Policy, Personality, and Presidential Performance John H. Kessel
by user
Comments
Transcript
Policy, Personality, and Presidential Performance John H. Kessel
Policy, Personality, and Presidential Performance* A Paper presented at a Panel in Honor of John H. Kessel by John H. Aldrich Paul Gronke and Jeff Grynaviski Department of Political Science Duke University * Prepared for delivery at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Palmer House Hotel, Chicago, Ill., April 15-18, 1999. Copies of this paper can also be found at the websites for the Duke University Democracy, Institutions, and Political Economy Program, http://www.poli.duke.edu/dipe, the Political Methodology section, http://polmeth.calpoly.edu, and at Gronke’s web page, http://www.duke.edu/~gronke. The authors would like to thank the Duke University Democracy, Institutions, and Political Economy Program and the Duke University Arts and Sciences Council for financial support. We are also indebted to John Brehm and Neil Carlson for their able assistance in the use and abuse of CALIS. Abstract Policy, Personality, and Presidential Performance John H. Aldrich, Paul Gronke, and Jeff Grynaviski The importance of personality and performance assessments for candidate evaluations and choice has been well established, most prominently in the work on presidential prototypes by Kinder and colleagues, and the social cognitive model of vote choice by Rahn and colleagues. This paper takes a revisionist look at the effect of personality assessments for understanding presidential elections. Most of the experimental and survey data were collected in a relatively brief period, particularly between 1980 and 1984. Among the unique aspects of the 1980s was the impact of the distinctive personality of Ronald Reagan, sometimes called the “teflon president,” because of the degree to which the public admired him as an individual, regardless of political events. His persona therefore might reasonably be assumed to have uniquely influenced the times and thus the models and results. We examine this question primarily by replicating the Rahn, et al. models using the NES surveys from 1984 through 1996, allowing us to evaluate the structure and performance of presidential prototypes and their role in candidate assessments over a longer period of time and greater variety of candidates and presidents. 1 Introduction One of the many significant contributions that John Kessel has made has been the demonstration of the value of replication of behavioral models over time, that is over a variety of electoral circumstances and candidate pairings (e.g., Kessel, 1992). While he is especially noted for his work on the role of issues in politics (Kessel, 1972; 1975; 1984; Bruce, Clark, and Kessel, 1991; Clark, Bruce, Jacoby, and Kessel, 1991), his full electoral models assess the longitudinal contributions of all three major forces – parties, issues, and candidates – on the vote. In this paper, we take a leaf from his book and begin a longitudinal assessment of the literature that studies impression formation about candidates, information processing, and judgment (see Ferejohn and Kuklinski, 1990; Lodge and McGraw, 1995). Kinder and colleagues applied psychological explanations of how individuals form impressions of others to politics, notably to impression formation of presidents and presidential candidates. They also developed measures that began to be used in the National Election Studies (NES) surveys, most fully beginning in 1984. In that year, but using their own survey, Rahn, et al. proposed a “social cognitive model” of voting that had at its core an account of electoral choice based on candidate appraisal (Rahn, Aldrich, Borgida, and Sullivan 1990; Sullivan, Aldrich, Borgida, and Rahn 1990). In this paper, we seek to meld the work of Kinder, et al. and Rahn, et al. by using the NES measures to develop dimensions of candidate assessments. These results are then used to replicate the candidate-centered voting model of Rahn, et al. in 1984 (the first year in 2 which the NES measures allow for a substantial test of the model) and then in 1988, 1992, and 1996. We evaluate the lasting contribution of this work in light of our replication and extension. Personality and Performance in Candidate Assessment In a seminal set of articles, Abelson, Kinder, and Fiske argued that political person perception draws on three separate sources. First, citizens have meta-theories (Kinder and Abelson 1981) or prototypes about what constitutes leadership: (p)rototypes are categories people hold about the nature of the world. An ideal presidential prototype in particular consists of the features that citizens believe define an exemplary president (Kinder, Peters, Abelson, and Fiske 1980). Prototypes are evaluative rulers against which presidential candidates and presidents are measured. Prior to widespread information about a candidate – for example, Gary Hart in the weeks following his second place finish in the 1984 Iowa caucuses and subsequent victory in New Hampshire – the prototype dominates and only later does “reality” intrude (Bartels 1988). Prototypes also function as an “ideal type,” and a leader’s perceived successes or failings may be largely due to perceptions about his ability to fulfill our highest expectations. A full statement of the possible contents of such a prototype can be found in Kinder, Abelson, and Fiske (1979). This set may include traits (personality characteristic ascribed to leaders), affective reactions (patterns of emotional responses elicited by leaders), behavioral expectations (understandings of what actions presidents take), ideal types (what the president should be and do), and spontaneous images (respondent 3 generated lists of expectations).1 Sullivan, Aldrich, Borgida, and Rahn (1990) identify a somewhat different set of dimensions of personality assessment. They argue that candidates are evaluated on three basic dimensions: altruism vs. selfishness, strength of will vs. lack of will power, and trustworthiness vs. untrustworthiness. Miller, Wattenberg, and Malunchuk propose yet a third set of dimensions. Based on an exploratory factor analysis of the open-ended “likes/dislikes” responses, they suggest that the responses fall into five categories: competence, integrity, reliability, charisma, and personal attributes (Miller, Wattenberg, and Malunchuk 1986). While specifics of the categories differ, in general terms these authors identify a very similar set of standards underlying voters’ personal assessments of presidential candidates. This should not be surprising. Experimental research has shown that character and personality assessments are a foundation of interpersonal relations. These assessments are not cognitively demanding to make (in part because routines have been developed and practiced repeatedly), they can therefore be rapidly mobilized, and they often turn out to be accurate, thus reinforcing their use. These sets of scholars draw upon research on interpersonal relations and person perception, extending the categories to perceptions of political actors (Kinder 1978; Miller, Wattenberg, and Malunchuk 1986; Rahn, et al., 1990; Sullivan, et al., 1990). An important difference between Kinder’s and Rahn’s teams’ approaches, however, is that Rahn and colleagues employ an explicitly comparative approach. Thus, 1 The 1979 Pilot Study of the National Election Study included the most elaborate set of candidate characteristics and evaluative scales. The list was substantially cut down for the 1980 study, extended in 1984, and was included in limited 4 candidates are advantaged to the degree by which they exceed the other candidate on one or another dimension of evaluation, whether they are evaluated high or low in absolute terms. This is a quite reasonable expectation, since the conclusion of the evaluation process is a voting choice, a choice made between or among competing