...

American Exceptionalism Revisited

by user

on
Category: Documents
3022

views

Report

Comments

Transcript

American Exceptionalism Revisited
American Exceptionalism Revisited
In Celebration of Historical Statistics of the United States, Millennial Edition.
The Historic Mission Inn, Riverside, CA, May 12-14, 2006.
Long-term Changes in Prices, Wages and the Size of
the Monetary Economy in Pre-industrial China
1000-1770
G. William Liu
SUNY, Albany
Department of East Asian Studies
E-mail: [email protected]
1
Abstract
This paper aims to compare later imperial China’s market economy in two transitional
periods: the Tang-Song transition (starting from the eighth century to the twelfth century,
and the Ming-Qing transition (starting from the sixteenth century to the eighteenth
century). The size of the Song market economy in the twelfth century was probably larger
than that of the Ming economy prior to 1600 and was only exceeded by the Qing
economy in the 1770s; while in terms of real income per capita the Song lead remained
even thereafter. This comparison also indicates that the early Ming period (1368-1450)
was a turning point that caused this Song-Ming divergence: prices dropped to a level as
low as that of the seventh-century China; meanwhile real wages declined dramatically
even when the aggregate population decreased by one-third in the late fourteenth century.
This paper highlights the significant role that silver imported from Japan and the
newly discovered America in the late sixteenth and early seventeenth centuries played in
the Chinese economy. Comparing the share of imported precious metals in the money
supply between early modern Europe and late Ming China, the author argues the Great
Discovery, in fact, rescued the late Ming economy which was then severely constrained
by the money famine mostly due to the failure of the Ming state’s fiscal and monetary
policies.
2
World historians have viewed China in the post-Song time as a transition from a
major leading civilization towards a stagnant agrarian empire, even though it still could
sustain a population as large as 0.3 billion in 1775. In a seminal comparative study of
economic growth in world history, the economic historian Eric Jones makes the startling
argument that Song China exhibited intensive growth (economic growth per capita),
preceding both Tokugawa Japan and seventeenth-century Britain by more than five
centuries.1 While Jones does point to the rise in real income per capita during the Song
period, it seems to me that one of the implicit questions generated by his study is the
following: why did the intensive growth fail to continue in the ensuing dynasties? Were
social upheavals such as the Mongol invasion one crucial factor in this downward turn?
In the following sections I will examine changes from the demand side of the
economy. The study on the demand side has an advantage in quantitative analysis. The
central government in pre-industrial China, especially in Song, was involved in taxing
non-agricultural sectors, financing the state apparatus to pay for a large number of
administrative staff and soldiers, and making governmental purchases for strategic
purposes. Thus, a large quantity of documents on wages, prices and currency were made
with respect to these affairs. My own empirical research has convinced me of the value of
using such methods in the analysis of the pre-industrial economy in the Chinese historical
context.
History of prices precisely shows two different price regimes: the late fourteenth
century was a crucial point between the price regime in Tang-Song era and that of MingQing. The price level in the late fourteenth and fifteenth centuries fell back dramatically
1
Jones, 1988, 77-8.
3
to that of the ninth century and displayed a sluggish feature until the sixteenth century. It
was not until the mid-eighteenth century that the price level eventually came back to the
high price level found in Song China in the mid-thirteenth century. Yet when one looks
into demographic changes, the trend becomes vague because of very scanty information
about the Ming population. The only reliable evidence suggests that the Ming population
arrived at around 60 million in 1393, just shortly after the end of civil wars and disasters.
The next benchmark came out about three and a half centuries later, at which point
China’s population had already increased to 310 million. The Chinese population had
come to be 100-120 million in the twelfth century; thus, the 1393 figure no doubt bears
directly upon the question under discussion—a huge decline in aggregate population in
the fourteenth century, mostly owing to wars and disasters under late Mongol rule. Such a
decline in population would account for the decline in the early Ming economy. But there
is no other reliable evidence from the late fourteenth century on, nor any record
documenting demographic changes at the regional level; most estimates of the Ming
population around 1600 fall into a range as big as 120 to 200 million. This imprecision
makes particularly difficult any speculation on long-term economic trends in relation to
population growth in Ming China.
The methodology I am using here, to be more specific, is to examine the
interrelations among prices, money supply and real income per capita through
quantitative monetary theory, especially through the Fisher equation MV=PT.2 As the
equation shows, changes in monetary items on the left side can be related to changes in
real economy on the right side. This interconnection in a monetary economy allows one
2
Here M stands for money supply, P for average price level, V for velocity of money in circulation, and T for total
volume of transactions.
4
to view long-term changes in China’s pre-industrial economy at the aggregate level. The
key variable I am looking for is real income per capita. For this purpose, T shall be
substituted by Y (output or national income). In Sections 1, 2 and 3, I explore changes in
prices, in population, and in money supply led to changes in the monetary economy in
terms of national income. I also choose four specific years as the benchmarks for
comparison: 1120, 1550, 1600, and 1750. The size of the monetary economy in 1750 is
the largest, totaling 376-400 million strings of bronze coins, and the Song monetary
economy in 1120s is the second largest. Given the fact that the population in 1120 was
only one-third of that in 1750, the money supply per capita in Song China would be the
highest. This result will help to explain why the market economy in Song was unusually
fluid.
In Section 4, I examine changes in real wages during Song and post-Song times.
Wages is the puzzle preoccupying many historians of the performance of the Chinese
economy, because little empirical work has been done in this field, and also because only
a small amount of information is reliable. To diminish these technical difficulties, I chose
to study the real wages of commoners as an alternative. For China prior to the eighteenth
century, one can hardly find any long-term wage data for either non-skilled laborers or
artisans that is similar to the Brown & Hopkins index of building wages in Britain. In my
research I adopt soldiers’ wages as the standard indicator for changes in payments to the
commoners. It is worth noting that, as early as in the writings of political arithmetic,
soldiers were already identified as a social group with lower-income. In Gregory King’s
social table, soldiers’ family income in late seventeenth-century Britain was only second
to the poorest income category of cottagers and paupers, and slightly lower than that of
5
laborers and out-servants.3 In late imperial Chinese history, soldiers received their
payment in different forms, and these payments in real terms varied greatly between Song
and early Ming. Likewise, soldiers and their families in China were always conceived of
as poor, just as their counterparts in early modern Europe.
Changes in real wages as shown in the index of soldiers’ wages during Song and
Ming times (see Appendix A) have in another way confirmed my estimates about real
income per capita. A comparison of soldiers’ real wages shows that Song soldiers were
paid 50 per cent more than their counterparts in the 1770s; based upon deduction from
monetary quantitative analysis, the gap in real income per capita would be 30 per cent.
Many of the estimates should be taken as approximations: they are often highly
speculative and at best no more than reasonable guesses that need to be improved by
future empirical studies. However, this quantitative analysis shows a surprising
consistency with data from different dimensions of the economy. It therefore helps to
integrate the rich but often isolated, and even sometimes conflicting, pieces of Chinese
economic history into a coherent account of economic change over eight centuries.
In addition to quantitative analysis, I also provide in this chapter contextual
narratives and institutional analysis that are both independent of and compatible to the
quantitative approach. The Ming government in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries, for
instance, made attempts to administer society through direct command of people and
resources. I will demonstrate in this chapter the anti-market nature of the Ming state
apparatus in enforcing services and taxes. The radical decline of state capability to
intervene in the market economy stands in sharp contrast to the Song government, which
3
Gregory King, Natural and political observations and conclusions upon the state and condition of England, in Two
Tracts, 31.
6
was capable of supplying sufficient currencies to meet the needs of the economy and of
stimulating the economy through many fiscal means. Besides the damage to the Ming
economy inflicted by wars and disasters in the fourteenth century, such this kind of manmade mistakes of the Ming government to a large extent impeded economic progress in
later times, as shown by the prices, wages and money supply data.
1. Population and Prices: the great divergence between Song and Ming
1.1. Estimates of demographic change, 1120-1775
Demographic change is of chief importance in any understanding of long-term trends
in an economy. For the project under discussion, we will come across six centuries.
However, the inexact nature of demographic data preserved in Chinese historical records
makes it hazardous for scholars to speculate either about the size of the aggregate
population or on the growth rate. In the last two decades scholars have made many
attempts to resolve data problems and sketch out an outline of demographic changes over
centuries.4 They have come to view Chinese demographic changes during the late
imperial period, especially from 1368 onward, as increasing at a slow but forward pace
up to the eighteenth century. However, a few years can serve as benchmark for changes in
population over the four centuries. The 1393 figure is the only reliable record for
population until the next reliable aggregate figure was secured in 1775, when the
population had already reached 310 million. To step further from Ho’s analysis, Dwight
Perkins estimates the aggregate population in China around 1600 was about 120-200
4
Ho Ping-ti’s work Studies in Chinese Population History laid a foundation for later research. Through Ho’ efforts,
historians came to understand that the population census in pre-industrial China was serving as an administrative
apparatus to control taxation and labor services. Under such circumstances, women and children were often ignored in
the official registration. Therefore, those figures recorded in official documents have to be adjusted before they can be
viewed as a survey of the aggregate population.
7
million. Despite many disagreements among scholars as to the size and growth rate over
the four centuries, the general trend in Ming-Qing population as described by Ho and
Perkins has been widely accepted.
Scholars are much more confident of the quality of Song population figures in
contrast to Ming population figures.5 For the aggregate population in the Song dynasty
from 980 to 1109 and from 1149 to 1223 respectively, we have at least one reliable record
for every two or three years. In the first phase, Song China achieved an annual rate of the
population growth at 9.2 ‰.6 It is beyond a doubt that Song population in the 1120s had
already reached 110 million. Therefore, the 60 million recorded in the 1390s was a
consequence of demographic decline owing to wars and disasters in the preceding
centuries. However, the demographic changes described above are far from sufficient as a
basis for making a general survey over Song-Ming times. In spite of the fourteenthcentury gap in terms of both aggregate population and urban residents, there are no
reliable estimates on the late Ming. The uncertainty of Chinese population in the
sixteenth and seventeenth centuries will happen again when we examine the size of
sixteenth-century monetary economy.
1.2. The demographic context of the Song-Ming transition
Researchers in the last ten years have paid attention to the political and social
contexts that had a direct impact upon immigration and family structure in Song-Ming
times. Many discussions point to the unusual scale of government-organized immigration
in the late fourteenth century and strict control of the Ming government over the
5
In the twentieth century, scholars had many doubts about the Song demographic statistics. However, in the recent
decades the study of the Song population administration shed some light on this subject, such as the definition of ding
(Wu Songdi, 2000, 2-4, 24-33).
6
Wu Songdi, 2000, 349.
8
population. Long-lasting rebellions and disasters in the mid-fourteenth century brought
an end to the rule of Mongols in China. The succeeding ruler decided to consolidate the
new empire by strict control over economy and society. The Ming government in its first
century succeeded in forcing people to move from rich, densely settled areas to
devastated areas in northern and southwestern China. The total number of immigrants,
according to Cao Shuji, may have reached eleven million, over one-sixth of the early
Ming population. 7 In addition to forced mass immigration, the Ming government
enforced strict control over the Ming populace in professions and residential places
through household registration. All the households under jurisdiction were identified by a
profession (peasants, artisans, soldiers, and so on.). Those who were registered in
registration could not freely change their professions or move to a new place other than
the registered one. 8 The categories covered all kinds of military and administrative
service ranging from soldiers, mining laborers, and artisans, to sedan carriers, trumpeters
as well as graveyard keepers. The majority of households in the registration were farmers,
who were called upon once for three months every three years to labor at places where
certain state needs, such as building city-walls or conveying grain taxes to the capital, had
to be fulfilled. The ideology of the early Ming government was that people, under the
Ming emperor, would organize themselves both to serve the state and to maintain the
harmony of local society. Neither the market nor the bureaucracy was favored as the
means in state building, because they both would bring out corruption in government and
local communities.9 Thus, the early Ming state had to rely solely upon its direct control of
individuals and resources. The military organization in the early Ming comprised 2.76
7
Cao Shuji, 1997, 472-3.
Wang Yuquan, 1991.
9
For a discussion on the early Ming state, see Chapter IV in my Ph.D thesis.
8
9
million soldiers, and if one takes into account their immediate families, their extended
families in their hometowns, and the reserves, the population under the professional title
of military services would be 6.2 million, about 8.5 per cent of the national population.
Yet the early Ming state spent very little to sustain such a large number of soldiers and
staff. The military troops, for instance, whether stationed in hinterland or frontier, had to
use more than half of their staff to cultivate and farm in order to maintain themselves in a
self-sufficient way. In 1403 the grain output from military farms was reported to be 23
million shi, which was not far below the annual agricultural tax the Ming government
could collect from rural peasant households.10
These policies reduced the bureaucracy and cash payments to a minimum size. Even
officials and generals were paid in grain instead of money. Government procurement
almost disappeared in the early Ming. As for its impact on society, people were requested
to provide services according to status, which the state assigned to them, and their duties
would be transferred to the succeeding generation when the seniors passed away. Soldiers
in the military, for instance, were enrolled from the households identified in the
registration as “military households”. Once a family was chosen to be a military
household, they were obliged to remain as such over generations. People needed to
request permission from the government when migrating, changing professions, or
traveling. The entire empire had been, in fact, organized as a workshop in which the
intra-regional flow of personnel and goods was shifted away from the market to central
government demand. Such a command system had severe impacts upon the economy,
including a decrease in monetary transactions and a very low price-level in Ming China,
both of which we will discuss in the following part of this chapter.
10
Wang Yuquan, 1965, 209.
10
The early Ming policies lasted one and a half centuries. Beginning in the late fifteenth
century, one sees the recovery of the market economy and the prosperity of local society
in many parts of Ming China, especially in the Lower Yangtze Delta. Many scholars
describe the Ming economy then as so vibrant that it was entering an economic and
cultural boom lasting into the eighteenth century. However, the collapse of the early Ming
system also terminated any effective state intervention into the private economy, so that
the sixteenth-century economic boom brought no significant expansion in the Ming state
revenues.11 One is left with little information in official documents on the wealth and
population. Therefore, the estimates of Chinese economy and population in the sixteenth
and seventeenth centuries should be made with great caution.
An institutional analysis of the Song dynasty will demonstrate contrasting
characteristics between Song and Ming in population administration and immigration
policies. The growth of the population in Song times accompanied the rise of a market
economy and urbanization. The literature on Song institutional and legal history points to
the fact that labor migrated from countryside to cities, or from one profession to another
by choice, and usually depending on the opportunities provided by the market economy.
To maintain its capacity to negotiate with society in a market economy, the Song
government was consistently sensitive to information on labor and wealth. The official
registration of local population and households was carried out once every three years
with particular concern for revaluating property and recording male adults.12 Thus, the
very distinctive feature presented in the Song official records of population and
11
The state in post-15th century China was inactive with diminished revenue. This situation remained unchanged even
up to the twentieth century. According to Rawski, at this period the taxes and public spending remained below 10
percent of GD With such a low share of state revenue, only two countries in the post-war world, Afghanistan and
Ethiopia, could stay alive (Rawski, 1989, 25-6). For a discussion of the very limited role of the state in Ming-Qing
China, see Eastman, 1988, 103-7, 130-4.
12
For the institutional aspect of Song household registration, see So, 1982; Wu Songdi, 2000, Chapter 2.
11
households is the basic division between taxable and non-taxable people, the so-called
zhuhu and kehu. For the individual falling into the former category, all of his and his
family’s mobile and immobile properties (cash, estate, farm, incomes, etc) were strictly
evaluated and in many cases required to be converted into cash.13 This concept of wealth
enabled Song officials to tax people based upon the amount of family property and
personal income, regardless of where they lived (urban or rural), or what they were doing
(farmers, merchants, owners of transport vehicles, or landlords). However, there was no
national standard for property gradations; local officials graded on the basis of local
situations all taxable farmer families into five levels, and urban residents into ten levels.
By comparison, Kehu were defined as employed laborers without any other major income,
such as tenants on a farm, or apprentices working at urban worksho
In light of these contextual analyses, one can perceive demographic changes in
relation to changes in social and institutional environments. I believe that the fourteenthcentury demographic data shall be reinterpreted as more than a quantitative reduction in
aggregate size. Much has to be considered about social differences between Song and
Ming.
1.3. Price: the great divergence
Price is the most evident indicator of the great divergence between the Song and
Ming economies. Owing to the studies by Peng Xinwei and Quan Hansheng, it is already
well known that the Ming food prices remained comparatively low.14 Yet the peculiarity
of the low prices in Ming China has been discussed little in relation to the working of a
13
For the property classification in household registration, see Liang Taiji, 1998, 19-36, 37-68, 1998; Wang Zengyu,
1996, 8-27. For the household registration in rural areas, see Yanagida Setsuko, 1986, 102-131.
14
Both Peng and Quan pointed out that the purchase power of the silver in the Ming was higher than in the Song (Peng,
1965, 706-722; Quan, 1967a).
12
real economy. Owing to their strategic significance, the prices of grain, especially that of
rice, were frequently reported to the government in imperial China. Although there are
several series of grain prices, the only comprehensive one to cover all periods of later
imperial China’s prices is made by Peng. I choose Peng’s series and compute them into a
single series based on silver value.
As the Peng’s grain index shows (see Table AA-1 in Appendix A), if we set the price
of 961-970 at 100, Song grain price gradually climbed up to 200 in nearly a hundred
years. By the beginning of the 13th century, it had risen to 3.5-4 times the early Song
grain price. After 1126, grain price in Southern China increased 50 per cent during the
twelfth century. Thus, during the three centuries, grain price continuously rose to 4-5
times that in pre-Song times. If grain price represents the general change of the prices,
this rising trend actually can be traced to an even earlier time. Scholars working on the
economic history of Tang China (618-907) have pointed out that the price level in Tang
began to rise in the late eighth century. By the beginning of the Song dynasty, silk prices,
for instance, were double that of the early eighth century.15
However, the long upward trend in prices came to an end in the late fourteenth
century. During the Ming, prices moved in the opposite direction. The Peng’s price index
indicates that, by the early Ming, it had almost returned to the original low level of the
mid-tenth century. Yet it was not the lowest point—grain prices bottomed out in the first
half of the fifteenth century. Not until the mid-sixteenth century did the grain price reach
250. And it was only in the second quarter of the eighteenth century that the grain price
attained the highest level in the Song grain prices. The two peaks were five hundred years
15
Ikeda On compares the price level between Han (206 B.C.-220 A.D.) and Tang (618-907) China and concludes that
the prices remained at a relatively low level in ancient China until the eighth century. Acknowledging the fact that the
rise of prices began in the late eighth century and heightened twice in the Song China, he attributes it to the transition in
social-economic structure in Tang-Song China. See Ikeda On, 1968.
13
apart.
Song bronze coins continued to serve as one of the major currencies in Ming, and
were necessary for small-sum transactions at local markets. 16 Because of the sharp
change in the silver-coin ratio, the current price index in silver value has disguised the
Ming deflation; using bronze coins as the value unit, the gap between Song and Ming
price levels might be magnified at least three times! The rice price in the early thirteenthcentury Lower Yangtze Delta, for instance, was, in fact, about ten times that in 1430s.
Two questions arise from the above comparison: why did the price level remain so
low in the early Ming and take so long time to regain the high level of the thirteenth
century? To what extent was such long-term deflation interrelated with the real economy?
Theoretically, price deflation means either a shrinking of total demand, and hence the
sluggishness of transactions among people who hold the money, or an adoption of a new
monetary system which has a low nominal value, but whose real value (exchange in
goods such as grain, textile, etc.) remains more or less the same. 17 Scholars tend to
attribute the low price level to the Ming money supply, especially to the trivial coinage
from Ming imperial mints, which could be ignored in comparison to the large amount of
money supply in Song.18 Both the lack of bronze coins and consumers’ preference for
silver, according to this monetarist argument, led to the higher purchasing power of silver.
However, this argument often fails to tell us whether the deflationary trend had an impact
16
Peng, 646; von Glahn, 1996, 98-102.
For the latter case, the Fisher equation MV=PT indicates the price (P) may descend or rise in direct connection with
the change of the money supply (M), only when the velocity of circulation (V) and quantity of transaction (T) remain
constant. Thus, the change of the money supply may only influence the price level, without interfering with the
working of the real economy.
18
The Ming money stock (including all the monetary means) prior to 1550, as I will discuss later, was only 1/6-1/3 of
the total output of bronze coins from Song imperial mints until 1220s, not to mention other kinds of money in
circulation during Song.
17
14
upon the real working of the Ming economy, or vice versa.19 An interpretation from a
purely nominal monetary perspective will face challenges from changes in relative prices
over Song-Ming times. As shown in Table 1, changes in relative prices show a wide range
of variance. What is striking is the relative price between silver and coinage, which
declined sharply from an exchange rate of 50 grams equal to 2,000-3,000 wen (the
minimum monetary unit for Chinese bronze coins) to 750 wen. This change goes against
the ratio of other items.
Table 1. Relative prices of silver in Song and Ming
Silver
(50 gram)
Song
Gold
(gram)
1
Silk
(bolt)
0.67
Rice
(liter)
340
Coin
(wen)
2000-3000
Ming
7.5 (1:7.5)*
1.67 (1:2.5)
1060 (1:3.1)
750 (1:0.32)
Sources: Quan, 1967a; Wang Wencheng, 2000, 175, 198.
* Figures in parentheses indicate the ratio between the Song and Ming prices of the same
item purchased with silver.
In addition to changes in relative prices between Song and Ming, the price movement
in Ming itself contradicts the nominal monetary interpretation as well. At first sight the
great gap between Song and Ming money supplies should account for the price
divergence. However, the price in Ming showed a deeper decline in the first half of the
fifteenth century, and remained at a low level for most of the century. It was by the end of
the fifteenth century that the price level moved towards a higher level, which had never
occurred before in the history of Ming prices. Such a trend implies no linear relationship
between the price level and the Ming money supply, since the latter had not changed
profoundly since the end of the fourteenth century. Most of the imperial mints were
19
Peng, 1965, 706-12; Quan, 1967a.
15
closed in 1390s, and the silver output from state-controlled domestic mining reached a
relatively high output in the first decade of the fifteenth century.20 When grain prices
began to decline again from 1400 on, the money supply during the period (1400-1435)
was larger than before or after. There is no reason from the money supply side to explain
why the price level declined during most of the fifteenth century and began to rise at the
end of that century.
