regional banks to create a quasi-experimental research design. They ask whether counties with more Citibank branches before the crisis experienced a greater reduction in lending and greater economic decline during the recession than counties with more US Bankcorp branches. The answer is yes but the magnitude is small. If you unrealistically consider all the lending decline to be supply-driven rather than attributing some of it to a recessioncaused reduction in demand, then reduced lending would account for just 0.5 percentage points of the 10 percent decline in small business employment in the recession—about 5 percent of the decline. If you use the upper bounds rather than the average of the 95 percent confidence intervals of the estimated effects, you can explain 13 percent of the decline—a real but small effect. And this is for small businesses; larger businesses with access to non-local credit supply would be even less affected, if at all. Cato at your Fingertips he Cato Institute’s acclaimed research on current and emerging public policy issues–and the innovative insights of its Cato@Liberty blog–now have a new home: Cato’s newly designed, mobile-friendly website. With over 2.2 million downloads annually of its respected Policy Analysis reports, White Papers, journals, and more–and it’s all free–the quality of Cato’s work is now only matched by its immediate accessibility. Visit today at Cato.org and at Cato.org/blog.