options. We adopt the comparative approach in this paper. Second, while employing the language of a “prototype,” Sullivan et al., (1990) reject a single, prototypical standard. Instead, they argue that citizens may employ two rules, judging a candidate against a standard of “superman” or one of “everyman.” “Everyman” is an “intuitive profile of human nature,” a standard by which we judge each other, while “supermen” are individuals who far exceed the performance standards that we expect of most people. The question, then, becomes whether presidential candidates are judged most often as everymen or supermen, and what the consequences may be for political choice. In addtition to political and leadership standards, individuals also evaluate political candidates based on and on actual performance as a politician. According to some, performance serves as a parallel evaluative system, based more on actual performance in office, or policy information that voters receive during a campaign. Kinder and Abelson (1981), for example, believe that some changes in the trait profiles that they observed during the 1980 campaign were a product of the campaign. Rahn, Aldrich, Borgida, and Sullivan (1990) take a different tack, identifying a set of adjective pairs, analogous to the “personality” items, which individuals use to ascribe professional capabilities. What they term competence is a set of “personal characteristics that have a form from 1988-1996. 5 clear professional component, ” standing in contrast to the more “purely personal and character oriented” standard of evaluation, personal qualities. Their survey, conducted by the Gallup organization in 1984, asked voters to rate the candidates on both the “personal” and the “competence” dimensions.2 The case of Gary Hart in 1984, already mentioned, once again is a useful illustration of the relative importance of personality versus performance. Hart was initially able to benefit from widespread projection based on prototypical expectations: “viable Democratic presidential contender.” Not much more was known about the candidate at that point, even though well over 80% of the respondents in weekly polls were willing to hazard a feeling thermometer evaluation and a series of issue placements (Bartels, 1988; Kinder and Gronke 1985). As the campaign wore on, facts about Hart’s political positions and personality (heavily colored by the Mondale campaign) served to diminish his support in the electorate. Depending on your perspective, he was either punished for his continued ambiguity (Alvarez 1997) or he could no longer benefit from voter projection due to uncertainty (Page 1978). However one decides to label the dimensions, their relative impact depends in part on the contents of the prototype and in part on history. Disentangling these two is a difficult task. As Kinder, Abelson, and Fiske (1979) conclude: “…properties of specific candidates may shade the meaning and perhaps shift the importance of competence and integrity.” Changing standards of evaluation over time, during the 1980 campaign 2 The survey also included items asking how “most people” fared on these dimensions. These measures provided them the ability to assess candidates against both the “everyman” and the “superman” standards, an approach we are unable to 6 (Kinder and Abelson 1981), and varying standards across candidates, as measured in 1979 (Kinder, Abelson, and Fiske 1979) illustrate the interaction of general standards, particular candidate arrays, and the campaign environment. Hart, Reagan, Clinton, and Presidential Candidate Assessments The number of articles spawned by this research agenda speaks, at least in part, to its power in allowing us to understand and predict presidential outcomes. The convergence in results employing different data sets and different methods is good evidence in favor of the social-cognitive approach.3 So, the reader might ask, why are we asking questions today? For three reasons: Bill Clinton, Gary Hart, and Ronald Reagan. Reagan as President apparently was able to base much of his sustained support on high approval of him as an individual. The “teflon President” was able to weather a good deal of political difficulties in this way. Clinton appears to be nearly the opposite. His sustained support appears to derive more directly from assessments rooted in political judgments, such as satisfaction with economic conditions. Continued high approval ratings came directly in the face of widespread disenchantment with his personal qualities (Moore 1999; Schneider 1998; Berke 1998). Perhaps, then, the public’s assessment of duplicate using the National Election Study’s data. 3 These different data and methods include an exploratory factor analysis of open ended candidate likes and dislikes items, using three decades of NES surveys;, another using new trait and affect measures, added to the 1979 pilot and 1980 regular National Election Study; and a third using specially written items included in a Gallup poll in a multi-equation statistical estimation model. 7 the president may be different than yet understood. There are at least two distinct possibilities. First, the public, in the face of real or perceived “hounding” of presidential candidates and public figures, may have learned to discount the personal failings of their political leaders, especially where “private” life is concerned. That is to say that one possibility is that the way in which the public assesses political figures may have changed since the 1980s when the Kinder and Rahn teams were writing. Second, the relative importance of personality and performance may be contingent on a particular candidate array. We have good prior expectations, based on a reading of the literature and our own results, that the latter process can occur. The lasting contribution of Gary Hart – as the “monkey business” Hart of 1988, not the “where’s the beef” Hart of 1984 – may have been to reduce the importance of personal sexual conduct in the way that American’s evaluate their political leaders. At least some of the authors cited above include “morality” as one aspect of character assessments. However, candidates’ sex lives were not a central part of the social cognitive approach. And while the public may discount personal sexual behavior (“morality”), this was not, in the eyes of many, this was not Clinton’s cardinal sin. He did lie to the American people in his speech in January, 1998, and that provided ample fodder for his political opponents. “Honesty” and “trustworthiness” are not only standards his critics claim he failed to meet, but they are also a critical portion of each set of scholars’ descriptions of the dimensions of candidate assessments. If the political aspects of the “personal” have undergone a fundamental shift, this argues for a reexamination of at least that aspect of the social cognitive model. If this has disappeared or undergone significant modification in the post-Hart era, this should be evident in 8 measurement models applied in 1992 and 1996, and not just for candidate Clinton, but for Bush, Perot, and Dole as well. Finally, we return to the political figure who shaped politics during the 1980s. One Reagan biographer calls him “an American icon” (Metzger 1989) while another scholar argues that Reagan revived the “nostalgic myth” of America as a “shining city on the hill.” (Combs 1993). Weiler and Barnett (1992) argue that Reagan fundamentally changed public and political discourse in America. We do not want to engage in Reagan hagiography. Yet, it is difficult to avoid the suspicion that Reagan was the prototypical presidential prototype. Virtually all of the Kinder, Rahn, and their colleagues’ research was conducted examining only one survey, election year, and pair of candidates, and that one survey often was conducted at the highpoint of Reagan’s popularity. A Strategy for Replication and Extension Where do all these question lead us? We do not question the power of candidate assessments in general nor of the social cognitive model, in particular. Indeed, a substantial part of the appeal of that model is the centrality it gives to candidate assessment in this candidate-centered era. Instead want to examine its stability in new contexts. Their own research provides guidance as to where we should focus our analytical lens. Our first task, then, is to see if we can produce reasonably similar candidate evaluation scales in 1984 and subsequent years. 