2. The fourteenth and fifteenth centuries: a crisis in the real economy
The divergence between Song-Ming price regimes recalls the price revolution in
sixteenth and seventeenth century Europe, but in an opposite direction—the price levels
increased about seven times in England and ten times in Netherlands. Jack Goldstone has
argued persuasively that the primary reason for such inflation was the change in the
velocity of the money (V), impelled by commercialization, especially urbanization,
which would certainly intensify the chances of transactions.21
I am convinced that the divergence between Song and Ming price regimes was not
a simple combination of the shrinking in money supply and the sharp decline in aggregate
population. 22 The insufficient money supply contributed to the Ming price deflation;
20
Quan, 1967b.
Goldstone, 1984; Lindert, 1985
22
If we turn to the quantitative monetary theory, we might calculate from either side of the equation to see if the results
are compatible. The money stock in late eleventh-century China was in fact about 3-6 times as large as that of the Ming
in 1550s (see Table 6 in this chapter). If we assume the early Ming phase stops around 1450, we can roughly estimate
the money supply then as only two-thirds of the Ming money stock in 1550s. The imperial mints closed after the early
Ming, and we believe many of Song coins still remained in circulation, thus giving more weight to the money supply in
the early Ming—then we can estimate that the money supply in the early Ming was only 11-22 per cent of that in
1120s. We know the early Ming population in 1394 was 60 million, and that it would be 76 million in 1550 (supposing
annual growth rate is 4‰). This would imply the decline in population between 1450 and 1120 was 69 per cent. If we
follow the Fisher Equation P=MV/T, and assume V constant and that T just exactly follows population change—
decline 69 per cent without decline in real income per capita, then we will predict that the price level in the early Ming
21
16
however, this cause could not explain the relative decline and rise within the Ming price
regime. Goldstone’s interpretation of the British price revolution highlights the fact that
urbanization and rising population were agents promoting a rise in V, which will grow as
the square of population growth when commercialization is spreading.23 The price level
in the first decade of the Ming dynasty was already only 75 per cent of that in the 1120s,
but it went down again in the first half of the fifteenth century to just 20 per cent of that
in the 1370s. Since there is no evidence suggesting a radical change in money supply
before 1370 and 1420, it is difficult to imagine this ever deepening deflation would not
result in changes in V and T as well in response to changes in M. Contrary to the view of
a deflation only in nominal terms, I suggest that the divergence between Song and Ming
price regimes reveals a long-term trend of deflation in the Ming monetary economy and,
more significantly, a crisis in real economy.
Several pieces of evidence from the early Ming point out precisely the diminution of
hard currency in transactions. In a mountain village situated in Huizhou, a region at the
far western part of the Lower Yangtze delta, The Wang brothers, Wang Qiugan and Wang
Qiuguan, left 38 contracts of land purchases.24 These land purchases mostly occurred in
the early Ming, with the first case recorded in 1393, just seven years after the
establishment of the Ming dynasty, and the last case in 1430.
would be 16-32 per cent of that in 1120s. The grain index shows the price gap between 1450 and 1120 was 22 per cent,
just falling into the range. But to accept this speculation one has to prove V was constant at the two observing points.
23
Goldstone, 1984.
24
Wang’s contracts were respectively collected by Anhui Provincial Museum and History Institute, China Academy of
Social Sciences. These contracts, along with many other land documents have been published in Ming-Qing Huizhou
Shehui Jingji Ziliao Congbian, vol.1-2, 1988, 1990. For Wang’s contracts, see ibid., vol.1, 1-15, 24-26, 388; vol.2, 1923, 28.
17
Table 2. Land purchase in Huizhou, 1393-1430*
Period
(a)
Baochao
(b)
Coin
(c)
Kind
(d)
Silver
(e)
Recor
d
10
(f)
c/e
(percentage
)
40
(g)
a/e
(percentage
)
6
1393-98
6
-
4
-
1399-
3
-
8
5
18
44.4
16.7
0
0
6
0
6
100
0
-
-
-
-
0
0
0
0
0
5
0
5
100
0
9
0
22
5
39
56.4
23
1402
14031413
14141424
14251430
Total
*Source: Ming-Qing Huizhou Shehui Jingji Ziliao Congbian, vol.1, 1-15, 24-26; vol.2,
19-23, 28.
On the one hand, these contracts, as displayed in Table 2, show the withdrawal of
currency, especially paper currency, in the first decade of the fifteenth century. On the
other hand ever since the late fourteenth century until the mid-fifteenth century, people
had to use cloth, grain and silver as payment to complete a transaction.
The contracts of land purchases occupy a large part of the preserved Huizhou
historical documents. Li Ruoyu reports about 1,062 Huizhou contracts collected in the
Anhui History Museum, dating from 1368 to 1644.25 He finds 226 cases for the first
century (1368-1457) in Ming history, among which payments in kind (cloth & grain)
25
Li Ruoyu, 1988, 40-41.
18
were 72, about 32 per cent of the total contracts. Especially for the early and middle
fifteenth century, cloth and grain became the means for land purchases.26 Silver was not
permitted to be used as currency in the early Ming; however, payment in silver
represented another one-thirds of land purchases. Units and quality of these silver
payments varied tremendously, and were described with particular attention in the
contracts. Some cases even indicated that they were from personal ornaments. In later
times, these variances disappeared from the contracts as silver was widely accepted in
circulation. Both the case of the Wang brothers and the report by Li Ruoyu from a
broader perspective demonstrate the use of cloth and grain in purchases in the early Ming,
especially in the fifteenth century. This explicitly points to the rising of a barter economy
in local communities in the Lower Yangtze Delta, the leading region in the Ming
economy. These non-standard payments were unlikely to encourage people to make more
transactions beyond the necessities. As a result, V, the velocity of money in circulation,
must slow down.
In addition to the cases of land purchases and sales in Huizhou, we know from many
but loose accounts that coins were rare and that silver was not yet popularly used. Then
we have to conclude that if the role of Ming paper currency in money circulation is not
considered important (as I will argue in the next section), then the early Ming economy
would have done little with monetary exchange, and is instead run on a basis of a barter
economy and unilateral payments.27
We have no direct evidence to verify an almost disappearance of the monetary
26
Li Ruoyu, 1988, 43. Also see von Glahn, 1996, 78.
The term “unilateral payments” is borrowed from the study of medieval European economy, which indicates the
revenues due to landlords and settled in kind or in labor (Cipolla, 1956, 7-8). I use it in the Chinese case to indicate the
early Ming state extracted revenues from local societies almost exclusively in kind or in labor. Not until the midsixteenth century did local governments gradually convert those “unilateral payments” into cash income. And this came
into a national accomplishment as late as in the mid-eighteenth century.
27
19
economy, despite the fact that we do have enough information to speculate. The early
Ming left almost no concise information about market prices. Except for the official
exchange rates between money, grain and cloth in unilateral payments recorded by the
government, which were kept unchanged over years, scholars find little information
available about early Ming prices and markets. The Huizhou case is exceptional in this
regard, which proves the existence of local markets in some regions in the early Ming,
but purchasers at these markets had to appeal to specific goods for exchange. Merchants
and craftsmen were, according to official records, sent for administrative and military
services to the capital and frontier garrisons mostly from the Lower Yangtze delta. They
were paid very low wages, if any, and had to make a living from other resources. In the
Wang brothers’ contracts, I find six cases of land sales owing to the transportation of
grain taxes: in the summer of 1401, six farmers from the same place sold their lands in
small lots to Wang in order to accumulate money for traveling expenses incurred in
delivering grain taxes to state depots.28 Delivery and transportation of grain taxes was one
of the heaviest burdens for peasants in the Lower Yangtze Delta, who had to carry all
grain taxes by themselves on a rotating basis to the state depots mostly situated at the
capital. Doushan Gong, a patriarch of a famous lineage at Huizhou, was from a military
household. His lineage established collective property in 1399 in order to support lineage
members’ military service at a remote garrison in Manchuria, thousands of miles away
from Huizhou. Both his father and his senior brother died at that garrison. They had to
keep providing a male adult to serve in the troop as well as providing all his living
expenses there.29 In addition to grain transportation and military services, the early Ming
28
29
Ming-Qing Huizhou Shehui Jingji Ziliao Congbian, vol.1, 10-11; vol.2, 20-21.
Doushan Gong Jiayi Jiaozhu.
20
state used in construction projects more than a hundred thousand craftsmen and laborers,
who were classified as artisans in the Yellow Register (Huangce 黃冊). In 1393, more
than 230,000 artisans across the country were recorded in the Yellow Register for the
building of the city wall of Nanjing, the capital then.30 They were called on once every
three years from their rural residences and worked at the assigned place for three months.
However, there is no evidence indicating that they were able to do business there, or, that
a commercial network spread out along the migration area. As noted before, the early
Ming policies tended to reduce the size of bureaucracy as well as money in circulation to
a minimum size. Many projects, including grain transportation and military defense, were
enforced on the basis of unilateral payments. The three capitals in the early Ming
(Fengyang, Nanjing and Beijing), for instance, were built by the corvee enlisted from
rural communities, soldiers and prisoners. Laborers exceeded 1 million people for each
project.31 Except for reimbursements made on rare occasions, most of the seasonal labors
such as peasants were supposed to feed themselves, and soldiers and artisans working
yearly were paid in grain, which was too little by which to support a family.
As a preliminary remark, I would conclude that as the formation of social
organizations and social relations in the early Ming centered on the state, the dominance
of unilateral payments greatly constrained developments in long-distance trade and intraregional networks. 32 Scholars usually take the Grand Canal as the example of long30
Ming Taizu Shilu, vol.230; Ming Huidian, vol.189, Ministry of Works.
Yang Guoqing gives estimates of the corvee in the construction of Nanjing’s city wall; he points out that the potential
human sources for building works included 200 thousand soldiers, probably fewer than 200 thousand artisans, 1 million
peasants, and several hundred thousand prisoners. The total work required 7 million individual workdays. See Yang
Guoqing, 2002, 37-44.
32
Although the development of markets and business network showed continuity in China from the sixteenth century
through the twentieth century, in Xu Tan’s view, it was in the Qing time that long-distance trade was expanding to
coastal areas and to the Yangtze river system in addition to the Grand Canal already achieved in the mid-Ming. (Xu
Tan, 2000).
31
21
distance trade under the Ming government. The transportation of grain tributary through
the Grand Canal to feed the officials and soldiers at Beijing was becoming more urgent
when Zhu Di decided to move the capital to Beijing. Corvee laborers and soldiers were
used extensively in grain transportation. Even ships used in transportation were built
entirely by the artisans at government docks and cost no money.33 It was as late as the
1430s that Zhou Chen, a high official in the Lower Yangtze Delta reported that native
people would avoid taxes and labor services by going out and seeking refuge at cities and
ferries along the Grand Canal, where they were able to do small-scale business.34 For our
purpose—money circulation and domestic trade in the early Ming—the Grand Canal can
hardly make out a strong case for such an argument.
If monetary demand did not come from long-distance trade in the early Ming, did
local markets draw much money? Many relevant records in the early Ming suggest that
this was not the case either. In the Ming gazetteers scholars find only a few towns and
periodic markets dating back to the early Ming, while the majority of local markets and
towns came into sight in the sixteenth century.35 Before that one can hardly expect that
the ongoing transactions on a trivial scale at rural markets would absorb a good deal of
currency. The contracts of land sales from the Huizhou archives also demonstrate the
dominance in the early Ming of land transactions in small pieces with pretty low prices.36
33
Fu Chonglan gives a good survey of cities and industries along the Grand Canal in late Ming and Qing and traces
their origins to the early Ming with regard to their administrative and military functions (Fu Chonglan, 1985).
34
Zhou Chen, “Yu xingzai hubu zhugong sh”, in Hong, 1988, 30-33.
35
For north China, see Yamane, 1995; for the Pearl River delta, see Ye Xian’en & Tan Lihua, 1984; for Fujian, see
Chen Keng, 1986; For Shandong, see Xu Tan, 1995. For the Lower Yangtze delta, see Fan Shuzhi, Liu Shiji. Xu Tan
recently attempts to theorize these regional investigations on the base of Skinner’s framework. She gives a
comprehensive analysis of the development of local markets and town both chronologically and geographically (Xu
Tan, 1997, 1999, 2000). The early Ming just saw the primary stage of markets development in rural counties ever since
the long-lasting civil wars which had destroyed local economy and society.
36
In the early Ming contracts, such as those of the Wang brothers, most transactions dealt with lands less than 1acre.
The price, if paid in grain, often doubled an annual rent of the land. Although in terms of Baochao, the land value
inflated much in the Yongle reign, the land prices in Huizhou in the early Ming remained as low as less than 1 tael of
22
The loss of about one-third or half of the population together with a severe
deflation would weaken the fourteenth-century economy significantly. The weak demand
from domestic markets should have been a direct cause of the low-level prices in the
early Ming. The anti-market policies of the early Ming government certainly shattered
society and delayed the recovery of a market economy because, for the first hundred
years, one can find little information on the resurgence of markets and consumption in
local society.37
3. Money supply
3.1. Periodization of Chinese monetary history: A silver economy vs. a coin economy
The periodization of Chinese monetary history also follows the division between
Song and Ming China. In the former period, both the number of bronze coins in
circulation and the amount supplied by imperial mints reached their height in Chinese
history; in the latter, however, silver became the major currency, whose supply and
circulation were entirely out of state control, and which largely depended on foreign
import. The influx of silver imports from America and Japan came to a peak at the end of
the sixteenth century. 38 The silver influx in sixteenth-century China undoubtedly
silver per mu (1 mu =0.16441 acre) until 1440s It then jumped up to about 10 taels in the Hongzhi reign (1488-1505),
and even lowered somewhat in late-sixteenth and mid-seventeenth centuries. In the late seventeenth and the first decade
of the eighteenth century, it rose slowly, but became apparently faster in the second decade, and came to a peak in the
Qianlong reign (1736-95), with the average price about over 20 taels per mu. The high price in land markets in the
Qianlong Reign can find a parallel in Suzhou (see the contracts of land sales collected by Hong Huanchun, 1988, 87177). It is worth be a promising prospect if scholars in the future can undertake a comprehensive research on changes in
land prices over the six hundred years ever since the fourteenth century in China, as there are more than hundred
thousand land contracts scattered over the country, especially concentrating on the lower Yangtze delta, Guangdong,
and Fujian.
37
I will continue to discuss on the early Ming state and economy in Chapter IV.
38
Scholars emphasize the monetary transition from using bronze coins to silver, and view it as a milestone in the
Chinese monetary economy. In this way, the silver transition theory does relate the Chinese economy to the emergence
of the sixteenth-century world economy. The monetarist historian Miyazawa has made a significant argument that the
monetary transition from bronze coins to silver was an important aspect of the social and economic transformation of
China from Song through Ming-Qing times. The different uses of these two kinds of metal currencies, according to him,
can be identified as a sequence of temporal stages in which each of them, either coins or silver, was predominant in
response to the needs of the Chinese economy and society at different stages (Miyazawa, 1993, 213-6). For the current
discussion on the formation of the silver economy in the Ming China, see Atwell, 1990,1998; Von Glahn, 1996;
23
stimulated a market economy, but it was far from sufficient to determine the trend of
price change, not to mention the nature of the economy.39 Ever since the Song dynasty,
China had been dominated by a multiple monetary system. In addition to bronze coins,
the Song government used a variety of monetary tools such as currency reserve (gold &
silver) as well as securities backed by precious metals and strategic goods (tea, salt,
alcohol, and so on.).40 Thereafter, merchants could easily save on the costs of transferring
bronze coins in long-distance trade by using bills of exchange issued or guaranteed by the
imperial ministry of the treasury. By the mid-twelfth century, paper notes (Huizi 會子)
had become the major currency, maintaining successfully their nominal value for over
sixty years. However, during the transition from Song to Ming, the state lost sovereignty
in issuing money. It was the rejection of paper currency by society and the inability of the
government to provide large amounts of coinage that gave rise to the prevalence of silver
as the standard value. The monetarist argument of the silver economy pays no attention to
money circulation, and often fails to acknowledge the question: how did changes in
monetary items, whether bronze coin or silver, interact with the working of a real
economy?
From a macro-economic perspective, one needs to relate the money supply, either
in bronze coin or in silver, to the needs of a developing market economy. It is not
necessarily true that bronze coins are inferior to silver as long as the former is maintained
in sufficient amount and supported by other monetary means. The circulation of bronze
coins in Song was supported by other monetary and fiscal tools such as commercial loans
Miyazawa, 1998.
39
The Swiss is another example of a country using low-value metal coins. Tokugawa Japan even adopted rice as the
standard for its payment in place of bronze coin. Yet this “regression” was particularly related to economic growth
occurring then in Japan. See Akira, 1988.
40
For the silver serving as the medium of exchange in the Song, see Wang Wencheng, 2001.
24
and bills of exchange. Hence, there were few technical difficulties in dealing with longdistance trade. Below, I am going to argue that the Song money supply measured in
bronze coins (not including silver, gold or any M2 currency) far exceeded that of Ming,
even if one includes both silver and bronze coins in the latter case.
Before making any estimate of the money supply in the two periods, I will address a
background issue in relation to the money supply in Ming: shall we take Baochao, the
Ming paper currency, as a part of the money supply? I suggest Baochao was used as a
means of payment rather than a medium of exchange. Following Song and the Mongols,
the Ming government issued Baochao.41 But they issued paper currency only for fiscal
purposes and subsequently it was irrelevant to other hard currencies in circulation. Ray
Huang reports that, in 1390, the emperor handed out no fewer than 75 million strings of
new paper currency, a figure Huang takes to be about 2.5 times of the annual land tax
revenue, which was the major income source of the Ming state.42 The inflation got worse
during the Yongle reign—whereas 1 guan of Baochao could, according to the regulation
of the Hongwu reign, buy 1 shi of rice, and was equal to 1,000 wen of bronze coins, in
1407, 1 guan of Baochao could buy only 1/30 shi rice. In 1448, a decade later, it was
only worth 2 wen even at the official rate, an inflation rate 500 times in comparison to its
original value. However, this super-inflation did not make the real economy
inflationary—the prices in both bronze coin and silver remained quite low almost through
the fifteenth century. This point will shed light on the nature of the Ming monetary
economy. The Ming government proceeded with issuing and distributing Baochao mostly
41
Unlike Song and the Mongols, the Ming government prepared no reserve to back up Baochao, but commanded that
Baochao was the only currency in the market. Neither coins nor silver could be used. This policy was disregarded by
common people, who preferred coins and silver.
42
Ray Huang, 1974, 69-70.
25
as payments to officials and to soldiers, while at the same time people no longer took
them as money. In this case, one can hardly expect circulation of baochao to be able to
meet monetary needs of the economy.
3.2. Estimates of the money supply in Song and Ming prior to 1550
At this point, we can turn to metallic money, both bronze coins and silver. It is a
well-known fact that the Song state minted the largest number of bronze coins ever in
Chinese monetary history, most of which were made prior to 1125.43 Even today, what
archeologists frequently discover in hoard sites are mostly Song coins. Furthermore,
Song coinage can be proven to support a monetary economy much larger than that of the
silver economy in seventeenth-century China. Before we quantify the size of the
monetary economy in Song and Ming, however, we have to figure out the size of the
money supply in Song and Ming China. To make them compatible, I constrain the
investigation to metallic money (coins and silver). For the minting of bronze coins in
Song China, we have reliable records for most periods. 44 The total adds up to 193.4
million strings of bronze coins prior to the Jurchen in 1125. Recently, Gao Congming has
reexamined Hino Kaisaburo and Peng’s estimates on the output of Song imperial mints,
and suggested that the total amount of the Song coinage (excluding steel coins) prior to
1125 was around 262 million strings of coins.45 Both his estimate and mine give weight
to the New Policy period, whereas he gives a more optimistic opinion on the late decades
(1100-25) of the New Policy. Either of the two figures can be hardly taken as real output,
43
When the court moved to Hangzhou in southern China, the scarcity of mineral sources, especially copper, forced it to
issue Huizi instead.
44
For the sources of information on imperial minting production , see Appendix A.
45
Gao, 2000, 103. Miyazawa suggests the money stock was about 300 million strings over the Song prior to 1127
(Miyazawa, 1993, 204).
26
but they indicate a spectrum in which real output could fall. Archaeologists and
numismatists have noticed that most of the Song coins regularly weighed and presented a
standard of material-combination. This, in fact, rules out the possibility of counterfeiting
currency in a large amount, which allows me to count only products from imperial mints
as the Song money supply.
The Ming imperial minting produced a smallest number of coins in the late imperial
history. The government was neither willing nor able to create a large amount of coinage.
The Ming imperial minting went into decline: it is usually thought to have produced only
a small number of coins in the late imperial history. From 1368 through 1572 the Ming
imperial minting produced 4-6 million strings of coins, a figure roughly matching the
annual output of the Song state in the 1080s.46 However, coins, including those from
previous dynasties and even counterfeit currency, were admitted by the imperial authority
to be used in small transactions most of the time. I assume the rate of 8:1 as the normal
ratio between Song and Ming coins in circulation during the Ming dynasty.47 This will
increase the total money stock to 36-54 million strings of coins, an amount roughly 15-27
per cent of that in the Song money supply prior to 1125, but already far exceeding the
usual expectation of bronze coins in circulation in Ming.
The monetary economy in Ming China was often characterized by the use of
silver. I will estimate how much the Ming money supply was secured by silver. For silver
domestic production, Quan notes that the Ming state lagged behind the Song in silver
mining. In contrast to the average annual mining revenue of 223,850 taels of silver in the
eleventh century, the Ming mining output was only 100,000 taels of silver per year (about
46
47
For the estimate of the coins in circulation, see Appendix A.
For how can I reach such a ratio, see Appendix A.
27
220,000 taels in the early fifteenth century, declining to 50, 000 taels in succeeding
periods). 48 The total amount from 1390 through 1520, according to Quan, was about
11,395, 775 taels.49 Since no more official records were reported after 1520, Wang Yuxun
gives his estimate of the Ming silver revenue in the later period (1520-1664). He thinks
the total amount in the late sixteenth and early seventeenth centuries should be
13,820,100 taels, which could be even larger than that in the preceding periods.50 The
aggregate silver output from domestic mining, then, according to this optimistic view,
would reach 25 million taels. A second look, however, suggests 15-25 million taels silver.