9 Second, incumbents and challengers appear to be evaluated in quite different ways. Mondale was held to more of a “superman” standard, a finding attributed to lower confidence that voters have in the content of their evaluations (Sullivan et al., 1990). This is similar to the claim that ambiguity by candidates may end up penalizing them in the eyes of voters (e.g. Alvarez 1997). Similarly, conceptions of the “ideal president” were only related to evaluations of the sitting president, not other contenders. Conceptions of the “ideal president,” it may turn out, may be substantially influenced by the actual occupant of the office (Kinder et al., 1979). Thus, our next hypothesis, one that can be tested across years, is that voters, even in the face of what Alvarez deems a “tremendous amount of information about candidates” in presidential general elections, will be far more certain in their evaluations of incumbents than of challengers. Third, both sets of scholars highlight the role of political sophistication in the process of candidate evaluation, yet come to somewhat different conclusions. Kinder and colleagues suggest that well-educated voters consider competence (i.e., assessments of political attributes) more in their prototypical expectations, while the less well educated are more likely to rely on likeability and morality (that is, judgements of the candidates as persons). The well educated are looking for an “exemplary manager” while the less well educated are looking for an “exemplary friend” (Kinder et al, 1979 [italics in original]; see also Kinder and Abelson 1981). Rahn and colleagues, in contrast, stress the stability of their regression coefficients across sophisticated and unsophisticated voters. All voters rely on both the “personal qualities” and “competence” ratings of presidential candidates, 10 regardless of their level of political interest. Our third hypothesis tests whether structural relationships are stable across subgroups (defined by political sophistication). Finally, and most centrally, we wish to examine the hypothesis implicit in Rahn, et al. (as in the work of Kinder and colleagues), that the structure of candidate assessments and its role is reasonably general and, hence, reasonably similar from election to election. Rahn and colleagues present a carefully laid out causal model of voting. Most proximate to vote choice in their model is party affiliation and “candidate affect” -- the candidate differential on the NES feeling thermometer scales. While the particular language may differ, their intellectual forebears include Kelley and Mirer (1974) and Markus and Converse (1979). In the Kelley and Mirer “simple act of voting,” a voter chooses by relying on the candidate differential (measured by the difference in “likes” and “dislikes”). If this is not determinative, party identification serves as a tiebreaker. Markus and Converse (1979) present a considerably more complicated model of choice, but the causal order is identical: working backwards from the vote, the first two “causal arrows” are from candidate evaluations. The penultimate step in the Rahn, et al., model is that candidate affect is determined by the cognitive assessments of candidate competence and personal qualities (the “schema triggered affect” hypothesis). These two, in turn, are shaped by other political forces – domestic and foreign policy, ideology, and partisan identification. The final analysis replicates and extends their causal model. 11 Candidate Evaluation: Personality, Performance, Plus …? Our initial task is replication. A first basic judgement in the Rahn, et al., model is that which the individual makes about the candidate’s qualities as a person. Respondents are given a set of adjective pairs – in the Rahn, et al., data, trustworthy-untrustworthy, selfish-unselfish, and cool and aloof-warm and friendly – and judge the candidates using these pairs. These pairs reflect the “personal qualities” of the candidates, or as we refer to it “personality.” We call the second standard “performance.” This time, respondents are asked to evaluate the candidate on three adjective pairs: ineffective-effective, incompetent-competent, and strong-weak. These are components of personality assessment that have a “clear professional component.” Because the measurement of candidate affect, the third dimension of candidate assessment, through use of feeling thermometers is widely accepted, we do not focus on it in this section. Given the typology, our replication proceeds in two steps. First, we see whether we can produce performance and personality as latent variables using a different data set, the 1984 National Election Study survey. In contrast to the data set used by Rahn et al., which was specially designed by the investigators, we are limited to the measures that the NES chose to include. Fortunately, the close intellectual relationship between their work and that of Kinder and colleagues meant that an at least related set of items were included in the 1984 study, and in each NES election study since then. 12 In order to build our set of measures, we collectively determined what we thought to be the best fit between the NES measures and categories employed by Rahn et al. The wording of these items, with some slight variation across phrases, is as follows: In your opinion does the phrase “Hard-Working” describe Reagan? 1) Extremely well; 2) Quite well; 3) Not too well; 4) Not well at all? Other phrases posed to respondents included “intelligent,” “hard working,” “provides strong leadership,” and “really cares about people like you.” In 1984, sixteen items were asked about each candidate (see Appendix). In 1988 and subsequently, only nine were asked about each candidate, with one different item in 1988 compared to 1992 and 1996. What we believed to be performance-related items included such phrases as “provides strong leadership,” “intelligent,” and “knowledgeable.” Personality items included measures such as “compassionate,” “moral,” and “honest.” Items that we initially chose to be unconstrained and therefore could load on both latent dimensions were “inspiring” and “sets a good example.” All estimations proceeded using confirmatory factor analysis.4 Our attempts to be replicate a model consistent with the two Rahn, et al., categories failed miserably. We began with 1984, under the assumption that if we could reproduce their results in 1984, then we could proceed to replicate in other years. The consequent estimated model, however, failed to provide an adequate factor structure 4 Estimation was performed in the CALIS procedure of SAS. 13 (results not reported here but available on request). Whether it was a poor fit between the measures available in the NES compared to their measures or some other difference, hypothesis tests based on the reported chi-square were unable to obtain anything close to an acceptable fit of the data and the model. 