We need to take it in mind that, before significant imports of silver into China began
in the late sixteenth century—quite late for Ming history—the money supply from the
domestic side was very limited: 15-25 million taels of silver plus 36-54 million strings of
coins would add up to 46.5-71.5 million strings of coins in total value.51 This figure is
only half of the money supply of the Song state prior to 1043. In the succeeding decades
of the New Policies the outputs of coinage outstripped all that had ever been produced
previously in the Song imperial mints.
The import of silver in late Ming times has legitimated the allegation that the Ming
monetary economy developed into an unprecedented size pumped up by its strong
connection to an emerging world economy. However, much of this assertion is not tested
in quantitative research. Because of the lack of reliable quantitative records available on
48
Quan, 1967b. Quan also notes that the silver collected in the Song was the tax part of mining output, while in the
Ming, owing to the strict monopoly policy, mining households submitted 40-50 per cent silver outputs to the court,
which was much larger than in the Song. This would imply a greater variance in silver outputs between the Song and
the Ming. See Quan, 1967b, 613-5. For a comprehensive view on mining policies in Song China, see Wang Lingling;
Qi, 1988, 576-97.
49
Quan, 1967b, Table 1 & 2, 602-8. For the period from 1487 through 1520 the mining revenues added gold and silver
together, thus the silver revenue would be a little lower than in records. Also see Cambridge History of China, vol.8,
386.
50
Wang Yuxun, 2001, 19.
51
I estimate 1 tael of silver as being equal to 0.7 string of coins according to the contemporary price of coins in silver.
28
the Chinese side, we have to rely on the records documented by officials and merchants
in Japan, Manila, Macao and Europe, countries that did not necessarily distinguish their
exports to China from those to other countries in East Asia and Southeast Asia.
Researchers come down quite differently on the aggregate value of imported silver, in
exchange for Chinese goods such as silk and tea, into late Ming China. The estimates, for
instance, vary from 100 million to over 300 million for the inflow of silver by the end of
the Ming empire (see Table 3).
Table 3. Estimates of Chinese Imports of Foreign Silver in Ming China, 1550-1645
(in millions of taelsa)
von Glahn
Wu Chengming
Yamamura &
Quan
Kamiki
1550-1600
57.7-62.5
41.27-51.77
47.4-63.5
1601-1645
134.2
44.4-59.4
184.9-225.1
-
Total,
1550-1645
191.9-196.7
85.7-111.2
232.4-288.9
45.8
Sources: von Glahn, 2000, 140; Wu Chengming, 2002, 170-173; Yamamura Kozo & Kamiki Tetsuo,
1983; Quan, for Japan, 1984, 644; for Spain, 1957 (also see Lin Man-houng, 1990, 303-4).
a. I have converted the weight unit into tael: 1 ton silver = 0.027 million taels silver.
Although the estimates in Table 3 show obvious variances in the total value of silver
imports, they reveal a similar trend that silver imports grew rapidly in the first half of the
seventeenth century.
3.3 Money supply and domestic markets: the late Ming puzzle
The significance of silver imports, rendered by these estimates, should not be
underestimated. One may calculate, following von Glahn’s opinion, that “during the
second half of the sixteenth century silver imports were adding at least eight times more
bullion to China’s stock of money than domestic mines; in the first half of the
29
seventeenth century, imports exceeded domestic production by perhaps twenty-fold”!52
One can also conclude, merely by recalling that the Ming money supply (coins plus silver)
before 1550 was estimated to be 40-63 million strings of coins, that this would cause the
money stock to swell 100 per cent around 1600, and more than 250 per cent around
1650. 53 This extraordinary increase in silver imports makes even less significant the
bullion flow from America into Europe. Imports between 1500 and 1650 increased by
only 26.7 per cent Europe’s stock of silver bullion. For gold, the increase was even
lower—3.6 per cent.54
In sum, the size of the Ming monetary economy could probably be as large as 174200.7 million strings of coins, an amount that already approximates that of the Song
money supply in the early eleventh century. Contrary to the Song case, however, the
increase in the Ming money supply was secured through marine trade, by which the
volume of about 200 million taels would indicate a similar size of exports from China
such as silk and tea. If these speculations can be proven, they reveal an export-leading
economy in late Ming. This pattern, though emphasizing the significance of foreign trade,
contradicts the current paradigm of the Ming domestic-based market economy. Economic
historians usually argue that the development of the market economy was based upon
domestic needs. And, in fact, until 1550, we see no sign of a strong connection between
domestic output and foreign markets.
How large, then, was China’s domestic trade and what was the share of foreign trade
in China’s trade? Wu Chengming suggests an annual volume of long-distance trade in
52
von Glahn, 2000, 140-1. Wu Chengming also suggests the silver import before the eigheenth century would tripled
the Ming silver stock (Wu Chengming, 2002, 173, 249).
53
I suppose the contemporary rate between silver and bronze coins is: 1 tael of silver = 0.7 string of coins.
54
Braudel, 1974, 28.
30
domestic markets of 12.1 million taels of silver. 55 Multiplying this figure by 5, we will
get an annual value of 121 million taels of silver for domestic trade in China.56
Table 4 Annual volumes of Domestic trade & overseas trade in Ming China,
1550-1645
(in million taels silver)
Trade, Total
O/Tb
Period
Domestic trade Overseas trade a
1550-60
121
1.2
122.2
0.98 per cent
1601-45
121
2.98
124
2.4 per cent
1550-1645
121
2
123
1.6 per cent
a. To get the annual volume of overseas trade, I divide the total silver imports (von
Glahn’s figures in Table 2.3) by the years from respective periods: the annual average
amount of silver imports 1.2 million for 1550-1600, 2.98 million for 1601-45, and about
2 million for the whole period of late Ming.
b. The ratio between overseas trade and trade in total.
The estimates of domestic trade and overseas trade are shown in Table 4. The figures
are best viewed as an order of magnitude rather than a precise measure of quantity.
Nonetheless, they demonstrate the very minor percentage of overseas trade in the total
trade, which, in fact, supports Wu’s argument. However, these two narratives of the Ming
economy, one of a gradual process driven by domestic markets, the other a spurt of
foreign trade and silver exports in the late sixteenth and early seventeenth centuries,
cannot be true at the same time. Either might be possible, but neither supports the other.
55
Wu Chengming approaches this figure through estimating several major goods in late Ming long-distance trade:
grain (8.5 million taels), cloth (3.3 million taels), silk (0.3 million taels). See Wu, 1983b. Wu Chengming
approaches this figure through estimating several major goods in late Ming long-distance trade: grain (8.5
million taels), cloth (3.3 million taels), silk (0.3 million taels). See Wu, 1983b. The size of long-distance
trade, according to Wu’s estimates, was no more than 20 per cent of the aggregate value of domestic trade
in the eighteenth century. Perkins’ study indicates that the ratio between the size of long-distance trade and
that of rural markets.prior to 1900 was about 1:3-4 (Perkins, 1969, 114-5). When applying this ratios to
estimating the late Ming’s trade, I assume the gross value of goods at the rural markets was about 10 times
long-distance trade, because the underdevelopment of long-distance trade in late Ming, thus late Ming
domestic trade not exceed 121 million taels.
56
Wu’s estimate is closely related to his Marxist view of the market economy in a pre-industrial society. He focuses his
demonstrations on the supply side instead of the demand. This made the estimate particularly indecisive because of the
impossibility of measuring the total products of peasant households at aggregate level.
31
Estimates on coins in circulation and silver imports suggest an obvious delay in the
Ming money supply in proportion to monetary demands from a market economy. In the
first narrative, the development of domestic markets in the sixteenth and seventeenth
centuries was achieved on the basis of specialization in agriculture and handicraft
industries, a specialization that led to increasing exchanges between agricultural products
and non-agricultural goods across regions, and growth in productivity on both sides. This
pattern has been recognized as a successful way to a high-level market economy, and
named as the Jiangnan (the Lower Yangtze delta) Path.57 Such a theory reserves little
space for the argument of foreign trade and silver imports as an engine for development
in the Ming economy, because regional specialization in agriculture and industry was a
gradual process starting from the late fifteenth century, thus, independent of foreign trade,
which was still negligible until the late sixteenth century. Silver imports only began to
influence the trend of the economy almost a century later. As such, one must ask how
could the Ming market economy maintain expansion with such a small money stock
before 1600?
In the second narrative, one cannot find the corresponding relationship between
silver imports and the prices. Silver imports began to surpass the domestic part of the
money supply, which I estimate to be 36-54 million strings of coins, until 1600. However,
the prices still remained stable around 1600. 58 Furthermore, as I discuss later, both
nominal and real wages changed little. How to explain the expansion of the market
57
For the recent theories of the market economy in the Lower Yangtze delta, see Li Bozhong, 1998.
According to Braudel & Spooner, the total amount of metal money in circulation in Europe and the Mediterranean
before the discovery of America was an approximate total of 5,000 tons of gold and 60,000 tons of silver. The arrivals
of bullion from America during the century and a half between 1500 and 1650 amount to 1,600 tons of silver and 180
of gold (Braudel, 1974, 28). The amount of silver importing into Europe in the sixteenth century now looks less
significant than it used to. In contrast, the case in late Ming would be extremely unusual by the dominant size of
imports over domestic stock of money and, yet, the stability of prices presented in the economy of late Ming China.
58
32
economy in late Ming at an aggregate level still remains a big puzzle. In sum, there is no
direct evidence either to support or to deny the existence of a market economy of such
size. The very backward nature of the Ming state made its tax revenues irrelevant of
growth in the market economy, and thus the Ming official documents can hardly recount
any changes in trade or industry at the aggregate level. Neither do we have a clear idea of
population growth around 1600.59 Any estimate of the size of the monetary economy in
late Ming China, therefore, shall be no more than a very speculative attempt; and to make
such speculation relevant, one needs to choose a benchmark year with rich and highquality data, for further analysis of the late Ming case.60 I will thus give an estimate of the
monetary economy in 1750, a year when the eighteenth-century economy was starting to
reach prosperity.
I attempt to compare the size of the monetary economy over the long run,61 and the
results are given in Table 5.
Table 5. Money stock in China, 750-1750
Bronze coin
(000,000 string)
Coins per capitad
(in strings)
Silver
(in millions of
taels)
Tang, 750
Song, 1120
Ming, 1550
Ming, 1600
Qing, 1750
21.3-42.6a
193.4-262
36-54c
36-54
122.8-146.8
0.31-0.61
1.53
0.18-0.45
0.18-0.45
0.4-0.48
-
-
15-25
125.8-130.6
317
59
The year of 1600 is currently recognized as the peak of Ming population. However, there was no reliable record for
population in the last two hundred years. The estimates of the aggregate population then vary between 120 and 200
million. A few examples are: Ho, 150 million (Ho, 1959, 264); Perkins, 120-200 million (Perkins, 1969, 216); Wu
Chengming, 120 million (Wu Chengming, 2000, 25); Cao, 200 million in 1590 (Cao Shuji, 2000a, 201).
60
Despite the fact that most of China’s socioeconomic historians often acknowledge the late Ming and early Qing as an
integral part of economic development, especially those engaged in the regional study of the Lower Yangtze delta and
other coastal provinces, the study of economic performance in pre-industrial China encounters two different cases in
regard to aggregate data.
61
Peng is the first in Chinese monetary history to propose comparing the money supply over the course of Chinese
history. His comparison sets up an example for later researchers, without whom the present research might be
impossible. However, in Peng’s estimates the money supply of the Ming in both total value and per capita are
overestimated. Peng underestimates the aggregate population of the Ming as only 60 million, and fails to identify the
specific year on which he is focusing (Peng, 1994, 781).
33
Money supply
46.5-71.5
124-145e
376-400f
21.3-42.6
193.4-262b
(in millions of
strings)
MS* per capita
0.31-0.61
1.53
0.23-0.6
0.62-1.21
1.25-1.33
(in strings)
Sources: for Tang China in 750, see Peng, 1994, 781. For an estimate of coins and silver in the Qing,
see Lin Man-hung, 1991.
* Abbreviation of Money supply.
a. Peng assumes private coins were probably not different from the total for official coins, thus
doubles the latter to get this figure. I decide to use official coins for a lower bound estimate.
b. I include only the coinage as the Song money supply. In fact, it would be larger if we took into
account precious metals (gold and silver) and commercial bills.
c. The Ming coinage accounts for only 1/9 of coins in stock. The majority are Song coins.
d. The aggregate population for each period is assumed to be: Song (1120)—126 million,
Ming (1550, 1600)—120~200 million, Qing (1750)—300 million.
e. 1 tael of silver is equal to 0.7 string of coins.
f. 1 tael of silver is equal to 0.8 string of coins.
The money supply expanded remarkably to a total value of 400 million strings of
coins around 1750, a height in Chinese monetary history. Song China, however,
maintained the record of money stock per capita, and followed immediately the Qing in
total value. The Ming cases show a great gap between the money supply in 1550 and that
in 1600, which calls for further explanation if such radical change ever occurred. But for
most of the Ming, the money supply per capita seems to have been very low. In addition
to the general pattern of the money supply, one should consider the role of coins as well.
As late as the eighteenth century coins were still a significant part of the money stock,
and probably accounted for 30-40 per cent of the total. Such a high percentage, in fact,
goes against Miyazawa’s monetary transition thesis.
4. Wages
Changes in prices and money supply in Song-Ming times inform us of a divergence
in economic performances between the two eras. The market economy was never wiped
out of daily life in the early Ming, and became vigorous again in the sixteenth-century
34
Lower Yangtze delta and some other coastal regions; however, the Song market economy
was unparalleled in terms of the annual growth rate in population, the rising price level
and the volume of money in circulation. In addition, my speculation suggests a more
optimistic view of the Qing monetary economy and, in turn, a rather pessimistic one of
the Ming economy, even though the late Ming case remains uncertain. In other words, if
changes in prices and money supply can denote the long-term trend in real economy, then
one can tentatively conclude that the monetary economy expanded astoundingly in the
late eleventh and twelfth centuries with increases in population growth, aggregate
demands and monetary payments, and that this expansion did not occur again until the
eighteenth century. Between the two periods, the Chinese economy encountered a longterm stagnation if not a total decline. In response to all these factors, one would expect
changes in living standards (esp. real wages) to appear during Song-Ming times as well.
The following analysis will investigate whether changes in real wages occurred and how,
if they did, they could be related to other changes over Song-Ming times. In contrast to
choosing unskilled laborers’ real wages, I will use soldiers’ real wages for a comparison
of living standards.62
I have converted wage data into an index of real wages for comparison. The index
clearly indicates a continuous decline in real wages over seven and a half centuries (see
Appendix A). In other words, the soldiers in Song were paid much better than those in
Ming: the soldiers in Song China prior to 1125 received payments 1-2.5 times higher than
their counterparts in Ming. In the Southern Song (1127-1279), because of the severe
inflation, their payments were just fifty to eighty percent higher than those made to early
62
For the discussion on the way of adopting the wage of unskilled labors as the alternative standard for real income per
capita and why the soldiers’ wage can be used in particular, see Appendix A.
35
Ming soldiers --and probably no higher than that of the Ming soldiers when the latter
were better paid in the mid-sixteenth century. During the first hundred years of the Song
dynasty (960-1060), the soldiers’ wages came to a peak in real terms, and then went down
to a monthly pay of fewer than 300 liters per head. In the century beginning from the
1150s, wages were even lower, ranging between 200 and 100 liters per head.
Besides the index of real wages based on the data from soldiers’ wages, I also find
support for my argument in the research on both Song and Ming military systems and
policies by other scholars. Policies in the recruitment and payment of soldiers are far less
responsive to temporal and situational variance as compared to the wage data.
Nonetheless, they can reveal the base of military expenses, especially soldiers’ wages,
and by what means those expenses and payments could be accomplished.
The Song soldiers’ wages depended on their ranks and skills. As noted before, the
wages of the soldiers in the Song armies usually comprised three parts: cash, rice, and a
clothing allowance in spring and winter. The first two were paid monthly, and the latter
was often converted into cash and paid biannually. A middle-level soldier serving in the
central armies was, each month, paid 2.5 Song shi (125.6 kg) in rice and 500-700 wen in
cash together with an annual compensation of 6 bolts of silk, 0.5 kg of cotton in addition
to 3,000 wen of bronze coins.63 Leaving aside the clothing allowance in order to make the
comparison with the Ming soldiers convenient (about 6000 wen of bronze coins
altogether, which was larger than that of Ming soldiers64), these wages can be converted
into 176-186 kg or 235-248 liters of threshed rice.65 The above estimate is for a soldier
63
Wang Zengyu, 1983, 216-9.
For the Ming soldiers’ clothe pension, see Appendix A.
65
I adopt the prices at the Capital Kaifeng in the Xining Reign (1068-77), usually 1 bolt silk equals 1,000 wen bronze
coins, 1 Song shi 1,000 wen. 1 Song shi rice in other regions 1 Song shi would be lower than in the apital, ranging from
64
36
stationed at Kaifeng, the Song capital. The Song central armies (jinjun) at the beginning
of the eleventh century had 660,000 soldiers, about 3.5 per cent of whom were stationed
at the capital. A soldier serving in other regions enjoyed as much as 6-15 per cent of extra
grain owing to the lower price of rice in relation to the monetary part of his payment. For
soldiers in local troops (xiangjun), they received monthly payments of 2 Song shi of rice,
100 wen in cash, and an annual clothing allowance of 4 bolts of silks plus 2,000 wen in
cash.66 If it is a soldier living in North China, this would be converted to be 143 kg or 191
liters of rice.
Since the Song central government moved to the south in the mid-twelfth century,
soldiers’ salaries were adjusted. The cash part increased proportionately: a soldier in the
central armies would be paid monthly with 3,000-9,000 wen in cash, 0.9-1.5 Song shi of
rice, with or without a clothing allowance.67 Leaving aside the clothing allowance, in the
mid-twelfth century a soldier in the central armies stationed in the Lower Yangtze Delta
would be paid in real wages about 105.5-256.3 kg, or 141-342 liters of rice. In general,
the armies in the Southern Song still maintained real wages at an average level of 120150 liters of rice. This was lower than the salary of the soldiers in the Northern Song,
which was about 200-240 liters of rice.68
This estimate essentially matches the wage data presented before. But the latter gives
both some higher and lower records departing from this standard as well.
The salary of the Ming soldiers is less studied than that of the Song. In an edict of
1379, Zhu Yuanzhang, the first emperor of the Ming ordered that a soldier with a family
500-700 wen. also equals to 0.67 shi. 1 shi is the basic unit of traditional Chinese volume measure, equals to 100 liters.
1 shi rice weights 150 catties (jin), or 75 kg.
66
Song History, juan 194, military section.
67
Wang, Zengyu, 1983, 220-4.
68
For a detailed discussion, see Appendix A.
37
should be paid 1 shi of rice per month, a single soldier 0.60 shi. This rule continued
through the Ming. 1 shi has been taken as the standard monthly payment of the soldiers in
the Ming armies, which can be converted into 75 kg, or 100 liters, of rice. Although many
scholars choose this standard, I must emphasize that it should be viewed as the ideal
standard according to the policy, not the real wage in general. From a financial
perspective, the Ming military system was basically self-sustaining, as over half of the
soldiers were sent to farm in order to procure enough food. The early Ming armies
probably had 2.76 million soldiers at full strength, and if seven-tenths were engaged in
farming, it would be equal to 1.93 million agricultural laborers.69 Many contemporary
descriptions show that soldiers were paid below this ideal standard in the late-fourteenth
and fifteenth centuries. The de facto decline in soldiers’ wages became noticeable in the
early fifteenth century, especially in the Yongle Reign (1403-24) under Emperor Zhu Di.
After Zhu Di usurped the throne, he moved the capital from Nanjing to Beijing, which
had been a major military base on the northern frontier and which was located thousands
of miles away from the central regions of the Ming economy. Sharply increased costs in
long-distance transportation made the grain supply problem even worse. As recorded in
the data, the soldiers and artisans who were enlisted to build the palaces and
infrastructure at Beijing were paid 0.4-0.6 shi (40-60 liters) of rice per month.70 In the
succeeding reigns, such as Hongxi (1425), Xuande (1426-35) and Zhengtong (1436-49),
69
According to the military section in Ming History, the military guard (Wei) in the late fourteenth century was
increased as many as 493, each guard had 5,600 soldiers at its full length. Supposing all the guards were in full size,
which is quite possible at the beginning of the Ming system, then the soldiers in the Ming troops would be 2.76 million.
Although this is a large number, it only includes the soldiers, not all the people involved in or regulated by the military
institutions, including the relatives, the households registered as military professions, and the reserves. Cao Shuji has
estimated the population in the military system was about 6.2 million, about 8.5 per cent of the total population in early
Ming. (Cao Shuji, 2000a, 247).
70
According to Hucker, the base pay of a Ming soldier in a guard was one bushel, thus 36.4 liters, of grain per month.
Hucker also believes all clothing, weapons, and equipment were provided by the government, which I doubt was the
case (Hucker, 1998, 67).
38
wages were often adjusted in many regions but remained lower than 1 shi.
In fact, the drop in soldiers’ pay was less obvious than the reports disclosed, and from
the Ming official view, wages were not declining at all because of the adoption of the
wage-compensation approach. From high-rank officials in the Ming central government
down to soldiers and artisans at camps, their wages were normally measured in rice units.
However, the payments were often made in more than one form, including clothing,
millet, and even cinnamon. Nonetheless, the normal means available through the wagecompensation approach was paper currency. The Ming state continued to issue paper
currency as the preceding dynasties had, and often used it as the means of payment for
officials, soldiers and merchants. However, the new paper notes, known as Daming
Baochao, had no reserves to back their value, and were disfavored by society. When the
Ming state in the Yongle Reign began to issue enormous quantities of paper notes, far
more than its yearly revenues, the real value of the Ming paper currency was soon
debased to 1/30 of its nominal value, 1/100 in the Zhengtong Reign, 1/500 in the Jingtai
Reign (1450-6) and 1/1,000 later. Regardless of the severe inflation, the Ming
government insisted the compensation (non-grain) part of the officials and soldiers’
salaries should be paid with paper currency at its nominal value. Thus, the income of
soldiers in fact depended upon the exchange value of the compensation part, and it is also
true that the Ming soldiers’ salary before the sixteenth century could hardly exceed 1.0
shi of rice per month, surely below the ideal standard set up by the first Ming emperor.
We have already seen that, within this payment system, not only the income of the
soldiers but also that of officials was eroded. In fact, the compensation policy was
particularly harsh on officials. Ming officials at the very beginning enjoyed a salary much
39
lower than that of their counterparts in Song China. A low-ranking Ming official, for
instance, was paid about 8 shi per month. A Song official at the corresponding level was
paid monthly about 7,000 wen in cash, or 10.3 shi (1030 liters) of rice in real wages;
besides that, he would have received different kinds of allowances and compensations no
less than his regular salary.71 However, a Ming official really received only 5.5 shi of rice,
with the other part being paid in paper notes. Later, Zhu Di made the policy stricter: for
low-ranking officials, 40 per cent of the salary would be paid in rice, and for high-ranking
as well as middle-ranking officials 30 per cent. Hence lower ranking officials were paid
only 3.2 shi (320 liters) per month, just 15-31 per cent of the salary of a Song official of
similar rank.
The pay of Ming officials and soldiers shed light on the idea of a standard wage in a
non-market economy. In pursuit of security, the early Ming government diminished the
influence of the market economy and solely relied upon direct control of population and
resources. Wages were not decided by labor supply and demand. Modern surveys of
prices and wages in the early Ming, including the present one, depend greatly upon
government-regulated prices and wages in official documents, which only came to be
recorded when policy changed. Thus, in data on both grain prices and soldiers’ wages the
records shows a very stable, and even motionless, trend for over a century. No doubt
there was an underground economy. The officials and soldiers in the troops stationed at
Suzhou and Songjiang, for instance, were reported to involve themselves in illegal
businesses such as salt smuggling and the sale of military equipment. And outbursts of
the so-called Japanese pirates along the coastal areas in southern China in the midsixteenth century were initially attributed to long-standing sea smuggling, which
71
Peng, 1965, 408, 674-5.
40
eventually dislodged the official prohibition of foreign trade that had been in place for
over two hundred years. However, it is impossible to combine incomes from the two
parts, the regulated part and the part from the illegal sources, into a real one.72 In general,
I believe, the low efficiency of the Ming administration and the failure of monetary
policy worsened the living standard of the common families in the fourteenth and
fifteenth centuries.
The next question is about the wages of the Ming soldiers since the sixteenth century.
Following the Single—Whip Reform (yitiao bianfa), except for the grain tax that was still
to be transferred directly to Beijing and the other administrative centers, the Ming
government permitted people to pay silver in place of labor service. Even the army
recruited soldiers from local society by paying cash monthly, and the percentage of these
recruits may have been as high as 70 per cent in some armies of the Lower Yangtze
Delta.73 By the end of the sixteenth century, the Ming court had to send 3,800,000 taels
(i.e., 190 tons) of silver to cover the salaries of the troops at the northern frontier, which
exhausted all state reserves. The wage data shows that soldiers did benefit from this pay
reform, especially in the Jiajing Reign (1522-1566), but it was not enough to catch up
with the wage level of Song soldiers before the mid-twelfth century. The payment at that
time for a soldier was 0.6-0.8 tael of silver per month. Given that the rice price swung
between 0.5-0.94 tael of silver per shi of rice, the real wage could hardly have exceeded
1.0 shi of rice by much.74 Monthly pay above 1 tael was issued only along the northern
72
A similar challenge comes from the study of the average incomes in communist China until the beginning of
reformation era in the late 1980s. Except for the fixed salary and housing regulated at a national standard, decided by
high officials at Beijing, one can hardly estimate how much a person could make good for himself by exploiting the
government resources.
73
Fan Zhongyi, 1998, 130.
74
Huang Miantang reports that the average rice price in the Lower Yangtze Delta in the mid-Ming was 0.5 tael, while
Quan estimates 0.94 tael for the mid- and late-Ming altogether (Huang Miantang, 1985, 355).
41
frontier, especially to those carefully selected soldiers at the Nine Guards (Jiubian). In the
mid-seventeenth century, the salary of a soldier stationed on the border of Manchuria had
risen to 2 taels per month.75 However, the northern frontier in Ming was a line dividing
the nomadic life and agricultural settlements and was surrounded by the mountains,
deserts and barren land. Food and material had to be conveyed from afar at a very high
cost. According to Quan, the grain price on the northern frontier rose about nine times in
the near 200 years after the mid-fifteenth century.76 This price inflation far exceeded the
increase in the soldiers’ wages and, in many cases, one finds that the soldiers sold
weapons, clothes, and even their children and wives, in order to make a living. The origin
of the great rebellion in late Ming is the failure of the Ming fiscal system to support its
troops along the northern frontier, which caused mobs of suffering soldiers to turn against
the government.
5. Estimates on national income in pre-industrial China
Changes in national income in pre-industrial China concern us in several important
ways. They can indicate the dependence (or independence) of change in the economy
from change in aggregate population. The increase in population, for instance, might lead
to an expansion of the economy, but without an increase in real income per capita; or, as
was the case during the Tang-Song transition, the increase in real income per capita could
occur along with an increase in population over a long period. One can identify the latter
type, as Jones does in his comparative study, as intensive growth. It also helps us to
75
76
Liang Miaotai, 1997, 46.
Quan, 1967d, 678.
42
discern structural change in a market economy, since national income directs both the
supply and the demand side. The variance in national income between Song and Ming,
for instance, would shed light on the differences in demand patterns if changes in
population cannot account for the variance alone. This will provide many insights for the
study of aggregate demand in a pre-industrial society.
5.1. Estimates of national income: 1120-1776
The study in Section 1 and 2 raises the subject of national income.
The
comparison of the monetary economy in Song, Ming and Qing China has provided an
idea of the monetary size of the economies. With the price data, one can speculate on
national income for the three dynasties. The results are displayed in Table 6.
Table 6. National income in Song, Ming and Qing China*
Song (1120)
M
Va
Pb
193.4-262
1
366
Tc
I
1-1.35
0.61-0.71
(0.53-0.72)
Ming (1550)
46.5-71.5
1
165
0.53-0.81
0.27-0.68
(0.28-0.43)
Ming (1600)
124-145
1
203
1.15-1.33
0.58-1.11
(0.61-0.71)
Qing (1776)
376-400d
1
458
1.55-1.64
0.50-0.53
(0.82-0.87)
*M= money supply, V= Velocity of money in circulation, P= average price level, T= transactions in
total.
a. For convenience, I assume V remains constant over time.
b. I use the index of grain prices here; the grain price in 961-970 is 100.
c. The figures in this column are those of relative value—indicating the degree of transactions in
total depending upon the other variables: M, V and Figures in brackets are arithmetical values
from the calculation T=MV/ I chose the Song figure 0.53 as 1 for convenience of comparison.
Thus, 1.55-1.64 in the last row stands for 1.55-1.66 times the bottom value (0.53) of the Song
estimates.
d. I use the figure of 1750 here.
43
If one looks at T (transactions in total), the variance becomes much smaller than it
appeared in the money supply. This decrease can be attributed to the relative low price
level in the Ming, which certainly gives weight to national income in real terms. However,
the estimates of Ming national income diverge greatly owing to varying selection of years
for measurement. The same problem exists, one remembers, in estimating the money
supply in late Ming. In comparison, national income in the Song and Qing are wellgrounded estimates.
5.2. Estimates of real income per capita: 1120-1776
Changes in real income per capita is another concern here. One may recall the
estimates of the population over time in Section 1: the populations stood at about 120
million in the 1120s, 120—200 million around the late sixteenth century, and 311 million
in 1776. Simply dividing the values in the T column by these figures respectively, one
will get the results in Column I. Once again, the values in 1600 are unusually high—even
the bottom value is higher than that in 1776—and only a little lower than that of Song.
The top value in 1600 is in fact the highest among those figures: it is about 50 per cent
higher than that in the 1120s, and 100 per cent higher than that in 1776. The top value
means the development of the market economy in late Ming enjoyed a very slow
population growth—it would have taken more than 200 years for the Ming population to
double from 60 million in 1393 to 120 million in 1600. How Ming China could have
maintained such slow population growth so that it experienced a burst only at the last
phase of the Ming dynasty is mystery to researchers. If it is true, then it implies that, for
two centuries, the Ming economy was too backward to sustain a population as large as
44
that of Song or Qing China. In this case, the above-standard performance in late Ming
should be secured by an astoundingly slow pace in population growth rather than by an
expansion of the monetary economy. In fact, this pattern is often recognized in the
literature of economic history as a post-crisis phenomenon.
However, if we set aside the estimate for late Ming in 1600, which looks like an
outlier for the whole pattern, and is based too much, as one may recall, on speculation,
we would see a greater consistency among the remaining part. The Song and Qing cases
would point to an economic expansion that went along with a sizeable growth in
population, and a rise in prices owing to the increases in money supply and transactions.
One peculiar feature of the Song case is that, in terms of money supply and price level,
the Song economy achieved almost the same level of economic performance as the Qing
with only one-third of the Qing population in 1776. This is an unusual success in
economic growth in the pre-industrial world. Although many Chinese historians doubt the
efficacy of the application of quantitative approaches to Chinese economic history prior
to 1600, the conventional paradigm of the Tang-Song transition in Chinese historiography
agrees with quantitative research on Song economic history.
Thus far, I have discussed national income through a comparison of the monetary
economy over Song, Ming and Qing times. Much of the comparison is based on the serial
data in population, prices and money supply reported in the preceding chapter. In the
third part of this chapter I have outlined a general trend in soldiers’ wages over time.
Each is obtained from independent sources, but they are interrelated in regard to changes
in real income per capita. Conjectures from the two perspectives mostly match-- except
for the optimistic and speculative estimate of the late Ming case in 1600. There was no
45
sign in the documents of a rise in soldiers’ payments around 1600. They were at least no
higher than that in 1550s, if not lower.
Another problem concerns the soldiers’ payments in the Qing. The current wage
data on soldiers pays less attention to payments in Qing, because the present research is
targeted at comparing Song and Ming. Thus, only when the data on late Ming is lacking
do we need a retrospective-analysis from the point of view of the eighteenth century to
postulate what likely had happened in the preceding two centuries. Also, because the
current scholarship on the Qing economy and state has provided much useful information,
one need not start the analysis from very basic levels (such as data collection). The case
of the market economy and state in eighteenth-century China deserves independent study.
One has the chance to discover tremendous details on prices and wages from the
eighteenth century on, which permit us to look into the inequality within society and
across professions. The wage data I extract from current research provides several
examples, most of which involve non-skilled laborers in handicraft and agriculture.
Scholars have shown that, along with the rising trend in prices, the nominal wage during
most of the eighteenth century remained stable, and therefore, resulted in a decline in real
wages.77 Day laborers towards the end of the nineteenth century, according to a foreign
observer, were paid at 0.03 tael.78 This was actually pretty close to the standard nominal
wage of day laborers in the late sixteenth century; however, prices had risen dramatically
over the three centuries, which suggests a worsening living standard for commoners.
77
Song Xuwu gives a general survey on the wages for labors and craftsmen in eighteenth-century China (Song Xuwu,
1997). Also see Wu Liangkai, 1983; Hu Cheng, 2000; Cheng Chaoyong, 2003.
78
Martin Miller reports this case. See Chung-li Chang, 1962, 101.
46
5.3. The Qing Soldiers’ real wages
A little should be added regarding Qing soldiers’ wages in the seventeenth and
eighteenth centuries. The majority of Qing troops in the eighteenth century were the socalled the Green Standard (Luying) troops stationed across the country. The Eight-banner
troops, the traditional Manchu system, were responsible for safeguarding Beijing.
Soldiers in the Green Standard troops, according to Luo Ergang, totaled about 650,000.79
These soldiers were paid 0.9 tael of silver plus 0.25 shi of rice for each month. Civilian
candidates (Yuding), who also lived at military campus and would replace the soldier
when needed, were paid 0.5 tael of silver plus 0.25 shi rice per month. At the end of the
seventeenth century this would mean 2.2 shi rice or 165 kg for an ordinary soldier, and
1.25 shi rice or 93.8 kg for a civic candidate. Thus, a Qing soldier in the seventeenth
century was paid even higher than a Song soldier in a local troop in the early twelfth
century.80 As the grain price went up to 1 tael per shi rice in the early-eighteenth century
and to 1.5 tael in the mid- and late-eighteenth centuries, the real wage for a soldier would
have become 0.92-1.25 shi or 69-93.8 kg of rice. This payment would be lower than that
of a Song soldier in the thirteenth century.81 It became popular in the eighteenth century
for soldiers, many of whom had a family, to find a second job.82 As one can see, a soldier
in the Qing at his best received payment close to his counterpart in the twelfth century.
Could this be a sign that the real income per capita in the early Qing rivaled the high
79
Luo Ergang, 1945, 158.
For a soldier serving in a local troop in Northern China, then, this would be 143 kg of rice per month (see the
previous calculation). However, a soldier in Song central armies received about 180 kg of rice.
80
81
The average pay for a Song soldier in the thirteenth century can be estimated as 120-150 liters or 90-112.5 kg of rice
per month.
82
Luo Ergang, 1939, 4-6.
47
standard of the Song case in the twelfth century? A careful examination casts doubt on
this optimistic conjecture. Civil wars ended finally in 1678. In the Kangxi reign (16621722), population growth and the market economy began to recover slowly, a
phenomenon to which scholars refer as the “Kangxi Depression” or the “Seventeenthcentury Crisis”. Thus, owing to an inactive economy during the recovery rather than
being a consequence of economic growth along with increases in population and
economy, high-level real wages were caused by rather low prices. When the recovery
came to an end and the economy boomed again in the eighteenth century, it is obvious
that real wages fell much behind the rising trend in prices.
6. Conclusion
As the discussion of changes in both the real wage and in the monetary economy
points to a gap in real income per capita between the Song and post-Song eras, one could
conclude that economic performance made a breakthrough in Song China. The criteria for
the post-Song era, though indicating an expansion of the market economy, argues against
a new phase of intensive growth. To put it in quantitative terms, the variance in real
wages between China in 1120 and later, in 1771, shows a decline of about 50 per cent.
The comparison from the analysis of the monetary economy suggests it was close to 30
per cent, a decline relatively moderate but still obvious.
This view will challenge the current idea of the Chinese economy in 1500-1800,
the so-called Ming-Qing transition. As the Skinner thesis bases itself on the expansion of
rural markets, it assumes that the more rural markets appeared, the more advanced was
48
the market economy. This leads those who follow the Skinner thesis to take the MingQing as the example of full development in traditional China, since the total number of
rural markets from 1500-1800 is unmatched. However, such a linear relationship between
the number of rural markets and the development of a market economy oversimplifies the
working of a market economy.
The other major trend in the study of Ming-Qing economic history is to
exaggerate the role of agricultural development as a fundamental and single cause of the
development of the market economy in pre-industrial China. It distorts the real working
of a market economy by focusing only on the supply side, and on farm yield in
particular—or, in Marxist terms, production.83 One can agree that agriculture, or more
specifically, agricultural yield per capita, is fundamental to society and economy. But it is
short-sighted to see agriculture and even farm yield alone as the direct cause of long-term
changes across diverse dimensions. The market economy even in pre-industrial times was
complicated enough to rule out this kind of linear explanation.
In contrast, the survey of long-term changes here has to deal with income—
national income and real income per capita. I weigh the demand side more than the
supply. Wages, indirect taxes on merchandise and on monopoly goods such as tea, salt
and alcohol, were all data related to consumption. Technically, the advantage is obvious:
it is too difficult to measure the output of a pre-industrial economy. In addition, the Song
83
The Song data show a correlation in a positive way in almost all dimensions of the market economy. Nonetheless,
some scholars pick up farm yields, which show an increase in the Lower Yangtze delta in the Ming time, as a yardstick
to argue for the relative underdevelopment of the Song economy. Farm yields in the Lower Yangtze delta also
increased apparently in the eighth and ninth centuries. However, scholars still debate if the increase in farm yields was
absent in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries in the Lower Yangtze delta. Even if one takes Li Bozhong’s view, it does
not necessarily lead one to believe in the relative underdevelopment of the Song economy. The first breakthrough in
agriculture in the Lower Yangtze delta, according to Li, had occurred in a time preceding to the Song. In opposite to the
agricultural fundamentalism, changes in agriculture usually could not require an immediate response from other
dimensions simultaneously. A useful comparison is British Industrialization which saw no agricultural revolution at the
same time, but followed agricultural developments in preceding centuries.
49
data, and to certain degree the Qing data, show consistency with each other as well. But
is it possible that the variances in real income per capita shown in the comparison can be
accounted for not only by real differences in the market economy but also by how those
data were produced? A state weak in the realm of finance and taxes such as the late Ming
leaves no records helpful in indicating changes in real demand. However, it is a wellknown fact that late sixteenth century communities in the Lower Yangtze delta witnessed
the building of gardens, villas, schools and bridges and appreciated luxurious food and
clothing. Were those local projects a sign of the improvement in living standards? It could
be. To prove that, however, we need to examine numerous events recorded by local
communities and translate them in a manner appropriate to quantitative analysis.
Nonetheless, the prosperity was probably regional—a typical case occurring only in the
Lower Yangtze delta.84
Several problems may affect the accuracy of my estimates. Firstly, we have less
than sufficient information on demographic change, especially for Ming, and this is the
weakest link in the chain of the reasoning. Secondly, we should not let ourselves be
biased by dynastic divisions. It is only for convenience that I continue to use terms such
as “Song China” and “Ming China” in the estimates of real income per capita. In the first
case, the Tang-Song transition will be a more significant concept to demonstrate what
changes happened in society and economy from the tenth century through the thirteenth
century. As for the fourteenth century crisis—which I think lasted through the fifteenth
century—it marks a beginning of a new phase. Within these stages one can still find
variances by arguing for more divisions, such as the invasion of the Jurchens which
84
For the economy and society in the Lower Yangtze Delta after 1400, see Fujii, 1953-4; Fu Yiling, 1956, 1957; Fan
Shuzhi, 1990; Chen Xuewen, 1993; Li Bozhong, 1998, 2000.
50
ended Song governance in North China. But such divisions make sense only at a
secondary order.
Ecological factors, including natural disasters and epidemic diseases, also play an
important role in long-term change. Unfortunately, we have few case studies on epidemic
diseases and their impact upon local economies and communities prior to 1800. Nor can
we rely on any survey of the general trend of the outbursts of epidemic diseases. As a
variable beyond the immediate influence of human activities, they had a significant
impact on those activities. The current study of the Ming economy depends too much on
the regional case of the Lower Yangtze delta. We are left with little idea of what was
going on in North China between the fourteenth and sixteenth centuries. Was it doomed
to be backward owing to irreversible damage to the environment brought on by wars and
epidemics in the thirteenth and fourteenth centuries? 85 The answer depends on future
research. Transportation matters as well. Pre-industrial China was a land empire with
only a few waterways that could play a significant role in long-distance trade. In the Song,
however, we have ample evidence to support an obvious decline in transportation costs in
waterway transportation.86 The water way canal system centered around Kaifeng linked
many natural waterways to constitute a very developed network at a national scale.87
Comprehensive research on transportation over Song-Ming times will help us greatly in
examining the sources of economic growth in a pre-industrial economy.
The reader who keeps all these questions in mind will, I believe, find that the
estimates here are consistent, and they show the superiority of the Song economy.
85
For the study of ecological changes in northern China, see Zou Yilin, 1978, 1997. Also see Appendix C.
See Table AD-1 in Appendix C.
87
Quan, 1944; Ikeda Shizuo, 1939-40. See also the transportation section in Shiba, 1968.
86
51
Appendix A
Prices and the Money Supply
1. Peng’s index of rice prices
Although a few scholars have studied a specific dynasty’s prices, such as that of the
Song prices (960-1279), Ming prices (1378-1644) or Qing prices (1644-1912), the only
comprehensive study to cover all periods of later imperial China’s prices is Peng’s work,
A Monetary History of China.88 Peng’s and others’ data series cannot give us a detailed
account of short-term fluctuations (such as seasonal changes and regional variances) in
grain prices, because for every 3-4 years one can find only one record, which was often
not at the same site but in close proximity. Nonetheless, the general trend described by
Peng’s observation of long-term changes in prices (such as that of grain and textile goods)
has been supported by all the other data series based on a specific dynasty. But even Peng
failed to make an explicit cross-dynastic comparison that would allow us to view changes
at the different price levels from the tenth century down to the twentieth century through
a single index, and therefore, to link changes in prices to changes in the real economy.89
In order to provide such an index, I have tabulated a series of Peng’s indexes of rice
prices into a single index—the Peng index—as following.
Table AA-1. Peng’s index of rice prices, 960-1910
88
For the study of the Song prices, see Wang Shengduo (1987), Miyazawa (1998), Long Denggao (1993);
for the Ming prices, see Quan (1967), Atwell (1990, 1998), Huang Miantang (1985); for the Qing prices see
von Glahn (1996), Kishimoto (1997).
89
Peng certainly acknowledges at some places of his book the rising trend in grain prices during the TangSong transition and the extraordinarily low level of grain prices in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries.