5 Hayduk (1987) reports that with large sample sizes, the chi-square is biased upwards: “…with large sample sizes even minute differences tend to be detectable as being more than mere sample fluctuations and hence significant.” He therefore suggests using the ratio of chi-square to degrees of freedom and relying on the other diagnostic goodness of fit measures provided in a typical LISREL output. An eyeball statistic for goodness of fit is the ratio of c2 to degrees of freedom; a ratio of two or three to one is a reasonable target; in none of our early models were we able to obtain ratios much under 10. Nonetheless, however ecumenical we wished to be, strict devotion to the Rahn categories was unproductive. We returned to the drawing board and re-categorized the data. Following both our own intuition and diagnostic statistics, we finally settled upon the following four factor solution, presented in Figure One. (INSERT FIGURE ONE ABOUT HERE) We agreed on four latent dimensions of candidate assessment: “character,” “competence,” “empathy,” and “strong leader.” The reader can refer to the specific measures that were allowed to load on each latent dimension, shown in Figure One and 5 A good fit of the model to the data in this context implies an insignificant chi-square. The chi-square statistic measures whether the observed data matrix S varies insignificantly from the “predicted” data or data implied matrix S (the 14 also on the first page of Table One. Character represents what various authors, cited above, describe as personal aspects of the candidate’s personality. Can they be trusted, are they compassionate, are they moral? Strong leader represents the performance aspect of candidate assessments – what aspects of personality evaluation relates more directly to activities in office. Thus, does the candidate project an image of strong leadership, does he merit our respect, are we inspired? Finally, we allowed for two other latent factors to be estimated, one an elaboration on character, but this time representing those standards of evaluation that indicate that the candidate understands or empathizes with the position of the respondent. This we label, not surprisingly, “empathy.” Finally, we added a second facet to performance as well, assuming that some parts of performance speak more to a candidate’s ability to perform a job well, without necessarily projecting a strong or vigorous image. We labeled this final dimension of evaluation “competence.” This set of four characteristics provided the most satisfactory fit of the data to the model. As shown in Table One, almost all (save three) of the factor loadings are in the correct direction, and only the three incorrectly signed coefficients are statistically indiscernible from zero.6 The goodness of fit measure is credible (.9204) and the ratio of the chi-square to degrees of freedom (at or under 4.0 for each year) indicates a reasonably good fit. (INSERT TABLE ONE ABOUT HERE) manifest responses predicted using the latent constructs and factor loadings). 6 In confirmatory factor analysis, one loading has to be set to 1.0. All other loadings are scaled relative to that 1.0. This is why, for example, the unstandardized loading on “religious” for the character dimension is 1.0. 15 We estimated a wide variety of alternative models, and via likelihood ratio tests within nested models, were able to compare the fit of these alternative models. Most relevant to our interests here, the four-factor solution described in Figure One and Table One outperformed a two-factor solution that was as close to the Rahn, et al., results as we could make it (given the constraints of developing nested models). In 1984, for example, the chi-square for the two factor solution was 4168 (d.f. = 442). We tried many variations on a two factor solution, including single-candidate and comparative dimensional assessments, allowing for covariance among the errors (under the assumption that the underlying dimensions may constitute a response set), etc. None of these smaller-dimensional measurement models provided an acceptable goodness of fit nor outperformed the four factor solution. Most importantly, these results also held in the 1988, 1992, and 1996 surveys. However, there are significant complications associated with each year that merit further examination. First, the NES reduced the number of items composing the trait battery after 1984. This means that our measurement models for 1988, 1992, and 1996 are based on a sparser set of manifest variables. We present in Table Two the set of factor loadings for 1996 for comparative purposes. As with 1984, there are no real surprises in this table. Except for the inexplicable negative loading for “decent” on the empathy dimension (implying that the higher value on the unobserved latent measure or “empathy,” the less well “decent” described Clinton or Dole). Even with the reduced set of indicators, we feel fairly confident with the measurement model in additional years. 16 (INSERT TABLE TWO ABOUT HERE) Second, we could not include estimations of Perot in 1992 or 1996. The NES did not include the questions asking about assessments of Perot in 1992. Attempts to estimate the model using what data were available about Perot in 1996 were not satisfactory These results support our suspicion that Perot was evaluated differently from major-party affiliated (and nominated) presidential candidates. If so, we erred in trying to force the same measurement model onto the data. To the extent that Rahn, et al., are correct in their view that evaluations of candidate traits are determined by issues, party identification, and ideology, it seems likely that individuals either did not have sufficient information to evaluate Perot, or they did not have cognitive routines for assessing unaffiliated candidates. It may not be very surprising that we were unable to replicate the Rahn, et.al. measurement model using the NES data. After all, the NES was not designed with these specific needs in mind. Still, even if the differences were not due to different questions, we do not view failure to replicate as theoretical disconfirmation of the social cognitive approach. The details of the modeling differ, but the theory underlying the Rahn et al., measures is quite similar to that underlying the results of Kinder, at al., and Miller, et al – and our own. We view this as positive confirmation of our first hypothesis. We have produced new dimensions that are replicable across four elections, suggesting that, at least within the context of the specific questions employed by the NES, candidate 17 impression formation has commonality over time and candidates. This allows us to move to a comparison of our ability to predict variation in the evaluative scales. Predicting Evaluative Standards Our first step, establishing the structure in the responses to the NES battery and assessing its persistence over time, is complete. We next assess the structure in the scales themselves. The first part of the task here is to answer the question of how well we can predict variation in candidate evaluations, using a fairly limited set of demographic predictors. While not strictly analogous to the variance based approach to uncertainty proposed by Alvarez and Brehm (1995), we do expect to find greater predictive power in our models of incumbent evaluations compared to challenger evaluation. For the time being, we will interpret higher explanatory power in these models as evidence of greater levels of respondent knowledge or certainty about the candidates. In Figure Two, we present the R2s of the regression of the various candidate assessment measures on demographic characteristics (education, income, gender, race, and region). Two points are quite striking in that figure. The first is that in 1984, 1988, and 1996, the fit of the incumbent president (or vice president in 1988) is substantially higher than the ability to explain citizens’ assessments of the challenger. Such a result is perhaps remarkably clear but otherwise not surprising. After all, the social cognitive account (like most theories of voter choice) is centrally concerned about the consequences of low and differential information acquisition and utilization. Note also that the incumbent is typically especially advantaged on the two performance measures, as this account would anticipate. The second conclusion is that 1992 data are quite different. While the