52
Period
Index*
Price**
Period
Index
Price
961-70
100
12.39
1181-90
359
44.5
971-80
153
19.02
1191-1200
510
63.19
981-90
95
11.76
1201-10
775
96.08
991-1000
119
14.73
1211-20
367
45.56
1001-10
184
22.76
1221-30
401
49.66
1011-20
95
11.79
1231-40
306
37.9
1021-30
98
12.21
1241-50
306
37.9
1031-40
159
19.67
1251-60
305
37.83
1041-50
382
1361-70
89.7
11.12
1051-60
136
16.81
1371-80
280
34.73
1061-70
207
25.7
1381-90
140
17.35
1071-80
444
55.1
1391-1400
105
13.02
1081-90
260
32.25
1401-10
85.4
10.59
1091-110
283
35.04
1411-20
*
*
1101-10
481
59.61
1421-30
104
12.87
1111-20
366
45.37
1431-40
78
9.63
1121-30
2141
265.42
1441-50
84
10.41
1131-40
1960
243
1451-60
100
12.38
1141-50
243
30.18
1461-70
122
15.07
1151-60
346
42.84
1471-80
124
15.33
1161-70
355
44.05
1481-90
148
18.39
1171-80
297
36.81
1491-1500
47.33
53
180
22.31
1501-10
172
21.3
1731-40
301
37.37
1511-20
144
17.83
1741-50
344
42.69
1521-30
162
20.14
1751-60
493
61.06
1531-40
172
21.3
1761-70
518
64.22
1541-50
165
20.48
1771-80
458
56.75
1551-60
184
22.75
1781-90
484
60.01
1561-70
182
22.6
1791-1800
1571-80
159
19.66
1801-10
654
81.13
1581-90
203
25.18
1811-20
647
80.19
1591-1600
203
25.22
1821-30
584
72.44
1601-10
215
26.6
1831-40
728
90.19
1611-20
182
22.57
1841-50
679
84.13
1621-30
293
36.37
1851-60
514
63.72
1631-40
271
33.57
1861-70
789
97.84
1641-50
380
47.11
1871-80
523
64.88
1651-60
361
44.81
1881-90
468
58.04
1661-70
258
31.94
1891-1900
1671-80
196
24.31
1901-10
1681-90
260
32.22
1691-1700
223
27.5
1701-10
290
36.01
1711-20
279
34.53
1721-30
265
32.84
54
591
73.28
724
89.72
1172
145.28
Sources: Peng, 1965, 505, 705, .498; 850.
*Index: 961-70=100.
**The price is rice per hectoliter in gram of silver in silver value. The Song rice prices are reported by
Peng in silver-tale, and I convert them into silver-gram at the rate: 1 tale of silver weighs 37.68 g.
In the Peng index (Table AA-1) the price of 961-970 is set at 100, it is apparent that
the Song grain price gradually climbed up to 200 over nearly a hundred years. By the
beginning of the thirteenth century, it had risen to 3.5-4 times the early Song grain price.
During the three centuries, Song rice prices continuously rose to 4-5 times that in preSong times. However, the long upward trend in prices came to an end in the late
fourteenth century. During the Ming, prices moved in the opposite direction. The Peng
index demonstrates that, by the early Ming time, it had almost returned to the original
low level of the mid-tenth century. Yet it was not the lowest point—grain prices bottomed
out in the first half of the fifteenth century. Not until the mid-sixteenth century did the
grain price reach 250. And it was only in the second quarter of the eighteenth century that
the grain price attained the highest level in the Song grain prices. The two peaks were
five hundred years apart.
2. Estimates of the amount of Song coins and the Ming money supply before 1550
By the Fisher Equation, changes in prices are expected to be closely related two other
variables at the macro-level: money supply and population. If changes in money supply
vary, for instance, much greater than demographic change, then, much of the gap between
the Song and the early Ming prices, should be defined as changes in nominal prices, and
need to be adjusted for inflation. Meanwhile, a decline in aggregate population could be a
consequence of the crisis of the real economy, which in turn indicates a real decline in
55
living standards and a shrinking of the size of the market economy. Therefore, the
emergence of the two price regimes, the Tang-Song and the Ming-Qing, should be further
examined under the highlights of changes in both money supply and population over the
Song-Ming-Qing time.
But I will focus on changes in money supply over the Song-Ming transition.90 A few
questions concern the estimates of money supply. First, one have to make sure the means
of exchange between the different periods must be comparable before making any
comparison; secondly, was there disparity of the circulation of money between the Song
and Ming? This will shift our focus from the amount of money supply to the circulation
of money, which is certainly more indicative of the total volume of traded goods made in
a specific period. If holders of the money in the Song time, for instance, were likely to
keep money, then, the total volume of trade would be smaller than what one can expect
about. Under such a circumstance, aggregate demand also tended to be constrained.
I can only attempt to tackle the first question here. There are several hints to the
second question. In terms of per capita head money supply, the Song consumers had more
money than those in the Ming-Qing time until the nineteenth century. Although
contemporary opinions in the eleventh-century contemporary often complained the
scarcity of bronze coins, and the dearth of money (qianhuang 錢荒) was heard in many
local communities, it was the period that the Song court produced the largest amount of
coins ever in Chinese history.91 Such a paradox between the Song money circulation and
90
The central point with regard to demographic change is that, there was an overall decline for
demographic changes during the Song-Ming transition. It is a widely accepted that the early Ming suffered
a huge loss in population due to wars and natural disasters.
91
For the dearth of money, see Hino, 1935, 1936, reprinted in 1983, 367-77, 443-7; Gao Chongming, 2000,
333-44.
56
money supply implies an extraordinary size of the Song economy, thus money demand
must be huge then. This will in turn push Song money-holders to spend faster than what
one can usually expect for a pre-industrial economy. However, I will assume at this
moment that the velocity of money remained constant between the Song and Ming to
make the comparison earlier to conduct.
The first question points to a variety of means of exchanges during the Song-Ming
time. The Song state can be viewed as a regime with active monetary policy. Precious
metals such as gold and silver, and the bronze coins produced by the imperial mints
would account for the major body of money in circulation. In addition, bills of exchange
(feiqian 飛錢 or bianqian 便錢) began to be widely used in the tenth century and later the
government initiated paper money in the twelfth century. The Ming state continued to
issue paper money (baochao), but only ended up with hyperinflation that caused the
baochao worthless in transactions. This gave rise to the using of silver and bronze coins
for exchange.
To make a conservative estimate of the Song money supply, I will only include
bronze coins produced by the imperial mints. This will severely downplay the total
amount of Song China’s money supply, since I include both silver and bronze coins in my
estimates of money supply in the Ming. In fact, silver output in Song was much more
than Ming China’s domestic output. However, even so, the conclusion drawn later from
in this comparison demonstrates that the total amount of money supply in the Song far
exceeded that of the Ming.
Hino has collected the data on Song imperial coinage. The Song imperial mints for
bronze coins amounted to 19 in the late eleventh century. The average amount of yearly
57
minted coins is displayed in Table AA-2.
Table AA-2. Average minted coins per year, 995-1119
(000,000 strings)
Year
Amount
Year
Amount
Year
Amount
995
0.8
1021
1.05
1077
3.73
1000
1.25
1030
1.00
1080
5.06
1007
1.83
1050
1.46
1105
2.89
1015
1.25
1065
1.70
1119
3.00
Source: Hino, 1936, in HKTSR, Vol.6, 345.
The production of the imperial mints in fact depended upon the sufficient supply of
the metals, especially copper and tin. Hino also surveyed the yearly output of copper The
production of the imperial mints in fact depended upon the sufficient supply of the metals,
especially copper and tin. Hino also surveyed the yearly output of copper controlled by
the Song state, and found that there was a very small margin between the reported copper
output and average amount of yearly minted coins.92 Therefore, the imperial mints could
maintain their production at full scale. Based on Hino’s estimates of average yearly
minted coins, Gao Congming multiplied them by years to get the amounts for different
periods.
Table AA-3. The amount of minted bronze coins, 995-1119
(000,000 strings)
92
Period
Amount
Period
Amount
976-82
0.49
1016-48
33.0
983-96
4.20
1049-73
40.0
997-999
2.40
1074-85
54.0
1000-15
18.75
1086-1125
109.20
Hino, 1936, in HKTSR, Vol.6, 357-666.
58
Total:
262.04
Source: Gao Congming, 2000, 103.
I also estimate the total amount of the bronze coins produced by the Song imperial
mints based on Peng’s data. Peng collects 16 figures of yearly imperial minting output for
15 reigns.93 I multiply them by the years of each reign, and the sum is 193.4 million
strings. This estimate could be underestimated, either because I exclude iron coins, which
had been officially minted and circulated in several regions in the Song, or because of the
years (94 years from 15 reigns) taken into account here comprised of only 64 per cent of
the total years in the Song prior to 1127. However, the figures show a significant increase
in coin minting in the early twelfth century, the New Policy era; the mints had produced
106.8 million strings bronze coins.94 This aggregate figure would exceed all of the Song
coins minted before. Peng estimates the total amount of the bronze coins produced by
Song imperial mints prior to 1127 was 140-150 million strings, and if including privatelyminted coins and coins produced by previous dynasties, the size of Song money supply
would reach 250-260 million.95
Either of the two figures, Gao Congming’s estimates and mine, can be hardly taken
as the real output of Song bronze coins, but they indicate a spectrum within which the
real output could probably fall in. In considering other means of exchanges in circulation
such as paper notes, silver and gold, iron coins, Song money supply would at least reach
Peng’s estimates, thus, 250-60 million strings.
The Ming imperial minting went into decline: it is usually thought to have produced
only a small number of coins in the late imperial history. The government was neither
93
Peng, 1965, 451.
The annual minting output during the New Policy period is given by Peng (Ibid, 401-2, 416).
95
Ibid, 451.
94
59
willing nor able to produce a large amount of coinage. The peak number of coins
annually produced in the early Ming period was about 0.22 million string in 1372, which
was only 4.3 per cent of the Song annual production in the 1070s. It is estimated that, for
the first 174 years, the average annual output was less than 35,000 strings of coins.96 As
the “monetary contraction” became so apparent, the Ming governments had made no
serious attempt to resolve coin dearth in the economy: for the century between the 1430s
and the late fifteenth century there was only a few official minting if not at all. The
Jiajing reign (1522-1566) launched new attempts to regulate the circulation of coins,
which had been then dominated by counterfeiting and coins from previous dynasties, by
opening up new mints in Beijing, Yunnan and other provinces. It turned out only a little
increase in coin output. It is estimated that for the first 174 years the average annual
output of was less than 35,000 strings.
This would add up to 4-6 million strings
altogether for the aggregate output of the Ming imperial minting from 1368 through 1572,
a figure roughly matching the annual output of the Song state in the 1080s.
However, coins, including those from previous dynasties and even counterfeiting,
were admitted to be used in small transactions by the imperial authority in most time.
Given the scarcity of the coinage from the Ming imperial mints, the majority of coins in
circulation were in fact those Song coins preserved into the day. The Ming hoarding
discovered today is without exception in possession of a large quantity of Song coins.
The special report on the hoarding in Henan, for instance, tells over ten thousands
kilograms of Song coins excavated in 3,000 sites across the whole province. 97 In
comparison the excavation of the Ming coins is much limited. For the purpose here we
96
97
Wang Yuxun, 2001, 3.
Xinyang Zhumadian qianbi faxian yu yanjiu, 10.
60
need to know how many Song coins were preserved and used again in the Ming time.
This might be found by checking the proportional size of the Song coins in excavation
sites of the Ming hoarding. It is unfortunate that no research has been carried out on the
whole quantity of the Song coins from excavation in proportion to that of the Ming coins
at the aggregate level. However, Japanese scholars have investigated hoarding sites of
Chinese coinage in late sixteenth-century Japan, and finds that the size of the Song coins
is about 10 times of the Song coins.98 Chinese coinage had been for long time used in
Japan as common currency until the mid-seventeenth century. This ration would give a
clear implication of how many Song coins in circulation along with Ming coins.
Considering that the trade between Ming China and Japan were officially either retarded
by the state monopoly or forbidden, most Chinese should flow through smuggling
channels into Japan, this probably reduced the potential inflow of Ming coins, which
were usually issued through official occasions. Thereafter I will lower the rate to be 8:1
as the normal pattern of Song coins and Ming coins in circulation over the Ming time.
However, coins, including those from previous dynasties and even counterfeit currency,
were admitted by the imperial authority to be used in small transactions most of the time.
I assume the rate of 8:1 as the normal ratio between Song and Ming coins in circulation
during the Ming dynasty. 99 This will increase the total money stock to 36-54 million
strings of coins, an amount roughly 15-27 per cent of that in the Song money supply prior
to 1125, but already far exceeding the usual expectation of bronze coins in circulation in
Ming.
In addition to coins in circulation, silver was used as a major currency. Aggregate
98
99
Ichiko, 55-61; Peng, 1965, 446-7.
For how can I reach such a ratio, see Appendix A.
61
silver output from domestic mining then, according to an optimistic view, would reach 25
million taels. A second thought will suggest 15-25 million taels silver instead. Therefore,
before significant imports of silver into China began in the late sixteenth century, the
money supply from the domestic side can be estimated to be 46.5-71.5 million strings of
coins in total value:15-25 million taels of silver plus 36-54 million strings of coins.100
This figure is only half of the money supply of the Song state prior to 1043. In the
succeeding decades of the New Policies the output of coinage outstripped all that had
ever been produced previously in the Song imperial mints.101
100
I estimate 1 tael of silver as being equal to 0.7 string of coins according to the contemporary price of
coins in silver.
101
I have dismissed the preservation of silver from previous dynasties into the Ming circulation. Certainly
the Ming economy inherited certain precious metals from previous dynasties, but contrary to the case of
Song coins, precious metals such as gold and silver, because of its precious value in relatively small
volume, had more likely been transferred outside China or disappeared over nearly three centuries of wars
before the establishment of the Ming state. To make the estimate convenient, I also dismiss silver from the
Song money supply, and step still further to dismiss the potential inheritance of silver by the Ming. This
dismissal would underestimate more severely the Song money supply than it does for the Ming.
62
Bibliography
The following abbreviations are used in the bibliography:
A. Chinese sources
BJGK Beijing Tushuguan Gujizhenben Congkan《北京图书馆古籍珍本从刊》
CSJB Congshu Jicheng Chubian《丛书集成初编》
CZSJ Chongzhen Songjiang fuzhi 《崇禎松江府志》
DZLL Zhongguo Difangzhi Lianhemulu《中国地方志联合目录》
GTJ Gujin Tushu Jicheng 《古今图书集成》
HFSZ Huangming Tiaofashi Leizhuan《皇明条法事类纂》
MHD Ming Huidian《明会典》
MLAH Mingshilu leizuan: Anhui shiliaojuan《明实录类纂安徽史料卷》
MLBJ Mingshilu Beijing shiliao《明实录北京史料》
MLFT Mingshilu Fujian Tanwan Shiliaojuan《明实录类纂福建台湾史料卷》
MLJJ Mingshilu leizuan: jingji shiliaojuan《明实录类纂经济史料卷》
MLZS Mingshiluleizuan:Zhejiang Shanghaishiliaojuan《明实录类纂浙江上海史料卷》
MTZL Mingshilu: Taizu shilu《明实录,太祖实录》
QHDZ Qinding Daqing Huidian Zeli《钦定大清会典则例》. (SKQS)
SHY Song Huiyao《宋会要》MSTL
SKQS Wenyuange Siku Quanshu《文淵閣四庫全書》
SKCM Siku Quanshu Cunmu Congshu《四庫全書存目叢書》
SKJK Siku Weishoushu Jikan 《四庫未收書辑刊》
SYDF Songyuan Difangzhi Congshu 《宋元地方志叢書》
XFZM Xinfangzhi Zongmu 《新方志总目(中国社会科学院图书馆)》
ZDSJ Zhengde Songjiang Fuzhi 《正德松江府志》
ZDJX Zhongguo Difangzhi Jicheng, Xiangzhenzhi Zhuanji《中國地方志集成. 鄉鎮志專
輯》
ZDJS Zhongguo Difangzhi Jicheng, Shanghaifuxianzhi Ji《中國地方志集成.上海府縣志
輯》
ZDJJ Zhongguo Difangzhi Jicheng, Jangxuifuxianzhi Ji 《中國地方志集成.江苏府縣志
63
輯》
ZHFL Essays in Chinese Martime History 中國海洋發展史論文集. Taipei, Sun Yat-sen Institute
for Social Sciences and Philosophy, Academia Sinica.
LSYJ Lishi Yanjiu 《历史研究》. Beijing, CASS.
LSDL Lishi Dili《历史地理》. Shanghai, Fudan University.
MSYL
Mingshi Yanjiu Luncong 明史研究论丛. Beijing, Zhongguo shehuikexueyuan.
ZGSY Zhongguoshi Yanjiu 《中国史研究》. Beijing, CASS.
ZHWL Zhonghua Wenshi Luncong 中华文史论丛
ZJYJ Zhongguo Jingjishi Yanjiu 《中国经济史研究》. Beijing, CASS.
ZGNS
Zhongguo Nongshi《中国农史》
ZGSK Zhongguo Shehuikexue 《中国社会科学》. Beijing, CASS.
ZSYJ Zhongguo Shehui Jingjishi Yanjiu 《中国社会经济史研究》. Fujian, Xiamen.
B. Japanese literature
HKTSR
Hino Kaisaburo toyo shigaku ronshu 日野开三郎東洋史学論集
THGK
Toho Gakuho 東方學報
TOKK
Toyoshi kenkyu 東洋史研究
TYGH
Toyo Gakuho 東洋学報
SGZH
Shigaku zasshi 史學雑志
C. English literature
EEH Explorations in Economic History
HER Economic History Review
JEH Journal of Economic History
JAS Journal of Asian Studies
HJAS
Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies
1. Primary Resources
Anhui shengbowuguan 安徽省博物馆.Ming-Qing Huizhou shehuijing ziliaocongbian 明清徽州
社会经济资料丛编, Vol.1 Beijing, 1988.
Cao Jiaju 曹家驹. Shuomeng 说梦. In SKJK.
Chen Shunyu 陈舜俞. Duguan Ji 都官集. In SKQS.
64
Cheng Yizhong 程毅中. Song-Yuan Xiaoshaojia Huabenji 宋元小说家话本集. Shandong, 2000.
Chongxiu Fenjing xiaozhi 重修楓涇小志. In ZDJX.
Jinze xiaozhi 金澤小志. In ZDJX.
(Kangxi) Chongming Xianzhi 康熙崇明县志
Daoguang Kunxin Liangxian Zhi 道光昆新两县志
Da Yuan haiyun ji 大元海運記.
Dong Wei 董煟. Jiuhuang Huominshu 救荒活民书. In CSJB.
He Liangjun 何良俊. Siyouzai congshuo 四友齋叢說. Shanghai: Zhonghua shuju, 1959.
Hong Huanchun 洪煥椿. Mingqing Suzhou nongcun jingji ziliao 明清蘇州農村經濟資料.
Nanjing: Jingsu Guji, 1988.
Huang Zhangjian 黄彰健. Mingdai Lyuli huibian 明代律例汇编. Taipei,1979.
Jiading chicheng zhi 嘉定赤城志. In SYDF.
Jingding yanzhou xuzhi 景定严州续志. In SYDF
Li Guoxiang 李國祥. Mingshilu leizuan, Zhejiang shanghai juan 明實錄類纂. 浙江 上海卷.
Hubei: Wuhan, 1995.
Li Heng 李衡. Lean yulu 樂庵語錄. In SKQS.
Li Tao 李焘. Xu Zizhi Tongjian Changbian (XZTC) 续资治通鉴长编.
Li Yan 李埏 & Lin Wenxun 林文勋. Song-Jin Chubishi Xinian 宋金楮币史系年. Kunming, 1996.
Sanshan zhi 三山志. SYDF.
Lu Shen 陆深. Yanshan waiji 俨山外集.
Shao Hengzhen 邵亨貞. Yechu ji 野處集. In SKQS.
65
Sun Pei 孙佩. Hushu Guanzhi 浒墅关志.
Tao Zongyi 陶宗儀. Nancun Cuogen Lu 南村輟耕錄. Shanghai: Zhonghua shuju, 1959.
Wang Heming 王鶴鳴 上海圖書館藏家譜提要. Shanghai, 2000.
Wang Qi 王圻. Xu wenxian tongkao 续文献通考.
Wang Anshi 王安石. Wang Anshi quanji 王安石全集. Shanghai: Shanghai guji, 1999.
Weijing 衛涇. Houle ji 後樂集. SKQS.
Wu Lyuzhen 吴履震. Wurong Zhiyi Suibi 五茸志逸随笔. In SKJK.
Xiao Lu 肖鲁 & Cao Qinghua 曹清华. Song Zhao Qingxian gong nianpu 宋赵清献公年谱. In
Songren nianpu congkan 宋人年谱丛刊, 1293-1330. Chengdu: Sichuandaxue, 2003.
Xie Guozhen 謝國楨. Mingdai Shehui Jingji Shiliao Xuanbian 明代社會經濟史料選編 Vol. 1, 2,
3. Fujian, 1980. (MSJS)
Xie Yingfang 謝 應 芳. Guichao gao 龜巢稿. In SKQS.
Xu Guangqi 徐光啟. Nongzhen quanshu 農政全書. Shanghai: Shanghai Guji, 1979.
Xuxiu Fengjing Xiaozhi 續修楓涇小志.In ZDSJ.
Yanzhou tujing 严州图经. In SYDF.
Yang Weizhen 楊維楨. Yang Weizhen ji 楊維楨集, 傳世藏書版. Haikou: Hainan Guoji Xinwen
Chuban Zhongxin, 1995.
Wanli fuzhou fuzhi 万历福州府志. Panyilong 潘颐龙等修 ,1579. In Mingdai guben
fangzhi zhuanji 明代孤本方志专辑.
Wanli Xuxiu Yanzhou fuzhi 万历续修严州府志. In RZDC.
Wanli Yanzhou fuzhi 万历严州府志. In RZDC.
Yunjian zhi 雲間志. In SYDF.
66
Zhang Haipeng 张海鹏 & Wang Tingyuan 王廷元. Ming-Qing huishang ziliaoxuanbian 明清徽
商资料汇编. Hefei, 1985.
Zhang Zhihan 張之翰. Xiyan ji 西嚴集. In SKQS.
Zheng Yuanyou 鄭元祐. Qiaowu ji 僑吳集. In SKQS.
Zhengde jinshan weizhi 正德金山卫志.
Zhiyuan jiahe zhi 至元嘉禾志. In SYDF.
Zhongguo shehuikexueyuan lishiyanjiusuo 中国社会科学院历史研究所. Ming-Qing Huizhou
shehuijing ziliaocongbian 明清徽州社会经济资料丛编, Vol.2 Beijing, 1990.
Zhou Shaoquan 周绍泉. Doushangong jiayi jiaozhu 窦山公家议校注. Hefei, 1993.
Zhu Yuanzhang 朱元璋. 申明佛教榜册 Shenming fojiao bangce.
2. All Other Works
Allen, Robert. Enclosure and the Yeoman: The Agricultural Development of the South Midlands,
1450-1850. Cambridge, 1992.
__________. “On the road again with Arthur Young: English, Irish, and French Agriculture
during the Industrial Revolution,” JEH, vol.38, 1988, 117-25.
__________. “The two English agricultural revolutions, 1450—1850,”in B. Campbell & M.
Overton, eds., Productivity Change and Agricultural Development. (Manchester, 1991)
___________. “The great divergence: wages and prices in Europe from the Middle Ages to the
first world war,” UBC Department of Economic Discussion paper 98-12, 1998.
____________. “Agricultural output and productivity in Europe, 1300—1800,” UBC Paper, 9814.
___________. “Escaping the Malthusian trap: an econometric model of European wages in the
early modern period,” 1998.
____________. “Tracking the agricultural revolution.” Discussion Paper No.: 98-18, Department
of Economics, University of British Columbia. Vancouver, 1998.
________________. “Real wages in Europe and Asia: a first look at the long-term
patterns,”2003.
Aoyama Hakushi Koki Kinen Sodai Shi Ronso Kankokai 青山博士古稀紀念宋代史論叢刊行会
. Aoyama Hakushi Koki Kinen Sodai Shi Ronso 青山博士古稀紀念宋代史論叢. Tokyo, 1974.
67
Aoyama, Sadao 青山定雄. To-So jidai no kotsu to chishi chitu no kenkyu 唐宋時代の交通と地
誌地圖の硏究 (Study of the communication systems of the Tang and Sung China and the
development of their topographies and maps). Tokyo, 1963.
Atwell, William S. “A seventeenth-century ‘general crisis’ in East Asia?” Modern Asian Studies,
24, no.4 (1990), 68-90.
__________. “Ming China and the emerging world economy, c.1470-1650.” In The Cambridge
History of China, Vol.8, The Ming Dynasty, 1368-1644, Part II, 376-417. Cambridge, 1998.
_________. “Time, money, and the weather: Ming China and the ‘Great Depression’ of the midfifteenth century.” In JAS, Vol.61, No. 1 (February 2002), 83-113.
Aramiya Manabu 新宮學. “南京還都.” In Minshin jidai no ho to shakai 明清时代法と社会, 5990. Tokyo, 1993.
Bai Shouyi 白寿彝. “Mingdai kuangye de fazhan 明代矿业的发展.” In Zhongguo
zibenzhuyimenya wenti taolunji 中国资本主义萌芽问题讨论集, 1957, 947-93. Later reprinted in
Bai Shouyi shixue lunji 白寿彝史学论集, 1994, 84-124.
Braudel, Fernand. “The Mediterranean economy in the sixteenth century.” In Earle ed., Essays in
European Economic History, 1974.
___________. Afterthoughts on Material Civilization and Capitalism. Baltimore and London:
The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1977.
___________. The Perspective of the World. Vol.III in Civilization and capitalism, 15th-18th
Century. Harper & Row, English translation, 1986.
Brown, E. H. Phelps. “Gregory King’s notebook and the Phelps Brown-Hopkins Price Index.” In
EHR, New Series, Vol.43, No.1 (Feb., 1990), 99-103.
____________ & Hopkins, Sheila V. “Seven centuries of building wages,” Economica, New
Series, XXII, No.87, 1955.
____________.“Seven Centuries of the Prices of Consumables, Compared with Builders’ WageRates,” Economica, New Series, XXIII, No.92 1956.
Bruchey, Stuart. The Roots of American Economic Growth, 1607-1861. New York, Harper &
Row, 1965.
Buchinsky, Moshe & Polak, Ben. “The emergence of a national capital market in England, 17101880.” In JEH, Vol.53, No.1 (March, 1993).
Cao Shuji 曹树基. Zhongguo Yiminshi 中国移民史, Vol.4, Ming shiqi 明时期. Fuzhou, 1997.
__________2000a. Zhongguo Renkoushi 中国人口史, Vol.4, Ming shiqi 明时期. Shanghai,
2000.
__________2000b. Zhongguo Renkoushi 中国人口史, Vol.5, Qing shiqi 清时期. Shanghai,
2000.
Cao Songye 曹松叶. “Song-Yuan-Ming-Qing shuyuan gaikuang 宋元明书院概况”. In Guoli
Zhongshandaxue yuyanlishixue yanjiusuo zhoukan 国立中山大学语言历史学研究所周刊, Vol.
68
10, Issue 111 ( 4425-53); Vol.10, Issue 112 ( 4479-97); Vol.10, Issue 113 ( 4505-31); Vol.10
Issue 114 ( 4541-62); Vol.10, Issue 115 ( 4576-89). Guangzhou, 1929-30.
Cao Yonghe 曹永和. “Shilun Ming Taizu de haiyang jiaotong zhengce 試論明太祖的海洋交通
政策.” In ZHFL, Vol.1 (1984), 41-70.
Carus-Wilson, E.M. Essays in Economic History, Reprints edited for The Economic History
Society. 3 vols. London,1962.
Chaffee, John W. The Thorny Gates of Learning in Sung China, a social history of examinations.
New edition. New York: State University of New York press, Albany, 1995.
Chang Chung-li 张仲礼. The Chinese Gentry: Studies on Their Role in Nineteenth-century
Chinese Society. Seattle: University of Washington Press, 1955. First paperback edition, 1967.
____________. The Income of the Chinese Gentry. Seattle: University of Washington Press,
1962.
Chang, Chung-li. The Income of the Chinese Gentry. Seattle: University of Washington Press,
1962.
Chao, Kang, also see Zhao Gang (趙岡). Man and Land in Chinese History: An Economic
Analysis. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1986.
Chen Chaoyong 陈朝勇. “Qianglongchao ‘Wuliao jiazhi zheli’ zhongde wujia yu gongjia 乾隆朝
《物料价值则例》中的物价与工价.” Paper presented in The third international symposium on
ancient Chinese books and records of Science and Technology, March 31-April 2, 2003, The
Eberhard Karls University of Tuebingen, Germany.
Chen Gaohua 陈高华. "Yuandai shangshui chutan 元代商税初探." In Zhongguo shehu ikexue
yuan yanjiushengyuan xuebao 中国社会科学院研究生院学报, Vol. 97, Issue 1 (1997), 8-16.
Chen Guodong 陈国栋. “Qingdai zhongye xiamen de haishang maoyi 清代中葉廈門的海上貿易
, 1727-1833.” In ZHFL, Vol.4 (1991), 61-100.
__________. “1780-1800, Zhongxi maoyi de guanjian niandai 中西貿易的關鍵年代.” In ZHFL,
Vol.4 (1991), 61-100.
Chen Guocan & Xi Jianhua 陈国灿, 奚建华. Zhejiang Gudai Chengzhenshi Yanjiu 浙江古代城
镇史研究. Hefei, 2000.
Chen Hengli 陳恒力. Bu nongshu yanjiu 補農書研究. Beijing : Zhonghua shuju, 1958.
Chen Keng 陈铿. “Ming-Qing Fujian nongcun shichang shitan 明清福建农村市场试探.” In
ZSYJ, Issue 4 (1986).
69
Chen Shiqi 陈诗启. Mingdai guanshougongye de yanjiu 明代官手工业的研究. Hubei, 1958.
Chen Xuewen 陈学文. Mingqing shiqi hangjiahu shizhenshi yanjiu 明清时期杭嘉湖市镇史研究
. Beijing, 1993.
_________________. Mingqing shiqi Taihu liuyu shangpinjingji yushichangwangluo 明清时期
太湖流域的商 品经济与市场网络. Hangzhou, 2000.
Chen Zhichao 陈智超. “Beisong shangshui e buque 北宋商税额补缺.” In ZGSY, Vol.36, Issue 4
(1987), p.114.
Chen Zhiping 陈支平 & Lin Feng 林枫. “Mingdai wanli qianqi de shangye shuizhi yu shuie 明代
万历前期 的 商业税 制与税额.” In Ming-Qing Luncong 明清论丛, No.1 (1999), 396-413.
Cheng Minsheng 程民生. “Songdai beifang jingji jiqi diwei xintan 宋代北方经济及其地位新探
.” In ZJYJ, Vol.7, Issue 3 (1987), 17-24.
___________. Songdai diyu jingji 宋代地域经济. Henan, 1992.
Ch’u T’ung-tsu. Law and Society in Traditional China. Paris: Mouton, 1961.
Chuan Han-sheng (also see Quan Hansheng). “The Chinese silk trade with Spanish America from
the late Ming to the Mid-Ch’ing period.” In Studia Asiatica: Essays in Asian Studies in
Felicitation of the 75th Birthday of Professor Ch’en Shou-yi, ed. Laurence G. Thompson. San
Francisco, 1975, 99-117.
_________ & Richard A. Kraus. Mid-Ch’ing Rice Markets and Trade: An Essay in Price History.
Cambridge: Harvard, 1975.
Cipolla, Carlo M. Money, Prices and Civilization in the Mediterrranean World, fifth to
seventeenth centuries. Princeton University Press, 1956.
Clark, Hugh R. “Settlement, Trade and Economy in Fu-chien.” In Vermeer, Edward B. eds.
Development and Decline of Fukien Province in the 17th and 18th Centuries. Leiden, 1990.
Clark, G. “Agriculture and the Industrial Revolution, 1750-1850.” In J. Mokyr, ed., The British
Industrial Revolution: An Economic Perspective. Boulder, 227-266, 1993.
Coleman, D. C. The Economy of England, 1450-1750. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 1977.
Collins, James B. Fiscal Limits of Absolutism: Direct Taxation in Early Seventeenth-Century
France. California, 1988.
Conference on Spacial and Temporal Trends and Cycles in Chinese Economic History, 980-1980.
Papers from the Conference on Spacial and Temporal Trends and Cycles in Chinese Economic
History, 980-1980. Ballogio, Italy, 1984.
Cong Hanxiang 丛瀚香. “Shilun Mingdai mian he mian fangzhiye de fazhan 试论明代棉和棉纺
织业的发展.” ZGSY, Vol.9, Issue 1 (1981), 61-78.
70
Crafts, N. F. R. “National income estimates and the British standard of living debate: a
reappraisal of 1801-1831.” In EEH, Vol.17 (1980), 176-88.
___________. “British economic growth, 1700-1831: a review of the evidence”, EHR, Vol.36
(1983), 177-99.
___________. “Gross national product in Europe, 1879-1910: some new estimates.” In EEH,
Vol.20 (1983), 387-401.
___________. British Economic Growth during the Industrial Revolution. Oxford, 1985.
Crone, Patricia. Pre-industrial Societies. Basil Blackwell, 1989.
Crouzet, Francois, eds. Capital Formation in the Industrial Revolution. London: Methuen & Co
Ltd, 1972.
Danjo Hiroshi 檀上宽. “Shoki Min cho no tsuka seisaku 初期明王朝の通货政策.” In TOKK,
Vol.39, Issue 3 (1980), 527-56. Reprinted in Min cho sensei shihai no shiteki kozo, 115-50.
_______. “明朝專制国家と儒教的家族国家観.” In Yamane Yukio kyōju taikyū kinen Mindaishi
ronso, 1990, 5-22.
_______. Min cho sensei shihai no shiteki kozo 明朝專制支配の史的構造. Tokyo, 1995.
Dardess, John W. Confucianism and Autocracy, professional elites in the founding of the Ming
dynasty. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1983.
Daunton, M. J. Progress and Poverty: An Economic and Social History of Britain, 1700-1850.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995.
Davies, Glyn. A History of Money, from ancient times to the present day. Third edition. Cardiff:
the University of Wales Press, 2002.
De Vries, Jan. Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 1600-1750. Cambridge, 1976.
_________. European Urbanization, 1500-1800. Cambridge, 1984.
_________. “The Industrial Revolution and the Industrious Revolution.” In JEH, vol.54, Issue 2
(Jun., 1994), 249-270.
_________ & Van Der Woude. The First Modern Economy: Success, Failure, and Perseverance
of the Dutch Economy, 1500-1815. Cambridge University Press, 1997.
Deng, Gang. 1999a. Maritime sector, institutions, and sea power of premodern China. Westport:
Greenwood Press, 1999.
_______. 1999b. The premodern Chinese economy: structural equilibrium and capitalist sterility.
New York : Routledge, 1999.
Deng Guangming 邓广铭. “Beisong de mubingzhidu jiqi yu dangshi jiruo jipin he nongye
shengchan de guanxi 北宋募兵制度及其与当时积弱积贫和农业生产的关系.” In ZGSY, Issue 4
(1980), 61-77.
_________& Li Jiaju 郦家驹, ed. Songshi yanjiu lunwenji: 1982 nian nianhui biankan 宋史研究
论文集:1982 年年会编刊. Zhengzhou: Henan renmin, 1984.
71
Deng Yibing 邓亦兵. “Qingdai qianqi yanhai yunshuye de xingsheng 清代前期沿海运输业的兴
盛.” In ZSYJ, Issue 3 (1996), 40-52.
Dreyer, Edward L. Early Ming China, a political history, 1355-1435. Stanford: Standford
University Press, 1982.
Du Wenyu 杜文玉. “Tang-Song jingji shili bijiao 唐宋经济实力比较研究.” In ZJYJ, Vol.52,
Issue 4 (1998), 37-52.
Du Jiaji 杜家骥. “Qing zhongqi yiqian de zhuqianliang wenti 清中期以前的铸钱量问题.” In
Shixue jikan 史学集刊, No.1 (1999), 27-31.
Earle, Peter. Essays in European Economic History, 1500-1800. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1974.
Eastman,Lloyd E. Family, Fields, and Ancestors, constancy and change in China’s social and
economic history, 1550-1949. Oxford, 1988.
Elvin, Mark. “The high-level equilibrium trap: the causes of the decline of invention in the
traditional Chinese textile industries.” In W.E. Willimot, ed., Economic Organization in Chinese
Society. California: Stanford University Press, 1972.
_________. The Pattern of the Chinese Past. Stanford, 1973.
_________.“Why China failed to create an endogenous industrial capitalism.” In Theory &
Society 13 (1984), 7-46.
_________. “China as a counterfactual.” In J. Baechler, J. A. Hall, and M. Mann, eds., Europe
and the Rise of Capitalism. Oxford, 1988.
Esherick, Joseph W. & Rankin, Mary B. Chinese Local Elites and Patterns of Dominance.
California, 1990.
Fan Jinmin 范金民. Jiangnan Sichoushi Yanjiu 江南丝绸史研究. Beijing, 1993.
________ & Xia Weizhong. Suzhou diqu shehui jingjishi Mingqingjuan 苏州地区社会经济史(
明清卷). Nanjing: Nanjing daxue, 1993.
Fan Shuzhi 樊树志. Zhongguo fengjian tudi guanxi fazhanshi 中国封建土地关系发展史.
Beijing: Renmin, 1988.
________. Mingqing jiangnan shizhen taiwei 明清江南市镇探微. Shanghai, 1990.
Fan I-chun 范毅军. “The Study of Ming-Ch’ing market Towns in the Lower
Yangtze Delta: A Review 明清江南市场聚落史研究的回顾舆展望.” In New History
新史學, Vol.IX, No.3. Taipei, 1998.
Fan Zhongyi 范中义. “Lun Mingchao junzhi de yanbian 论明朝军制的演变.” In ZGSY, Vol.78,
Issue 2 (1998), 129-39.
72
Fang Jian 方健. “Tang-Song cha chandi he chanliang kao 唐宋茶产地和产量考.” In ZJYJ,
Vol.30, Issue 2 (1993), 71-85.
Fang Xing 方行.Qingdai nongminjingji kuodazaishengchan de xingshi 清代农民经济扩大再生
产的形式.” In ZJYJ, Vol.41, Issue 1 (1996), 32-46.
__________.“Qingdai jiangnan nongmin de xiaofei 清代江南农民的消费.” In ZJYJ, Vol.43,
Issue 3 (1996), 91-8.
__________. “Zhengque pingjia qingdai de nongyejingji 正确评价清代的农业经济.” In ZJYJ,
Vol.47, Issue3 (1997), 141-50.
__________. Zhongguo fengjian jingji lungao 中国封建经济论稿. Beijing, 2004.
__________ & Jing Junjian 经君健, Wei Jinyu 魏金玉, eds. Zhongguo jingji tongshi, Qing part
中国经济通史, 清代卷. Vol. I-III. Beijing, 2000.
Fu Yiling 傅衣凌. Mingqing shidai shangren ji shangye ziben 明清时代商人及商业资本.
Beijing, 1956.
__________. Mingdai jiangnan shimin jingji shitan 明代江南市民经济试探. Shanghai, 1957.
__________. Mingqing shehui jingji bianqian lun 明清社会经济变迁论. Beijing, 1989.
Gao Congming 高聪明. “Lun Songdai huobi liutong zhong de jige guanxi 论宋代货币流通中的
计各关系.”In ZJYJ, Vol.50, Issue 2 (1998), 89-97
________. Songdai Huobi yu Huobi Liutong Yanjiu 宋代货币与货币流通研究. Hebei, 2000.
Gates, Hill. China’ motor: A Thousand Years of Petty Capitalism. Ithaca: Cornell University
Press, 1996.
Gerschenkron, Alexander. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. New York, 1962.
________. “On the Concept of Continuity in History.” In Continuity in History and Other Essays.
Cambridge, 1968.
Ge Jianxiong 葛剑雄, Cao Shuji 曹树基 & Wu Songdi 吴松弟. Jianming Zhongguo Yiminshi 简
明中国移民史. Fuzhou, 1993.
Golas, Peter J. The Sung Wine monopoly. Cambridge: Harvard University, Ph.D thesis, 1977.
_________. “The Sung economy: how big?” In Bulletin of Sung Yuan Studies, No.20 (1988), 904.
_________. “A copper production breakthrough in the Song: the copper precipitation process.” In
Journal of Sung Yuan Studies, No.25 (1995), 154-68.
Goldsmith, Raymond W. Premodern Financial System, a historical comparative study.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987.
73
Goldstone, Jack A. “Urbanization and inflation: Lessons from the English price revolution of the
sixteenth and seventeenth centuries.” In American Journal of Sociology, Vol.89, No.5 (Mar.,
1984), 1103-42.
Gu Cheng 顾诚. “Weisuo zhidu zai Qingdai de biange 卫所制度在清代的变革.” In Beijing
Shifandaxue Xuebao 北京师范大学学报, Issue 2 (1988).
_________(1989a).“Ming diguo de jiangtu guanli tizhi 明帝国的疆土管理体制.” In LSYJ,
Vol.199, Issue 3 (1989), 135-150.
_________(1989b). “Tan Mingdai de weiji 谈明代的卫籍.” In Beijing Shifan Daxue Xuebao 北
京师范大学学报, Vol.95, Issue 5 (1989), 56-65.
__________. “Shen Wansan jiqi jiazu shiji kao 沈万三及其家族事迹考.” In LSYJ, Vol.257,
Issue 1 (1999), 66-85.
Guo Zhengzhong 郭正忠. “Nan-Song haiwai maoyi shouru jiqi zai caizhengshuifu zhong de bilu
南宋海外贸易收入极其在财政税赋中的比率.” In ZHWL, Vol.21, Issue 1 (1982), 255-69.
_______. Songdai Yanye Jingjishi 宋代盐业经济史. Beijing, 1990.
________1997a. Liangsong chengxiang shangpin jingji kaolue 两宋城乡商品经济考略. Beijing,
1997.
_______1997b. Zhongguo yanyeshi, gudaibian 中国盐业史. Beijing: Renmin, 1997.
Haeger, J. Winthrop, ed. Crisis and Prosperity in Sung China. Tucson: The University of Arizona
Press, 1975.
Hamashima, Atsutoshi 濱島敦俊. Mindai Konan noson shakai no kenkyu 明代江南農村社會の
研究. Tokyo, 1982.
_________. “Minmatsu Konan kyoshin no gutaizo-Nanjun Sho-shi ni tsuite 明末江南鄉绅の具
体像——南潯莊氏について.” In Minmatsu Shinshoki no kenkyu 明末清初期の研究, eds.
Han Rulin 韩儒林, ed. Yuanchao shi 元朝史. Beijing: Renmin, 1986.
Hartwell, Robert M. “A revolution in the Chinese iron and coal industries during the Northern
Sung, 960-1126 A.D.” In JAS, Vol.21, Number 2 (1962), 153-62.
_________. A Guide to Source of Chinese Economic History, A.D. 618-1368. Chicago:
Committee on Far Eastern Civilizations, the University of Chicago, 1964.
__________. “Markets, technology, and the structure of enterprise in the development of the
eleventh-century Chinese iron and steel industries.” In JEH, Vol.26, Issue 1 (1966), 29-58.
_________. “The evolution of the early Northern Sung monetary system, A.D. 960-1025.” In
Journal of the American Oriental Society, Vol.87, No.3 (1967), 280-9.
__________. “Demographic, Political and Social Transformation of China, 750-1550.” In HJAS
47(1982): 539-593.
74
__________. “Government Finance and the Regional Economics of China, 750-1250.” In
Conference on Spatial and Temporal Trends and Cycles in Chinese Economic History, 980-1980.
Bellagio, 1984.
__________. “The Imperial Treasuries: Finance and Power in Song China.” In the Bulletin of
Song-Yuan Studies, No.20 (1988), 18-89.
__________. “Review on Man and Land in Chinese History: An Economic Analysis.” In JAS,
Vol.47, Issue 2 (May, 1988), 355-6.
Heijdra, Martin. “The socio-economic development of rural China during the Ming.” In the
Cambridge history of China, Vol.8 (1998), 417-578.
Hicks, John. A Theory of Economic History. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1969.
Hino Kaisaburo 日野开三郎. 1935a.“Hoku-So jidai ni okeru dotetsusen no chuzogaku ni tsuite
北宋時代における銅鐵の铸造额に就いて.” In SGZH, Vol.46, Issue 1 (1935), 46-105.
__________1935b. “北宋時代の博糴に就いて.” In 歷史學研究, Vol.4-3 (1935). Late collected
in HKTSR, Vol.11, 333-63.
__________1935c.“宋代の便糴に就いて.” InTYGH, Vol.23, Issue 1 (1935). Late collected in
HKTSR, Vol.11, 365-417.
__________.“Hoku-So jidai ni okeru dotetsusen no jukyu ni tsuite 北宋時代に おける銅鐵銭の
需给に就いて.”In Rekisjigaku kenkyu 歷史學研究, Vol.6, Issue 5, 6, 7, 482-510, 663-85, 79198, 1936-7.
__________. “五代.北宋の歳幣. 歳赐と財政—五代.北宋歳幣. 歳赐考第二章.” In 東洋史學,
Vol.6 (1952:12). Late collected in HKTSR, Vol.10, 415-440. Tokyo, 1984.