overall 18 fit for Clinton, the challenger, differs little from those for other challengers, the fit for Bush is much lower than for other incumbents (including himself as vice president four years earlier). A third conclusion we draw from the detailed results in Table 3 is that the only major change over time in the impact of individual variables is the much stronger impact of race on assessments of Clinton. This difference might account for at least some of the anomaly of 1992 and explain why the explained variance is so high in 1996 (albeit only marginally more so than 1984). (INSERT FIGURE TWO AND TABLE THREE ABOUT HERE) Results from Voting Models The conventional understanding of the forces shaping voter choices has not changed much since The American Voter (Campbell, et al., 1960). Scholars agree that some combination of partisan considerations, issue evaluations, and candidate assessments shape the voting decision. We do not address the various structural models (e.g., Fiorina, 1981; Jackson, 1975; Page and Jones 1979; Markus and Converse 1979) that compete with Rahn, et al., and others for specification of the vote choice. We simply adopt the formulation proposed Rahn, Aldrich, Borgida, and Sullivan (1990) and by Kinder and Abelson (1981). In both cases, argued more forcefully by Rahn and colleagues, affective evaluations of the candidates are most proximal to (and therefore the last formed before) the vote choice (as is also true in Page and Jones, 1979). Their final 19 vote choice combined the affective evaluations and party identification, with the cognitive evaluations of the candidates determining the affective assessments. The interesting question, and original developments Rahn, et al., provided, concerned the cognitive assessments. Numerous models note the importance of, and provide estimates of, the effect of candidate thermometer ratings on the vote (see, for example, Abramson, Aldrich, and Rohde, 1999, for illustration over recent threecandidate elections). Therefore, we focus first on estimations with the cognitive measures (akin to a one-step reduced form estimation). In Table Four, we report probit estimations of the effects of the four factors of social cognitive judgements and partisan identification on the vote. In each case, the overall goodness of fit is quite large (as is ordinarily true in estimating vote choice models). In each case, the impact of partisan identification is significant and large. In each case, some aspect of candidate assessments is also significant and substantial in magnitude. There, however, the similarities end. In particular, the specific dimensions of candidate evaluations that are consequential differ from election to election. One could provide an account that made sense of which factors were relevant when (with the possible exception of 1996), but as reasonable as those may be, they would be post hoc accounts. In other words, it seems plausible and consistent with social cognitive accounts in general (and in the specific cases) that the particular mix of candidates and political conditions would make some dimensions relevant to choice in one election, others in another. The theory, however, is not yet sufficiently developed to provide stronger 20 guidance. Assuming our results here persist across alternative elections and data sets, developing such an account becomes vital. In Tables Five and Six we report the full replication of the Rahn, et al., model using the 1984 and 1996 NES surveys. Reported there are the estimates for the full sample and for the sample partitioned into thirds by level of political engagement.7 We discuss the full-sample estimates first. (The full causal model, with separate estimates for each of the evaluative dimensions as well as the vote, are not presented here in interests of brevity, but are available upon request.) (TABLES FIVE AND SIX ABOUT HERE) This attempt at replication of the Rahn, et al., voting model fared substantially better than our earlier replication effort. Thus, for example, the overall pattern of fit of the equations is reasonably similar to that which they report. Direct comparisons are, of course, impossible, because we have four dimensions of cognitive appraisal to their two (and good evidence that their two category approach fails with the NES measures). In addition, there are differing patterns to the effect of the various variables between the two elections in our data. That is, we can almost certainly reject the hypothesis that the coefficients are the same in 1984 as in 1996. Still, the most important point is that the 7 We constructed a scale of political engagement using interest in politics, frequency of political discussion, newspaper and newsmagazine readership, frequency of TV news viewing, and attentiveness to presidential campaign news for each of these media outlets. These variables were factor analyzed (no rotation, limited to a single factor) in order to determine weights for an additive index. We also produced a measure of political knowledge, based on the respondents education, the interviewer’s perception of respondent’s political knowledge; and the respondents ability to place the Democratic candidate at a more liberal position than the Republican candidate on three seven-point issue scales. We do not report analytical breakdowns based on the knowledge measure here. 21 overall shape of the model estimates is largely similar in the two NES data sets, in particular. This is especially so in the modeling of the four cognitive assessments. All variables are significant in each case, and the relative magnitudes of coefficients are similar across the two years. The same is roughly true for the affect equation, although there is a different mix of which cognitive dimensions are significant in the two years. Much the same can be said about the analysis of political sophistication. Rahn, et al., concluded that the less politically engaged differed little from those more involved. Here, we report estimates for each of the three divisions of political engagement. In general, the differences across the three levels are less striking than is the overall similarity. The overall fit of the equations for those included is increase somewhat with increasing level of engagement, but those differences are reasonably slight particularly in the case of 1996. Indeed, the differences are sufficiently small that the overall similarity is the more striking – and the more consistent with Rahn, et al., conclusion. Perhaps even more supportive is the pattern of coefficient estimates. Those who anticipate a major effect of sophistication would likely expect the effect to be revealed through consistently larger coefficient estimates for the most sophisticated respondents, compared to those less so. While the estimates differ across levels (and elections), to be sure, there is no consistent pattern. We therefore conclude that, at least among those who do respond to the relevant questions, our data are consistent with the Rahn, et al., conclusion. Perhaps surprisingly, the only major exception is the affect equation. Comparing the two NES surveys, the first noticeable exception is that more variables are significant among the least than among the most engaged. Issues, for example, are not significant in either year 22 for those highest on engagement, whereas (and with virtually the same n), issues are significant in both years for the least (and the moderately) engaged. Looking across years, it is also striking that party, ideology, and empathy drive the results for the most engaged in 1996, whereas ideology was not significant in 1986, but the measure of strong leadership was. While not seeking to underplay these differences, the overall pattern is of broad similarity in the two NES and, in so far as one can judge, the Gallup data sets. Conclusions In this paper, we sought to examine the effect of cognitive appraisals of presidential candidates