_________. “銀绢の需給上見た五代.北宋の歳幣. 歳赐.” In TYGH, Vol.35, Issue 1-2
(1952:9,12). In 東洋史學, Vol.6 (1952:12). Late collected in HKTSR, Vol.10, 441-500. Tokyo,
1984.
_________. To Gudai no kahei to kinyu 唐五代の貨幣と金融. In HKTSR, Vol.5. Tokyo, 1982.
_________. Sodai no kahei to kinyu 宋代の貨幣と金融. In HKTSR, Vol.6-7. Tokyo, 1983.
Hisayuki Miyakawa. “An outline of the Naito Hypothesis and its effects on Japanese studies on
China.” In Far Eastern Quarterly, 14.4 (1955), 533-52.
Ho, Ping-ti. Studies on the population of China, 1368-1953. Cambridge: Harvard University
Press, 1959.
_______. Zhongguo huiguan shilun 中國會館史論. Taibei: Taiwan xuesheng shuju, 1966.
Hu Cheng 胡成. “Jindai jiangnan nongcun de gongjia jiqi yingxiang 近代江南农村的工价及其
影响.” In LSYJ, Vol.268, Issue 6 (2000), 56-71.
Huang Miantang 黄冕堂. Mingshi Guanjian 明史管见. Jinan: Qilu shushe, 1985.
_________. “Mingdai wujia kaolue 明代物价考略.” In Mingshi Guanjian, 347-72.
75
_________. “Qingdai nongcun changgong zonghengtan 清代农村长工工价纵横探.” In ZJYJ,
Vol.27, Issue 3 (1992), 71-78.
Huang, Ray. Taxation and governmental finance in sixteenth-century Ming China. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1974.
__________. “Military expenditures in sixteenth century Ming China.” In Oriens Extremus, 17,
Nos 1-2 (1970), 415-49.
__________.“The Ming fiscal administration.” In the Cambridge History of China, Vol.8, 106171.
Hucker, the late Charles O. “Ming government.” In the Cambridge History of China, Vol.8, 9105.
Hymes, Robert Statesmen and Gentlemen: The Elite of Fu-chou, Chiang-his, in Northern and
Southern Sung. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986.
_________& Schirokauer, Conrad. Ordering the World: Approaches to State and Society in Sung
Dynasty China. Berkely: University of California Press, 1993.
Ihara Hiroshi 伊原弘. Chugoku kaiho no seikatsu to saiji—Egakareta Sodai no toshi seikatsu 中
国開封の生活と嵗時—描かれた宋代都市生活. Tokyo: Yamakawa shuppansha, 1991.
__________ “宋銭の重さ—中国文学にあらわれた庶民の钱.” In 歷史書通信, Vol.85 (1992).
__________. “ Toshi rinan ni okeru shinko wo sasaeta shomin no keizairyoku 都市臨安におけ
る信仰お支えた庶民の経済力.” In Komazawa daigaku zenkenkyujo nenpo 駒澤大學禅研究所
年報, Vol.5 (Mar, 1994).
__________. “Sodai taishu rinkaiken ni okeru shomin no keizairyoku to shakai 宋代台州臨海県
における庶民の経済力と社会.” In Komazawa daigaku zenkenkyujo nenpo 駒澤大學禅研究所
年報, Vol.7 (Mar, 1996).
__________. “宋代社会と銭--庶民の資産力おめぐって.” In Intriguing Asia アジア遊学,
No.18(2000), 4-18.
__________. “The Qingming shanghe tu by Zhang Zeduan, and its relation to Northern Song
society.” In Journal of Song-Yuan Studies, 31 (20001), 135-56.
Ichiko Shozo 市古尚三. Mindai Kahei Shiko 明代貨幣史. Tokyo, 1977.
Ikeda On 池田温. 中國古代物價の一考察(1) (2)—天寶元年交河郡市估案斷片お中心として .
In SGZH, Vol.77, Issue 1-2 (1968), 1-64.
Ikeda Shizuo 池田靜夫. “北宋に於ける水運の發達.” In Toa keizai kenkyu, Vol.23 (1939),
Issue 2-6, 1-40, 41-60; 48-61, 70-89, 61-74; Vol.24 (1940), Issue 1, 45-70.
Iwai, Shigeki 岩井茂樹. Chūgoku kinsei zaiseishi no kenkyū 中国近世財政史の研究. Kyoto,
2004.
76
Iwami Hiroshi 岩見宏. Studies on the Statute Labor System in the Ming Dynasty (Mindai
yoekiseido no kenkyu) 明代徭役制度の研究. Oriental Research Series, No. 39. Kyoto: Dohosha,
1986.
Iwao, Seiichi. “Kinsei nisshi boeki ni kansuru suryoteki kosatsu 近世日支貿易に關する數量的
考察.” In SGZH, Vol.62, No.11 (Nov., 1953), 981-1019.
_________. “Japanese foreign trade in the sixteenth and seventeeth centuries.” In Acta-Asiatica:
Bulletin of the Institute of Eastern CultureNo.30 (1976), 1-18.
Jiang Xidong 姜锡东. Songdai Shangye Xinyong Yanjiu 宋代商业信用研究. Hebei, 1993.
_________. Songdai shangye xinyong yanjiu 宋代商业信用研究. Beijing: Zhonghua, 2002.
Jing Junjian 经君健 & Xu Tan 许檀. “Qingdai qianqi shangshui wenti xintan 清代前期商税问题
新探.” In ZJYJ, Vol.18, Issue 2 (1990), 87-100.
Johnson, Linda Cooke. Cities of Jiangnan in Late Imperial China. Albany: State University of
New York Press, 1993.
__________. Shanghai, From Market Town to Treaty Port, 1074-1858. California, 1995.
Jones, Eric L.. The European Miracle. Environments, Economies, and Geopolitics in the History
of Europe and Asia. Second edition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 1987.
__________. Growth Recurring, Economic Change in World History. Oxford: Clarendon, 1988.
_______. “The real question about China: why was the Song economic achievement not
repeated.”In Australian Economic History Review, Vol.30, No.2 (September 1990), 5-22.
Kikuchi, Hideo 菊池英夫. “北宋時代一僻地聚落の盛衰.” In Nakamura Jihē Sensei koki kinen
Tōyō shi ronsō, 171-204.
King, Gregory. Natural and political observations and conclusions upon the state and condition
of England, in Two Tracts. Edited with an introduction by George E. Barnett. Baltimore, The
Johns Hopkins press, 1936
Kinugawa Tsuyoshi 衣川强. “宋代の俸给について—文臣官僚お中心として.” In THGK,
Vol.41 (1970), 415-66.
_________.“Kanryo to hokyu 官僚と俸给.” In THGK, Vol.42 (1971), 177-208.
_________. Songdai wenguan fengji zhidu 宋代文官俸给制度. Taipei, 1977.
Kishimoto Mio 岸本美緒. Shindai chugoku no bukka to keizai hendo 清代中國の物價と経済變
動. Tokyo, 1997.
Koiwai Hiromitsu 小岩井弘光. “南宋大軍兵士の給與錢米について--生券.熟券問题と關連し
て.” In TOKK, Vol.35, Issue 4 (1977), 87-117.
77
__________. Sodai heiseishi no kenkyu 宋代兵制史の研究. Tokyo: Kyukoshoin, 1998.
Koizumi Teizo. “The operation of Chinese junks.” In Watson, 1972, 1-14.
Kubota Katsuo 久保田和男. “宋都開封の人口数についての一试論.” In TYGH, Vol.82 Issue 2
(2000), 163-94.
Kuroki Kuniyasu 黑木國泰. “一条鞭法研究の課題と展望.” In Minshin jidai no ho to shakai 明
清时代法と社会, 593-608. Tokyo, 1993.
Kuhn, Philip, A. Origins of the Modern Chinese State. Stanford, 2002.
Kuznets, Simon. “Statistical trends and historical change.” In EHR, New series, Vol.3, Issue 3
(1951), 265-278.
____________.“The state as a unit in study of economic growth.” In JEH, Vol.11, No.1 (winter,
1951), 25-41.
_________.“National income estimates for the United States prior to 1870.” In JEH, Vol.12,
No.2 (spring, 1952), 115-130.
__________. “Problems in comparisons of economic trends”, in Kuznets eds., Economic Growth:
Brazil, India, Japan, 3-28. Durham, N.C., 1955.
_________. Modern Economic Growth: Rates, Structure and Spread. New Haven, 1966.
_________. “Modern economic growth: Findings and reflections.” In The American Economic
Review, Vol.63, Issue 3 (Jun., 1973), 247-258.
Lee, James & Wang Feng. One Quarter of Humanity: Malthusian Mythology and Chinese
Realities. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1999.
Li Bozhong 李伯重. Tangdai Jiangnan nongye de fazhan 唐代江南农业的发展. Beijing: Nonye,
1990.
______________. “Songmo zhi Mingchu Jiangnan renkou yu gengdi de bianhua, shisan-shisi
shiji Jiangnan nongye bianhua tantao zhiyi 宋末至明初江南人口与耕地的变化:十三世纪、
十四世纪江南农业变化探讨之一.” In ZGNS, Vol.16, Issue 3 (1997), 18-32.
___________(1998a). “Songmo zhi Mingchu Jiangnan nongye jishu de bianhua, shisan-shisi shiji
Jiangnan nongye bianhua tantao zhi’er 宋末至明初江南农业技术的变化:十三世纪、十四世
纪江南农业变化探讨之二.” In ZGNS, Vol.17, Issue 1 (1998), 16-24.
___________(1998b). “Songmo zhi Mingchu Jiangnan nongmin jiyingfangshi de bianhua,
shisan-shisi shiji Jiangnan nongye bianhua tantao zhisan 宋末至明初江南农民经营方式的变化
:十三世纪、十四世纪江南农业变化探讨之三.” In ZGNS, vol.17, Issue 2 (1998), 30-38.
____________(1998c). “Songmo zhi Mingchu Jiangnan nongye bianhua de tedian yu lishi diwei,
shisan-shisi shiji Jiangnan nongye bianhua tantao zhisi 宋末至明初江南农业变化的特点和历史
地位:十三世纪、十四世纪江南农业变化探讨之四.” In ZGNS, vol.17, Issue 3 (1998), 39-46.
__________(1998d). Agricultural Development in Jiangnan, 1620-1850. New Tork: St. Martin’s
Press, 1998.
78
________. “Zhongguo quanguo shichang de xingcheng 中国全国市场的形成, 1500-1840. In
Qinghua daxu xuebao, Vol.14, Issue 4 (1999), 48-54.
_________2000a. Jiangnan de zaoqi gongyehua 江南的早期工业化, 1550-1850. Beijing:
Shehuikexue wenxian, 2000.
_________2000b. “Xuanjing, jicui yu Songdai jiangnan nongye geming‘选精’、‘集萃’与‘宋代江
南农业革命’.” In ZGSK, Vol.127, Issue 1 (2000), 177-92.
____________. Fazhan yu zhiyue, Ming Qing Jiangnan shengchan li yanjiu 发展与制约,明清
江南生产力研究. Taipei, 2002.
_______2003a. “Was there a ‘fourteenth-century turning point’? population, land, technology,
and farm management.” In Smith & von Glahn, ed., The Song-Yuan-Ming Transition in Chinese
History.
_______2003b. Duoshijiao kan jiangnan jingjishi 多视角看江南经济史. Beijing: Sanlian, 2003.
Li Defu 李德甫. Mingdai Renkou Dili yu Jingji Fazhan 明代人口地理与经济发展. Kunming:
Yunnan University, Ph.D thesis, 2002.
Li Guoxiang 李國祥 & Yang Chang 楊昶. Mingshilu leizuan: jingji shiluojuan 明實錄類纂﹕經濟
史料卷. Wuhan, 1993.
Li Huarui 李华瑞. Songdai jiu di shengchan he zhengque 宋代酒的生产和征榷. Hebei, 1995.
Li Jinming 李金明. Mingdai haiwai maoyi shi 明代海外贸易史. Beijing: Zhongguo
shehuikexue, 1990.
Li Jinxiu 李锦秀.Tangdai Caizheng Shigao, Vol.I 唐代财政史稿, 上卷. Beijing, 1995.
__________. Tangdai Caizheng Shigao, Vol.II 唐代财政史稿, 下卷. Beijing, 2001.
Li Longqian 李龙潜. “Mingdai chaoguan zhidu shuping 明代钞关制度述评.” In Mingshi Yanjiu
明史研究, Vol.2 (1994), 25-43.
_______.“Mingdai shuikesi, ju he shangshui de zhengshou 明代税课司, 局和商税的征收.” In
ZJYJ, Vol.48, Issue 4 (1997), 95-118.
Li Longsheng 李隆生. “Mingmo baiyin cunliang de guji 明末白银存量的估计.” In China
Numismatics 中国钱币, Issue 1 (2005), 3-8.
Li, Ruoyu 李若愚. “Cong Mingdai de qiyue kan Mingdai de bizhi 从明代的契约看明代的币
制.” In ZJYJ, Vol.12, Issue 3 (1988), 39-43.
79
Li, Yan & Lin, Wenxun. Song Jin chubishi xinian 宋金楮币史系年. Kunming: Yunnan minzhu,
1996.
Liang, Fangzhong 梁方仲. “Mingdai guojimaoyi yu yin de shechuru 明代国际贸易与银的输出
入.” In Zhongguo shehui jingjishi jikan 中国社会经济史集刊, Vol.6, Issue 2, 1939
_________.“Mingdai yitiao bianfa nianbiao 明代一条鞭法年表”. In Lingnan Xuebao 岭南学报,
Vol.12, Issue 1 (1952), 15-49.
_______. Mingdai liangzhang zhidu 明代粮长制度. Shanghai, 1957. Reprinted in 2001.
__________. Zhongguo lidai hukou tiandi tifu tongji 中国历代户口、田地、田赋统计.
Beijing,1980.
__________. “Yuandai zhongguo shougongyeshengchan de fazhan 元代中国手工业生产的发展
.”In Zhongguo shehui jingjishi luncong 中国社会经济史论丛, Vol.2 (1982), 230-82. Later
reprinted in Liang Fangzhong Jingjishi lunwenji 梁方仲经济史论文集.
________. Liang Fangzhong Jingjishi lunwenji bubian 梁方仲经济史论文集补编. Zhengzhou:
Zhongzhou guji, 1984.
________. Liang Fangzhong Jingjishi lunwenji 梁方仲经济史论文集. Beijing, 1989.
________. “Yuandai shehui jingjishi 元代社会经济史.” In Liang Fangzhong Jingjishi
lunwenjijiyi.
_______. Liang Fangzhong Jingjishi lunwenjijiyi 梁方仲经济史论文集辑遗. Guangdong: 1990.
Liang, Keng-yao 梁庚堯. Songdai shehui jingji shi lunji 宋代社會經濟史論集(上、下), Vol.III. Taipei, 1998.
____________“Songdai Taihu pingyuan nongyeshengchan wenti de zaitantao 宋代太湖平原農
業生產問題的再檢討.” In Humanitas Taiwanica 臺大文史哲學報, Vol.54 (April 2004).
Liang, Miaotai 梁淼泰. Ming-Qing Jingdezhen chengshi jingji yanjiu 明清景德镇城市经济研究.
Nanchang: Jiangxi remin, 1991.
___________. “Mingdai jiubian de xiangshu bing guyin 明代“九边”的饷数并估银.” In ZSYJ,
Issue 4 (1994), 46-56.
___________. “Mingdai jiubian xiangzhong de zheyin yu liangcao shichang 明代“九边”饷中的
折银与粮草市场.” In ZSYJ, Issue 3 (1996), 27-39.
_________. “Mingdai jiubian de mubing 明代“九边”的募兵.” In ZSYJ, Issue 1 (1997).
Lin, Man-hung 林滿紅. “Shijie jingji yu jindai zhongguo nongyeshi 世界經濟與近代中國農業.”
In Jindai Zhongguo nongcun jingji shi lunwenji 近代中國農村經濟史論文集, 291-325, Taipei,
1990.
80
___________.“Zhongguo de bayin wanliu yu shijie de jinyin jianchan 中國的白銀外流與世界
的金銀減產”, in ZHFL (1991), 1-44.
Lindert, Peter H. “Englsih Occupations, 1670-1811.” In JEH, Vol.40, No.4 (Dec., 1980), 685-712.
____________.“English population, wages, and prices: 1541-1913.” In Journal of
Interdisciplinary History, Vol.15 (Spring, 1985), 609-634.
____________. “Why the welfare states looks like a free lunch.” Discussion Paper at Harvard
University, 18 November, 2002.
Lindert, Peter H. “Englsih Occupations, 1670-1811.” In JEH, Vol.40, No.4 (Dec., 1980), 685-712.
_________ & Williamson, Jeffrey G. “Revising England’s social tables, 1688-1812.” In EEH,
Vol.19, Issue 4 (1982), 385-408; Vol.20, Issue 1 (1983), 94-109.
Liu Miao 刘淼. Mingdai yanye jingji yanjiu 明代盐业经济研究. Guangdong, 1996
Liu Qiugen 刘秋根. Zhongguo diandang zhidushi 中国典当制度史. Shanghai: Shanghai guji,
1995.
Liu Sen 刘森. “Maipu shinian zhi wojian 买扑始年之我见.” In ZGSY, Vol.32, Issue 4(1986), 316.
_________. Song-Jin Zhibi Shi 宋金纸币史. Beijing, 1993.
_________.“Songdai de tieqian yu tie chanliang 宋代的铁钱与铁产量.” In ZJYJ, Vol.30, Issue 2
(1993), 86-90.
Liu Shiji 刘石吉. Mingqing jiangnan shizhen yanjiu 明清时代江南市镇研究. Beijing, 1987.
Liu, Ts’ui-jung & Fei, John C. H. “An analysis of the land tax burden in China, 1650-1865.” In
JEH, Vol. 37 (Issue 2), 1977.
Liu Xinyuan. “Jiang Qi Taoji zhuzuo shidai kaobian (1), (2)----Jianlun Jingdezhen Nan-Song yu
Yuandai ciqi gongyi, shichang ji shuizhi deng fangmian de chayi 蒋祈《陶记》著作时代考辩---兼记景德镇南宋与元代瓷器工艺、市场及税制等方面的差异.” In Wenshi 文史, Vol.18
(1983), 111-30; Vol.19 (1983), 97-107.
Liu, Xufeng 劉序楓. “Qing Kangxi-Qianlong jiannian yangtong de jinkou yu liutong wenti 清康
熙-乾隆年間洋銅的進口與流通問題.” In ZHFL, Vol. 7 (1999), Part I, 93-144.
Long Denggao 龙登高.“Songdai liangjia fenxi 宋代粮价分析.” In ZJYJ, Vol.29, Issue 1 (1993),
152-60.
Luan Chengxian 栾成显. Mingdai huangce yanjiu 明代黄册研究. Beijing, 1998.
Luo Ergang 罗 尔 纲 . Lyuying bingzhi 绿 营 兵 志 . Chongqing: Shangwu yinshuguan, 1945.
Reprinted in Minguo congshu, 1996.
___________. Xiangjun xinzhi. Changsha : Shang wu yin shu guan, 1939. Reprinted in Minguo
congshu, 1996.
81
Luo Lixin 罗丽馨. Shiliu, shiqi shiji shougongye di shengchan fazhan 十六十七世纪手工业的生
产发展. Taipei, 1998.
_________. “Mingdai jiangjirenshu zhi kaocha 明代匠籍人数之考察.” In Shihuo yuekan 食貨月
刊, Vol. 17, Issue 1-2 (June, 1988), 1~20.
Luo Yudong 罗玉东. Zhongguo lijin shi 中国厘金史. 2 vols. Shanghai: 1936.
Maddison, Angus. Chinese Economic Performance in the Long Run. Paris, 1998.
Maeda Naonori 前田直典. “Gencho jidai ni okeru shihei no kachi hendo 元朝時代における紙
币の價值变动.” In Maeda Naonori, Gencho shi no kenkyu 元朝史の研究. Tokyo, 1973, 107-43.
Mann, Susan. Local Merchants and the Chinese Bureaucracy, 1750-1950. Stanford: Stanford
University Press, 1987.
Mao Boke 茅伯科. Shanghai gangshi 上海港史(古近代部分). SH_ZSYC. Beijing: Renmin
jiatong, 1990.
Mathias, Peter. The Brewing Industry in England, 1700-1830. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1959.
_________. The Transformation of England: essays in the economic and social history.
London : Methuen, 1979.
_________& O’Brien, Patrick Karl. “Taxation in Britain and France, 1715-1810: a comparison of
the social and economic incidence of taxes collected for the central governments.” In Journal of
European Economic History, 5 (1976), 601-50.
Myers, Romon H. “Customary law, markets, and resources: transactions in late imperial China.”
In Ransom, Sutch, & Walton, ed., 1982, 273-98.
_________ & Sands, Barbara. “The spatial approach to Chinese history: a test.” In JAS, Vol.45,
No.4 (Aug., 1986), 721-743.
Mayhew, N. J. “Population, money supply and the velocity of circulation in England, 13001700.” In EHR, New Series, Vol.48, No.2 (May, 1995), 238-257.
Mazundar, Sucheta. Sugar and Society in China: Peasnats, techonology, and the world market.
Cambridge: Harvard University Asia Center, 1998.
Min-Shin shi ronso kankokai 明清史論叢刊行會. Nakayama Hachiro kyoju shoju kinen MinShin shi ronso 中山八郎教授頌壽記念明清史論叢. Tokyo, 1977.
Miyazaki Ichisada 宫崎市定. “宋代州県制度の由來とその特色.” In Shirin 史林, Vol.36, No.2
(July 1953). Later reprinted in MIZS, Vol.10, 216-45.
82
___________. “Mindai So-Sho chiho no shidaifu to minshu 明代蘇松地方の士大夫と民眾.” In
Shirin 史林, Vol.37, No.3 (June 1954), 1-33. Later reprinted in MIZS, Vol.13, 3-39.
____________. “洪武から永乐へ.” In TOKK, Vol.27, Issue 4 (1969). Later reprinted in MIZS,
Vol.13, 40-65.
____________. Chugokushi 中國史. Vol.1-2. Tokyo, 1977-1978. Later reprinted in MIZS, Vol.1.
Miyazawa Tomoyuki 宫澤知之. “Sodai senkin chitai no kaiso kosei 宋代先進地带の階層構
成.”In Yorei shigaku 鷹陵史学, Vol.10 (1984), 25-82.