using different measures than in previous studies but applying those measures over the four available elections. The measures included in the 19841996 NES surveys support a four-dimensional measurement of such appraisals. Roughly speaking, two are focus on the individual personalities of the candidates and two are centered more on the performance of the political tasks of the presidency expected or already observed in the candidate. The over-time continuity in this set of factors is a major argument in behalf not just of the dimensions themselves but on the social cognitive theory of candidate appraisal underlying them. Another major conclusion flows from the reasonable replicability of the social cognitive model of vote choice developed by Rahn, et al. These estimates imply that, even though based on four rather than two cognitive dimensions, there is strong support for an information processing 23 based account that puts candidate appraisal in the center of political choice in this candidate-centered electoral era. There are significant tasks remaining in this field of study. First, reasonable arguments and evidence have now been amassed in support of different numbers and types of factors of cognitive appraisal of presidential candidates. Both theoretical and empirical work is sorely needed to adjudicate among the known (and conceivably many other) alternatives. Indeed, we view this as a crucial and theoretically significant next task. In addition, we recommend treating the four-fold solution as a hypothesis rather than a finished product. For example, the NES questions were originally derived from the Kinder, et al., work that was based on a different set of specific factors. Revisiting the number and content of manifest variables in light of the results here seems warranted. First, neither our work nor Rahn, et al. tests the full social cognitive model against alternatives, and neither tests for specific causal claims. That is, we now have sufficient positive evidence for this model that it – and all the others in the same class (e.g., Marcus and Converse, 1979, and Page and Jones, 1979) – should be evaluated against one another. Second, our estimates indicate that the relative impact of the various dimensions of candidate appraisal vary from election to election. Social cognitive theory is not, however, sufficiently rigorously developed in the discipline to propose hypotheses to explain such variation. These recommendations are primarily theoretical – indeed, very difficult theoretical work. We close with one more substantive observation. We have learned a 24 great deal from the effort to replicate studies of candidate appraisal on different data and in different political circumstances. This is just the lesson Kessel teaches us. We also were motivated by the empirical puzzle of how Clinton could maintain support in spite of public perception of personal failings (and Reagan often held high levels of support because of perceived personal strengths). Neither our work nor those who preceded us in the study of candidate and presidential perception seem able to explain this puzzle, at least not in post-hoc hindsight. 25 Appendix: Candidate Characteristics, 1984 – 1996 HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE WORD "(word or phrase)" DESCRIBES (Candidate)? Descriptor HARD-WORKING DECENT COMPASSIONATE COMMANDS RESPECT INTELLIGENT MORAL KIND INSPIRING KNOWLEDGEABLE SETS A GOOD EXAMPLE REALLY CARES ABOUT PEOPLE LIKE YOU PROVIDES STRONG LEADERSHIP UNDERSTANDS PEOPLE LIKE YOU FAIR IN TOUCH WITH ORDINARY PEOPLE RELIGIOUS HONEST GETS THINGS DONE · 1984 X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X 1988 1992 1996 X X X X* X X X X X* X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X Questions were asked only of Clinton, so were excluded from measurement models to increase likelihood of compatible factor scores across candidates. 26 Extract from the National Election Study Codebook (1984): 319 HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE WORD "HARD-WORKING" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN 320 321 322 323 324 325 326 327 328 329 330 331 332 333 334 HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE WORD "DECENT" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE WORD "COMPASSIONATE" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE PHRASE "COMMANDS RESPECT" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE WORD "INTELLIGENT" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE WORD "MORAL" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE WORD "KIND" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE WORD "INSPIRING" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE WORD "KNOWLEDGEABLE" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE PHRASE "SETS A GOOD EXAMPLE" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE PHRASE "REALLY CARES ABOUT PEOPLE LIKE YOU" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE PHRASE "PROVIDES STRONG LEADERSHIP" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE PHRASE "UNDERSTANDS PEOPLE LIKE YOU" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE WORD "FAIR" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE PHRASE "IN TOUCH WITH ORDINARY PEOPLE" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN HOW WELL DOES R FEEL THE WORD "RELIGIOUS" DESCRIBES RONALD REAGAN 27 Figure One: Measurement Model of Candidate Evaluation, 1984 Decent Religious Intelligent Moral Hard Worker x Compassionate Kind Fair “Character” x Set Example “Empathy” Knowledgeable “Strong Leader” x In Touch “Competent” x Understanding Strong Leader Inspiring Commands Respect Cares 28 Table 1: Personality and Performance, Latent Variable Equations, 1984 (Reagan and Mondale) Manifest Variable Religious In Touch Fair Understands people like me Sets a good example Compassionate Knowledgable Decent Hard Worker Intelligent Commands respect Moral Really cares about people Kind Inspiring Provides strong leadership Character Reagan Mondale 1.0000 0.6070 1.0000 0.6274 0.4385 0.2662 0.5593 0.3509 0.4334 0.7188 0.2631 0.4363 0.4894 0.9975 0.3071 0.6259 1.2943 0.4048 0.7856 0.2457 1.2243 0.6579 0.7682 0.4128 1.2379 0.7696 1.2373 0.7764 0.9961 0.6046 1.1283 0.7080 Empathy 1.0000 0.7660 1.1027 0.2327 0.5051 0.8211 0.6289 0.9055 0.1911 0.4147 1.0000 0.6366 1.1170 0.2068 0.2461 0.8005 0.5096 0.8941 0.1655 0.1970 1.1221 0.2741 0.2563 0.9213 0.2250 0.2104 1.1112 0.1118 -0.0081 0.8894 0.0895 -0.0065 Leadership Reagan Religious In Touch Fair Understands people like me Sets a good example Compassionate Knowledgable Decent Hard Worker Intelligent Commands respect Moral Really cares about people Kind Inspiring Provides strong leadership Adjusted Goodness of Fit Mondale Reagan Competence Mondale Reagan Mondale 0.4671 0.3951 0.5106 0.4359 0.0459 0.0386 -0.0208 -0.0176 -0.0096 -0.0081 0.2427 0.2071 1.0168 0.8561 0.7336 0.6212 0.4795 0.4056 -0.0677 -0.0578 0.1868 1.0000 0.1573 0.842 0.3348 1.0000 0.2835 0.8468 0.8147 0.6891 0.8574 0.7319 0.7108 0.6012 0.9715 0.8292 1.0000 0.8459 1.0000 0.8536 0.9204 Chi-square 1593.29 (degrees of freedom) 416 Null Model 34726.96 (d.f.) 496 Notes: Data Source = 1984 NES. Cell entries are confirmatory factor analysis coefficients (from manifest variable equations). Standardized coefficients are italicized. Estimated with Proc CALIS (SAS) Table 2: Personality and Performance, Latent Variable Equations, 1988 (Bush and Clinton) Manifest Variable Compassionate Knowledgable Decent Intelligent Moral Really cares about people Honest Inspiring Provides strong leadership Character Bush Dukakis 0.5654 0.4344 0.4270 0.3162 Empathy Bush Dukakis 0.4052 0.3523 0.4467 0.3958 1.1663 0.8960 1.2156 0.9002 -0.1701 -0.1479 -0.1437 -0.1273 1.0000 0.7683 1.0000 0.7406 1.0000 0.8695 1.0000 0.8861 1.0708 0.8227 1.1034 0.8171 0.2760 0.2399 0.1282 0.1136 Leadership Bush Compassionate Knowledgable Decent Intelligent Moral Really cares about people Honest Inspiring Provides strong leadership Adjusted Goodness of Fit 0.0881 Competence Dukakis 0.0778 0.2893 0.5285 0.7625 0.5986 1.0000 0.883 1.0000 0.9533 Chi-square (degrees of freedom) 0.2456 0.6474 0.8490 432.00 99 Bush Dukakis 0.8660 0.6943 0.6611 0.5091 1.0000 0.8017 1.0000 0.7701 Null Model (d.f.) 15591.06 153 Notes: Data Source = 1988 NES. Cell entries are confirmatory factor analysis coefficients (from manifest variable equations). Standardized coefficients are italicized. Estimated with Proc CALIS (SAS) 30 Figure 2: Relative Explained Variance in Evaluative Dimensions, Incumbent vs. Challenger 0.6 1988: Bush vs. Dukakis 1984: Reagan vs. Mondale 1992: Bush vs. Clinton 1996: Clinton vs. Dole 0.4 Incumbent Challenger 0.3 0.2 0.1 pa th y er ad ng Le te pe om ro St ra C ha Em e nc er ct th C Em pa ad ng Le te ro St pe Dimension of Evaluation, by Year 31 y er e nc er om C C ha ra pa ct th y er ad Le Em e ng ro St om pe ra C ha C te ct nc er y th pa ad Le ng pe te ro St om Em e nc er ct ra C ha er 0 C Variance Explained 0.5 Table 3: Relative Explanatory Power in Evaluative Dimensions: Significant Predictors Party ID Ideology Education Income Female Black South Character .104 *** .078 *** -.002 .001 .093 *** -.238 *** .068 * Reagan Strong Competence Leader .129 *** .170 *** .108 *** .115 *** -.040 *** .003 .005 .004 .131 *** .048 .049 -.153 * .118 * .112 * Empathy .179 *** .113 *** -.003 .003 .081 * -.256 *** .133 ** Mondale Strong Character Competence Leader -.045 *** -.067 *** -.108 *** -.015 -.001 -.029 * .005 -.006 -.033 ** -.001 -.004 -.011 ** .012 .038 .031 .021 .145 * .283 *** -.017 -.013 -.030 Empathy -.091 *** -.027 .003 -.008 * -.022 .100 -.102 * R-square .407 .297 .448 .084 .156 Character Party ID .122 *** Ideology .029 ** Education -.008 Income .004 Female .054 Black -.124 * South .122 *** Strong Competence Leader .110 *** .152 *** .025 ** .036 ** -.017 -.041 ** .006 * .004 .027 .053 -.010 .088 .029 *** .216 *** Empathy .160 *** .036 ** -.029 * .006 .078 * -.105 .150 *** Dukakis Strong Character Competence Leader -.062 *** -.047 *** -.106 *** -.004 -.000 -.001 .035 ** .020 * .008 -.006 * -.003 -.010 -.030 -.024 .038 .024 .028 .121 * .003 .026 .027 Empathy -.102 *** -.008 .027 * -.007 * .002 .077 -.000 R-square .245 .319 .093 .143 1984 1988 .428 Bush .279 .287 .110 .056 .248 .193 Notes: Data are drawn from the 1984, 1988, 1992, and 1996 National Election Studies. As a rough indicator of statistical significance, * = the estimated regression coefficient is more than two times its standard error. ** = more than three times. *** 32 Table 3: Relative Explanatory Power (con't) 1992 Bush Character Party ID .089 *** Ideology .032 * Education -.017 Income .004 Female .019 Black -.252 ** South .066 Strong Competence Leader .076 *** .104 *** .033 * .034 * .000 -.035 * .003 -.003 .010 -.020 -.119 -.191 * .075 .113 * R-square .134 .172 .171 Empathy .127 *** .037 * -.036 * .005 -.002 -.292 ** .049 Clinton Strong Character Competence Leader -.084 *** -.052 *** -.101 *** -.033 ** -.007 -.032 * -.014 .040 ** .001 -.007 * -.002 -.007 .043 .052 .058 .298 *** .227 ** .296 *** .018 .013 .019 Empathy -.091 *** -.033 * -.006 -.005 .047 .328 *** .025 .194 .228 .215 Empathy .151 *** .045 *** .016 .006 -.003 -.121 * .041 Clinton Strong Character Competence Leader -.188 *** .117 *** -.188 *** -.031 ** .018 * -.024 * -.041 *** -.016 -.024 * -.109 *** .000 -.007 * .067 * .027 .055 .242 *** -.141 * .269 *** -.010 .027 -.029 Empathy -.195 *** -.036 *** -.011 -.009 ** .073 * .265 *** -.010 .274 .500 .471 Dole 1996 Party ID Ideology Education Income Female Black South Character .092 *** .025 ** .042 *** .008 ** -.033 -.217 *** .021 Strong Competence Leader .077 *** .094 *** .024 ** .036 *** .031 ** .034 .007 ** .006 * -.035 -.026 -.168 *** -.142 * .038 .080 * R-square .248 .232 .206 .079 .208 .219 .463 Notes: Data are drawn from the 1984, 1988, 1992, and 1996 National Election Studies. Cell entries are a rough indicator of statistical significance. * = the estimated regression coefficient is more than two times its standard error. ** = more than thre 33 Table 4: Voting Models, 1984 - 1996, Including Only Evaluation and Partisanship Character Competence Empathy Strong Leader Party ID Constant N of Observations Chi-square Pseudo-R2 Character Competence Empathy Strong Leader Party ID Constant N of Observations Chi-square Pseudo-R2 Probability of Republican Presidential Vote, 1984 By Political Engagment Low Medium High Full Sample 0.626 -0.432 1.447 0.394 1.145 -0.391 0.223 -0.226 0.986 0.486 -0.104 0.846 -0.211 3.57 0.485 0.860 0.752 1.718 -0.144 3.924 0.469 0.254 0.564 0.698 -0.046 6.671 0.307 0.357 0.311 0.330 -0.158 -2.545 -0.187 -0.256 -0.404 -0.508 198 175.75 0.660 805 731.91 0.669 396 353.95 0.656 198 205.47 0.760 Probability of Republican Presidential Vote, 1988 By Political Engagment Low Medium High Full Sample 0.297 0.550 0.539 0.025 0.003 1.227 -0.168 0.447 -0.377 -0.179 0.339 -1.137 0.437 2.087 0.902 0.106 0.911 2.253 0.325 3.129 0.434 1.019 1.092 1.333 0.035 10.212 0.356 0.488 0.315 0.389 0.137 -3.702 -0.578 -0.506 -0.832 -0.403 286 285.72 0.723 1165 1135.5 0.705 34 574 548.2 0.695 287 297.67 0.748 Table 4: Voting Models, con't Character Competence Empathy Strong Leader Party ID Constant N of Observations Chi-square Pseudo-R2 Character Competence Empathy Strong Leader Party ID Constant N of Observations Chi-square Pseudo-R2 Probability of Republican Presidential Vote, 1992 By Political Engagment Low Medium High Full Sample 0.561 0.498 1.126 1.837 1.016 -2.962 -0.768 0.456 -1.684 0.787 -0.564 -2.734 0.483 2.338 -0.119 3.244 1.128 1.692 0.476 3.889 1.012 1.850 2.540 4.885 0.058 5.927 0.344 0.331 0.680 0.343 0.210 -4.872 -1.024 -1.075 -1.028 -1.482 152 166.27 0.822 616 641.66 0.796 307 326.62 0.806 152 165.37 0.865 Probability of Republican Presidential Vote, 1996 By Political Engagment Low Medium High Full Sample 0.247 0.189 1.308 0.231 0.432 0.172 1.678 1.137 1.477 2.115 0.794 4.268 0.170 4.196 0.200 0.934 0.715 1.167 0.567 0.711 0.797 0.673 0.390 1.397 0.045 8.039 0.363 0.322 0.386 0.717 0.196 -7.306 -1.434 -1.308 -1.516 -2.987 209 170.44 0.602 838 854.75 0.745 418 443.67 0.773 209 256.78 0.894 Notes: Data Source, 1984 - 1996 NES. Cell entries are probit coefficients. For the full sample, the second column contains the standard error, and the third column contains the t-statistic. For all coefficients, rough statistical significance is indica 35 Table 5: Full Comparative Model, Evaluations and Affect, 1984 Political Engagement Medium High Estimates -0.309 -0.413 -0.142 0.113 0.169 0.137 1.054 0.884 1.233 0.290 0.653 0.417 0.347 0.405 0.515 225 453 226 Full Sample Low Character Intercept Party ID Political Issues Index Political Ideology Adj. R-square N Estimate Std. Error 0.030 -0.307 0.008 0.144 0.164 1.028 0.081 0.464 0.430 923 Competence Intercept Party ID Political Issues Index Political Ideology Adj. R-square -10.263 -0.416 15.533 0.176 6.952 1.541 5.235 0.571 0.398 -0.159 0.129 1.522 0.201 0.297 -0.398 0.162 1.396 0.557 0.369 -0.611 0.216 1.788 0.856 0.514 Strong Leader Intercept Party ID Political Issues Index Political Ideology Adj- R-square -0.466 0.269 1.975 0.832 0.460 0.053 0.015 0.289 0.142 -0.415 0.219 1.736 0.669 0.399 -0.424 0.256 1.661 0.685 0.397 -0.524 0.323 2.953 0.996 0.603 Empathy Intercept Party ID Political Issues Index Political Ideology Adj- R-square -0.937 0.255 1.847 0.759 0.470 0.049 0.014 0.266 0.131 -0.747 0.214 2.168 0.510 0.433 -0.972 0.254 1.453 0.678 0.433 -1.002 0.279 2.214 1.064 0.548 Low Full Model Estimate Std. Error 0.017 Intercept -0.840 Party ID 0.005 0.043 Political Issues Index 0.077 0.259 0.037 Political Ideology 0.156 0.037 Character 0.139 Competence 0.001 0.021 0.014 Strong Leader 0.137 Empathy 0.019 0.132 R-square 0.821 Affect Equation -0.099 0.044 0.322 0.159 0.122 0.018 0.178 0.089 0.741 Medium High Estimate -0.111 -0.061 0.035 0.059 0.353 0.221 0.147 0.148 0.062 0.188 -0.018 0.028 0.133 0.103 0.135 0.160 0.821 0.856 Notes: Data source, 1984 National Election Study. Cell entries are unstandardized regression coefficients. Sample size is entered for the first equation only, but is fixed across all estimates. 36 Table 6: Full Comparative Model, Evaluations and Affect, 1996 Full Sample Political Engagement Low Medium High Estimates -0.412 -0.490 -0.437 0.245 0.286 0.353 0.873 1.647 0.800 0.253 0.071 0.484 0.416 0.480 0.550 295 587 294 Character Intercept Party ID Political Issues Index Political Ideology Adj. R-square N Estimate Std. Error 0.043 -0.442 0.014 0.293 0.234 1.151 0.115 0.305 0.487 1179 Competence Intercept Party ID Political Issues Index Political Ideology Adj. R-square -0.558 0.211 0.848 0.223 0.490 0.031 0.010 0.168 0.083 -0.480 0.169 1.247 0.141 0.417 -0.579 0.219 0.583 0.286 0.485 -0.579 0.234 0.750 0.206 0.541 Strong Leader Intercept Party ID Political Issues Index Political Ideology Adj- R-square -0.659 0.288 1.141 0.302 0.478 0.043 0.014 0.234 0.115 -0.570 0.233 1.619 0.213 0.410 -0.684 0.298 0.820 0.387 0.471 -0.683 0.316 0.996 0.277 0.528 Empathy Intercept Party ID Political Issues Index Political Ideology Adj- R-square -0.112 0.336 0.459 0.483 0.513 0.048 0.015 0.264 0.130 -1.019 0.290 2.303 0.197 0.449 -1.081 0.324 1.011 0.672 0.496 -1.222 0.392 1.272 0.402 0.581 Low Full Model Estimate Std. Error Intercept 0.015 -0.180 Party ID 0.004 0.040 Political Issues Index 0.062 0.311 Political Ideology 0.030 0.180 Character 0.029 0.015 Competence 0.078 0.166 Strong Leader 0.036 0.049 Empathy 0.012 0.089 R-square 0.809 Affect Equation -0.133 0.031 0.140 0.253 0.009 0.332 -0.025 0.061 0.739 Medium High Estimate -0.176 -0.226 0.034 0.056 0.187 0.483 0.220 0.111 0.037 0.043 0.172 -0.061 0.034 0.136 0.081 0.129 0.812 0.850 Notes: Data source, 1996 National Election Study. Cell entries are unstandardized regression coefficients. Sample size is entered for the first equation only, but is fixed across all estimates. 37 References Abelson, R.P., D.R. Kinder, M.D. Peters, and S.T. Fiske. 1982. “Affective and Semantic Components in Political Person Perception.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 42,4: 619-630. Abramson, Paul R., John H. Aldrich, and David W. Rohde. 1999. Change and Continuity in the 1996 and 1998 Elections. Washington, DC: CQ Press. Alvarez, R. Michael. 1997. Information and Elections. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Alvarez, R. Michael and John Brehm. 1997. “Are Americans Ambivalent Towards Racial Policies?” American Journal of Political Science 41 (April): 345-374. Bartels, Larry M. 1988. Presidential Primaries and the Dynamics of Public Choice. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. Berke, Richard L. 1998. “In Presidents, Virtues Can Be Flaws (and Vice Versa).” New York Times, September 27, 1998. Bruce, John M., John A. Clark, and John H. Kessel. 1991. “Advocacy Politics in Presidential Parties.” American Political Science Review. 85(Dec.): 1089-1106. Campbell, Angus, Philip E. Converse, Warren E. Miller, and Donald E. Stokes. 1960. The American Voter. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Combs, James E. 1993. The Reagan Range: The Nostalgic Myth in American Politics. Bowling Green: The University of Bowling Green Press. Clark, John A., John M. Bruce, William Jacoby, and John H. Kessel. 1991. “I’d Rather Switch than Fight: Life-Long Democrats and Converts to Republicans among Campaign Activists.” American Journal of Political Science. 35(Aug.): 577-597. Fiorina, Morris P. 1981. Retrospective Voting in American National Elections. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Fiske, Susan T. 1993. “Cognitive Theory and the Presidency.” In Geroge W. Edwards, John H. Kessel, and Bert A, Rockman, eds., Researching the Presidency. Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press: 233-265. Ferejohn, John, and James Kuklinski, eds. 1990. Information and Democratic Processes. Urbana, IL: University of Illinois Press. Hayduk, Leslie A. 1987, Structural Equation Modeling with LISREL: Essentials and Advances. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Jackson, John. 1975. “Issues, Party Choices, and Presidential Votes.” American Journal of Political Science. 19(February): 851-80. 38 Kelley, Stanley, Jr., and Thad W. Mirer. 1974. “The Simple Act of Voting.” American Political Science Review. 68(June): 572-91. Kessel, John H. 1972. “Comment: The Issues in Issue Voting.” American Political Science Review. 66(June): 459-65. Kessel, John H. 1983. “The Structures of the Carter White House.” American Journal of Political Science. 27(Aug.): 431-63. Kessel, John H. 1992. Presidential Campaign Politics, 4th ed. Pacific Groves, CA: Brooks/Cole. Kessel, John H. 1984. Presidential Parties. Homewood, IL: Dorsey Press. Kinder, Donald R. 1983. “Presidential Traits: Pilot Study Reports to the 1984 NES Planning Committee.” Ann Arbor, MI: Center for Political Studies, University of Michigan. --------. 1978. “Political Person Perception: The Asymmetrical Influence of Sentiment and Choice on Perceptions of Presidential Candidates.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 36,8: 859-871. Kinder, Donald R. and Robert P. Abelson. 1981. “Appraising Presidential Candidates: Personality and Affect in the 1980 Campaign.” Paper prepared for the 1981 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, New York, NY. Kinder, Donald R., Robert P. Abelson, and Susan T. Fiske. 1979. “Developmental Research on Candidate Instrumentation: Results and Recommendation. Report Submitted to the NES Board of Overseers.” Ann Arbor, MI: Center for Political Studies, University of Michigan. Kinder, D.R., and Paul Gronke. 1985. “Character and Affect in the 1984 Presidential Election.” Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, IL. Kinder, Donald R., Mark D. Peters, Robert P. Abelson, and Susan T. Fiske. 1980. “Presidential Prototypes.” Political Beahvior. 2:317-37. Lodge, Milton, and Kathleen M. McGraw, eds. 1995. Political Judgment: Structure and Process. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Marcus, Gregory B., and Philip E. Converse. 1979. “A Dynamic Simultaneous Equation Model of Electoral Choice.” American Political Science Review. 73(Dec.): 1055-70. Metzger, Robert P. 1989. Ronald Reagan: An American Icon. Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania Press. Miller, Arthur, Martin Wattenberg, and Oksana Malunchuk. 1986. “Schematic Assessments of Presidential Candidates.” American Political Science Review 80:2 (June) 521-40. Moore, David W. 1999. “Good Times for Clinton the President. But Personal Reputation Hits New Low.” Gallup News Service, The Gallup Organization (http://www.gallup.com/poll/releases/pr990123.asp), January 23, 1999. Page, Benjamin I. 1978. Choices and Echoes in Presidential Elections: Rational Man and 39 Electoral Democracy. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Page, Benjamin I., and Calvin C. Jones. 1979. “Reciprocal Effects of Policy Preferences, Party Loyalties and the Vote.” American Political Science Review. 73(Dec.): 1071-89. Rahn, W.M., J.H. Aldrich, and E. Borgida. 1994. “Individual and Contextual Variations in Political Candidate Appraisal.” American Political Science Review. 88,1 (March): 193-199. Rahn, W.M., J.H. Aldrich, E. Borgida, and J.L. Sullivan. 199x. “A Social Cognitive Model of Candidate Appraisal,” in Ferejohn, J.A. and J.H. Kuklinski (eds), Information and Democratic Processes. Champaign, IL: University of Illinois Press. Schneider, William. 1998. “Not a President to Respect or Fear.” The National Journal “Cloakroom” website (http://www.cloakroom.com/members/buzz/njbuzz.htm), August 21, 1998. Sullivan, J.L., J.H. Aldrich, E. Borgida, and W.M. Rhan. 1990. “Candidate Appraisal and Human Nature: Man and Superman in the 1984 Election.” Political Behavior. 459-484. Weiler, Michael and W.B. Barnett. 1992. Reagan and Public Discourse in America. Tuscaloosa: University of Alabama Press 40