____________. “唐より明にいたる貨幣経済の展開.” In Namamura Satoru, 1993, 185-220.
____________. State and Economy in Sung China: Finance, Market and Money 宋代中国の国
家と経済. Tokyo, 1998.
Miu Kunhe 缪坤和. Songdai Xinyong Piaoju Yanjiu 宋代信用票据研究. Kunming: Yunnan
University Press, 2002.
Momose, Hiromu 百瀬弘.“明代中国外国貿易.” (1935a). Later reprinted in Min Shin shakai
keizaishi kenkyu 明清社会経済史研究, 3-21.
_______. “明 代 の 銀 産 と 外 国 銀 に 就 い て .” (1935b). Later reprinted in Min Shin shakai
keizaishi kenkyu 明清社会経済史研究, 22-70.
________. Min Shin shakai keizaishi kenkyu 明清社会経済史研究. Tokyo, 1980.
Mote, Frederick W. & Twitchett, Denis. The Cambridge History of China, Vol.7, The Ming
Dynasty, 1368-1644, Part I. Cambridge, 1988.
_____________. The Cambridge History of China, Vol.8, The Ming Dynasty, 1368-1644, Part II.
Cambridge, 1998.
Nagai Chiaki 長井千秋. “Nanso gunpei no kyuyo 南宋軍兵の給與—kyuyogaku to kyuyo
hoshiki wo chushinni 給與额と給與方式お中心に.” In Umehara Kaoru 梅原郁 ed., Chugoku
kinsei no hosei to shakai 中國近世の法制と社會, 249-92. 1993
Nakamura, Jihe 中村治兵衛. Nakamura Jihē Sensei koki kinen Tōyō shi ronsō / Nakamura Jihē
Sensei Koki Kinen Tōyōshi Ronsō Henshū Iinkai hen, [daihyō Shimada Jōhei] 中村治兵衛先生
古稀記念・東洋史論叢 / 中村治兵衛先生古稀記念東洋史論叢編集委員会編, [代表嶋田襄
平]. Tokyo, 1986.
Nakamura, Satoru 中村哲,ed. Higashi Ajia sensei kokka to shakai, keizai 東アジア專制国家社
会
経済. Tokyo, 1993.
83
Ni Laien (Brian Moloughney) 倪来恩 & Xia Weizhong 夏维中. “Waiguo baiyin yu Ming diguo
de Bengkui: Guanyu Mingmo waiguo baiyin shuru jiqi zuoyongde xin jiantao 外国白银与明帝
国的崩溃:明末外国白银输入及其作用的新检讨.” In ZSYJ, Issue 3 (1990), 46-56.
Nishijima, Sadao 西島定生. “松江府における棉業形成過程について.” In Shakai keizai
shigaku 社會經濟史學, Vol.13, Issue 11-12 (1944). Reprinted in Nishijima Sadao Higashi
Ajiashi ronshu 西島定生東アジア史論集, vol.1, 243-50.
________. “明代における木棉の普及について.” In SGZH, vol.56-57 (1948). Reprinted in
Nishijima Sadao Higashi Ajiashi ronshu 西島定生東アジア史論集, Vol.1, 251-300.
_________. Chugoku keizaishi kenkyu 中國経済史研究. Tokyo: Tokyo daigaku, 1969.
_________. Nishijima Sadao Higashi Ajiashi ronshu 西島定生東アジア史論集. 1-5 vols.
Tokyo, 2002.
O’Brien, Patrick Karl. “Path Dependency, or Why Britain Became an Industrialized and
Urbanized Economy Long Before France”, EHR, New Series, Vol.49, Issues 2 (May, 1996), 213249.
___________. Power with Profit: the State and the Economy, 1688-1815. London, 1991.
___________. “The political economy of British taxation, 1660-1815.” In EHR, 2nd ser. XLI, I
(1988).
____________& Caglar Keyder. Economic Growth in Britain and France, 1780-1914: Two Paths
to the Twentieth Century. London: George Allen & Unwin, 1978.
Oberst, Zhihong Liang. Chinese Economic Statecraft and Economic Ideas in the Song Period
(960-1279). Ph. D thesis of Columbia University, 1996.
Okuyama, Norio 奥山憲夫. “明軍の給与支給について—正统、景泰期お中心にぃて.” In
Minshin jidai no ho to shakai, 133-153. Tokyo, 1993.
________. 明代軍政史研究. Tokyo, 2003.
Peng Xinwei 彭信威. Zhongguo Huobi Shi 中国货币史. Shanghai, 1958.
_____________. Zhongguo Huobi Shi 中国货币史. The third version. Shanghai, 1965.
_____________. A Monetary History of China (Zhongguo Huobi Shi). Vol.1, Vol.2. Trans. by
Edward H. Kaplan. Western Washington University, 1994.
Peng Zeyi 彭泽益. Zhongguo Jindai Shougongyeshi Ziliao 中国近代手工业史资料, 1840-1949.
Beijing, 1957.
_________.“Xu Yikui ‘Zigongdui’ jishi de niandai he zhiye wenti 徐一夔‘织工对’记事的年代和
织业问题”. In Zhongguo Zibenzhuyi Mengya Wenti Taolunji Xubian 中国资本主义萌芽问题讨
论集续编. Beijing, 1960.
_______ & Wang Renyun 王仁运, ed. Zhongguo yanyeshi guoji xueshu taolunhui lunwenji 中国
84
盐业史国际学术讨论会论文集. Sichuan: Sichuan renmin, 1991.
Perdue, Peter. Exhausting the Earth: State and Peasant in Hunan, 1500-1850. Cambridge:
Harvard University Press, 1987.
Perkins, Dwight H. “Government as an obstacle to industrialization: the case of eighteenth-cetury
China.” In JEH, vol.27, no.4 (1967): 478-92.
_________. Agricultural Development in China, 1368-1968. Chicago, 1969.
Pomeranz, Kenneth. The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the making of the modern world
economy. Princeton, 2000.
_________. “Beyond the East-West binary: resituating development paths in eighteenth-century
world.” In JAS, Vol.61, No.2 (May 2002), 539-90.
Postan, Michael M. “Recent trends in the accumulation of capital.” In EHR, Vol.6, No.1 (1935,
Oct.). Reprinted in Capital Formation in the Industrial Revolution, 70-83.
__________. “The rise of a monetary economy.” In EHR, Vol.14, No.2 (1944), 123-134.
Reprinted in Essays on Medieval Agriculture and General Problems of the Medieval Economy,
28-40.
_________. “Some economic evidence of declining population in the latter Middle Ages”, ECHR,
II, 1949-50. Reprinted as “Some agrarian evidences of declining population in the latter middle
ages”, in Essays on Medieval Agriculture and General Problems of the Medieval Economy, 186213.
__________. “Money, population and economic change in late medieval Europe. Note.” In EHR,
New series, Vol.12, No.1 (1959), 77-82.
__________.The Medieval Economy and Society: An Economic History of Britain in the Middle
Ages. London, 1972.
__________. Essays on Medieval Agriculture and General Problems of the Medieval Economy.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973.
Qi Xia 漆侠. Songdai Jingjishi 宋代经济史. Shanghai, 1987.
_______eds. Songshi Yanjiu Luncong 宋史研究论丛, Vol.4. Hebei, 2000.
_______& Li Yan 李埏 eds. Songshi Yanjiu Lunwenji 宋史研究论文集. Kunming, 2000.
Quan Hansheng 全漢昇. “Nansong Hangzhou de xiaofei yu waidi shangpin zhi shuru 南宋杭州
的消费与外地商品之输入.” In Zhongyang Yanjiuyuan Lishiyuyan Yanjiusuo Jikan 中央研究院
历史语言研究所集刊, Vol.7 (1936), 91-119.
__________. “Bei-Song Bianliang de shuchuru maoyi.” In Zhongyang Yanjiuyuan Lishiyuyan
Yanjiusuo Jikan, Vol.8 (1939). Later reprinted in Zhongguo jingji shi luncong, 87-200.
_________1944a. “Tang-Song wujia de biandong 唐宋物價的變動.” In Zhongyang Yanjiuyuan
Lishiyuyan Yanjiusuo Jikan, Vol.11 (1944). Later reprinted in Zhongguo jingji shi luncong, 29-86.
_______1944b. Tang-Song diguo yu yunhe 唐宋帝国与运河. Chongqing, 1944. Reprinted in
Zhongguo jingjishi yanjiu, Vol.1, 265-395.
_______1948a. “Songmo de tonghuopengzhang jiqi duiyu wujia de yingxiang 宋末的通貨膨脹
及其對於物價的影響.” In Zhongyang Yanjiuyuan Lishiyuyan Yanjiusuo Jikan 中央研究院历史
85
语言研究所集刊, Vol.10 (1948). Later reprinted in Zhongguo jingji shi luncong, 325-354.
_________1948b. “Tang-Song zhengfu suiru yu huobi jingji de guanxi 唐宋政府岁入与货币经
济的关系.” In Zhongyang yanjiuyuan shiyusuo jikan, Vol.20, 1948. Reprinted in Zhongguo
jingjishi yanjiu, Vol.1, 209-55.
__________1967a. “Song-Ming jian baiyin goumaili de biandong jiqi yuanyin 宋明间白银购买
力的变动及其原因.” In Xinya xuebao 新亚学报, Vol.8, Issue 1(1967). Reprinted in Zhongguo
jingjishi yanjiu, Vol.2, 179-208.
__________1967b. “Mingdai de yinke yu yinchan e 明代的银课与银产额.” In Xinya shuyuan
xueshu niankan 新亚书院学术年刊, Vol.9, 1967. Reprinted in Zhongguo jingjishi yanjiu, Vol.2,
209-232.
__________1967c. “Ming-Qing jian meizhou baiyin de shuru zhongguo 明清间美洲白银的输入
中国.” In Zhongguo Wenhua Yanjiusuo Xuebao 中国文化研究所学报,Vol.1, 27-49, 1967.
__________1967d. “Mingdai beibian miliang jiage de biandong 明代北边米粮价格的变动.” In
Xinya xuebao 新亚学报, Vol.9, Issue 2 (1967), 49-96. Reprinted in Zhongguo jingjishi yanjiu,
Vol.2, 261-308.
_________. Zhongguo jingji shi luncong 中國經濟史論叢. Vol.1-2. Hong Kong, 1972.
____________. “Ming-Qing shidai yunnan de yinke yu yinchan e 明清时代云南的银课与银产
额.” In Xinya xuebao 新亚学报, Vol.11 (1974), 61-88.
_____________. “Ming zhongye hou zhongri jian de siyin maoyi 明中葉后中日間的 絲銀貿
易.” In Zhongyang Yanjiuyuan Lishiyuyan Yanjiusuo Jikan 中央研究院歷史 語言研究所集刊,
Vol.55, Issue 4 (1984).
__________. Zhongguo jingjishi yanjiu 中国经济史研究. Vol.1-3. Hong Kong: Xinya yanjiusuo,
1991.
__________. “Luelun xinhanglu faxianhou de zhongguo haiwai maoyi 略論新航路發現后的中
國海外貿易.” In ZHFL, Vol.5 (1993), 1-16.
__________& Li Longhua 李龍华. “Ming zhongye hou taicang suiru yiliang de yanjiu 明中叶
后太仓岁入银两的研究.” In Zhongguo Wenhua Yanjiusuo Xuebao 中国文化研究所学报, Vol.6,
Issue 1 (1972), 169-244.
Rawski, Evelyn S. Agricultural Change and the Peasant Economy of South China. Cambridge:
Harvard University Press, 1972.
Rawski, Thomas G. Economic Growth in Prewar China. Berkeley: University of California Press,
1989.
_________& Li, Lillian M. Chinese History in Economic Perspective. California, 1992.
Reed, Bradly W. Talons and Teeth, County Clerks and Runners in the Qing Dynasty. California:
Standford University Press, 2000.
Rowe, William T. Hankow: Commerce and Society in a Changing Society. Standford: Standford
86
University Press, 1984.
___________. “Approaches to modern Chinese social history.” In Reliving the Past: the worlds of
social history, ed. Oliver Kunz, 236-96. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1985.
Rozman, Gilbert. Urban Networks in Ch’ing China and Tokugawa Japan. Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1973.
_____________. Population and Marketing Settlements in Ch’ing China. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1982.
Shiba, Yoshinobu 斯波義信. Sodai Shoyoshi Kenkyu 宋代商業史研究. Kyoto, 1968.
_________. “宋代市糴制度の沿革.” In Aoyama Hakushi Koki Kinen Sodai Shi Ronso 青山博士
古稀紀念宋代史論叢, 123-59, 1974
_________. “Agrarian and commercial changes in the Lower Yangtze: 980-1550.”In Conference
on Spatial and Temporal Trends and Cycles in Chinese Economic History, 980-1980. Bellagio,
1984.
_______. “宋代江南秋苗額考.” In 中村治兵衛先生古稀紀念東洋史論叢, 1986, 303-19.
________. Sodai konan keizaishi no kenkyu 宋代江南経済史の 研究. Kyoto, 1988.
________. “Sodai no shoshi, seisansuijun shitan 宋代の消费.生産水準試探” In Chugoku
Shigaku 中國史學, Issue.1 (Oct, 1991), 147-72.
________. “宋代の都市化お考える.” In Tohogaku 東方學, Vol.102 (2002), 1-18.
________ & Satake Yasuhiko 佐竹靖彦.So Gen jidaishi no kihong mondai 宋元時代史の基本問
題. Tokyo, 1996.
Smith, Paul J. “Commerce, agriculture, and core formation in the Upper Yangtze, 2 A.D. to
1948.”In Papers from the Conference on Spacial and Temporal Trends and Cycles in Chinese
Economic History, 980-1980, vol.2.
__________. Taxing Heaven’s Storehouse: Horses, Bureaucrats, and the Destruction of the
Sichuan Tea Industry, 1074-1224. Cambridge: Harvard University, 1991.
__________& von Glahn, Richard. The Song-Yuan-Ming Transition in Chinese History.
Cambridge: Harvard University, 2003.
Song Xuwu 宋敘五. Qingchu zhi Qianjiajian wujia ji gongzhi de biandong 清初至乾嘉間物價
及工資的變動. In Xieya xuebao 新亞學報, Vol.18 (1997), 49-98.
Steinmo, Sven. Taxation and Democracy: Swedish, British, and American Approaches to
Financing the Modern State. New Heaven, Yale University Press, 1993.
Struve, Lynn A. The Ming-Qing Conflict, 1619-1683: A Historiography and Source Guide. 1998.
Su Jilang 苏基朗 (also see So, Billy K. L.). “Songdai de huduo koushao xianxiang: dui hukou
tongji zhidu de yige fenxi 宋代的户多口少现象:对户口统计制度的一个分析.” In Tang-Song
fazhishi yanjiu.
Tang Wenji 唐文基. Mingdai fuyi zhidushi 明代赋役制度史. Beijing, 1991.
87
Terada, Takanobu 寺田隆信. “Minmatsu ni okeru gin no ryutsuryo ni tsuite—aruiwa Sho Chin no
choho ni tsuite 明末における銀の流通量について—あるいは蒋臣の鈔法.”In Tamura
hakushi shoju Toyoshi ronso 田村博士頌壽東洋史論叢, ed.
_______. The Study of Shansi Merchants 山西商人の研究:明代における商人および商業资
本. Kyoto: Toyoshi Kenkyukai, 1972.
Tilly, Charles, eds. Coercion, Capital, and European States. Oxford, 1990.
Von Glahn, Richard. Fountain of Fortune: Money and Monetary Policy in China, 1000-1700.
Berkeley: University of California Press, 1996.
___________. “Towns and temple: urban growth and decline in the Lower Yangtze Delta, 11001400.”In Smith & von Glahn, ed., The Song-Yuan-Ming Transition in Chinese History,
176-211.
Wang, Jianying 王剑英. Ming Zhongdu 明中都. Beijing, 1992.
Wang, Liangxing 王良行. “Qingmo duiwai maoyi de guanlian xiaoguo (1860-1911)清末對外貿
易的關聯效果.” In ZHFL, Vol.6 (1997), 281-347.
Wang, Shengduo 汪圣铎. “Nansong liangjia xibiao 南宋粮价细表.” In ZSYJ, Issue 3 (1985), 3852.
_____ __.“Beinan Song wujia bijiao yanjiu 北南宋物价比较研究.” In Songshi yanjiu lunwenji
宋史研究论文集, 1987, 238-54.
________. “Nan-Song gejie huizi de qiqi, shu’e ji huijia.南宋各界会子的起迄、数额及会价.”
In Wenshi 文史, Vol.25 (1985), 129-44.
_________. “Guanyu Songdai tihu de jige wenti 关于宋代亭户的几个问题.” In Peng Zeyi &
Wang Renyun, 1991, 445-462.
_________. Liang-Song caizheng shi 两宋财政史. Beijing: Zhonghua shuju, 1995.
_________. Liang-song huobi shi 两宋货币史. Vol.1-2. Beijing: 2003.
_________. Liang-song huobi shiluo huibian. Beijing: Zhonghua shuju, 2004.
Wang, Shigang 王轼刚. Changjiang hangyunshi 长江水运史. Beijing: Renminjiaotong (ZSYC),
1993.
Wang Wencheng 王文成. Songdai Baiyin Huobihua Yanjiu 宋代白银货币化研究. Kunming:
Yunnan University Press, 2001.
Wang, Yeh-chien. The land taxation in Imperial China, 1750-911. Cambridge: Harvard
University Press, 1973.
__________. “Food supply and grain prices in the Yangtze Delta in the eighteenth century.” In
88
Proceedings of the Second Conferences on Modern Chinese Economic History, 423-61. Taipei,
1979.
_________. “Spatial and Temporal Patterns of Grain Prices in China, 1740-1910.” In Paper
presented at the Conference on Spatial and Temporal Trends and Cycles in Chinese Economic
History. Bellagio, Italy, 1984.
________.“Secular Trends of Rice Prices in the Yangzi Delta, 1683-1935”, in Rawski eds.,
Chinese History in Economic Perspective.
Wang Yuesheng 王跃生. Shiba shiji zhongguo hunyin yu jiating yanjiu 十八世纪中国婚姻与家
庭研究. Beijing, 2000.
Wang Yuquan 王毓铨. Mingdai de juntun 明代的军屯. Beijing: Zhonghua shuju, 1965.
____________. “Mingchao de peihudangchai zhi 明朝的配户当差制.” In ZGSY, Vol.49, Issue 1
(1991), 24-43.
_____________, Liu Chongri 刘重日, & Zhang Xianqing 张显清, eds. Zhongguo jingji tongshi,
Ming part 中国经济通史明代卷, vol.I, II. Beijing, 2000.
Wang Yumin 王育民. “Mingdai hukou xintan 明代户口新探.” In LSDL, Vol.9 (1990), 143-54.
Wang Yuxun 王裕巽. “Mingdai baiyin guonei kaicai yu guowai liuru shu’e shikao 明代白银 国
内开采与国外流入数额试考.” In China Numismatics 中国钱币, Vol.62, Issue 3 (1998), 18-25.
_____________“Shilun Ming Zhong-hou qi de shizhu yu wujia 试论明中、后期的 私铸与物
价.” In China Numismatics 中国钱币, Vol.74, Issue 3 (2001), 18-25.
Wang Zengyu 王曾瑜. Songchao Bingzhi Chutan 宋朝兵制初探. Beijing, 1983.
__________. Songchao Jieji Jiegou 宋朝阶级结构. Hebei, 1996.
Watson, Andrew, trans. Transport in Transition: the evolution of traditionsal shipping in China.
Michigan Abstracts of Chinese and Japanese Works on Cinese History, No.3, 1972.
Wei Qingyuan 韦庆远. Mingdai huangce zhidu 明代黄册制度 . Beijing : Zhonghua shuju, 1961.
__________. “Lun mingchu dui jiangnan diqu de jingji zhengce 论明初对江南地区的经济政
策.” In MSYL, Vol.3 (1985), 23-44.
Williamson, J.G. “Unbalanced Growth, Inequality, and Regional Development: Some Lessons
from U.S. history,” in Alternatives to Confrontation. 1980.
_________.”New Views on the Impact of the French Wars on Accumulations in Britain,” HIER
Discussion Paper No.1480 (April 1980)
_________.“Why Was British Growth So Slow During the Industrial Revolution?” In JEH,
Vol.44, Issue 3 (September 1984), 687-712.
_________(1998a). “Real wages and relative factor prices around the Mediterranean basin, 1500-
89
1940.” Paper presented at the Conference on Long Run economic Change in the Mediterranean
Basin, Istanbul, Turkey, June 4-6.
_________(1998b). “Real wages and relative factor prices in the third world 1820-1940: Asia.”
HIER Discussion Paper No. 1844, Department of Economics, Harvard University, Cambridge,
Mass. (August).
Williamson, J.G & Lindert, Peter H. “English Workers’ living standards during the Industrial
Revolution: A new look.” In EHR, vol.36, 2nd series, Issue 1 (1983), 1-25.
________& O’Rourke, Kevin H. Globalization and History, the Evolution of a NineteenthCentury Atlantic Economy. The MIT Press: Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1999.
Wong, R. Bin. “The development of China’s Peasant Economy: A New Formulation of Old
Problems.” In Peasant Studies, Vol.18, Issue 1 (Fall, 1990), 5-26.
________. China Transformed: Historical Change and the Limits of European Experience. Ithaca:
Cornell University Press, 1997.
Wong, R. Bin & Will, Pierre-Etienne. Nourish the People: The State Civilian Granary System in
China, 1650-1850.Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1991.
Wrigley, E. Anthony. “Urban Growth and Agricultural Change: England and the Continent in the
Early Modern Period,” Journal of Interdisciplinary History, Vol.15, Issues 4, (Spring, 1985), 683728.
_______& Abrams, Philip, eds. Towns in societies, Essays in Economic History and Historical
Sociology. Cambridge, 1978.
Wu Chengming 吳承明. 1983a. “Lun Qingdai qianqi woguo guoneishichang 论清代前期我国国
内市场.” In LSYJ, Vol.161, Issue 1 (1983), 96-106. Later reprinted with revisons in Zhongguo de
xiandaihua, 144-66.
___________.1983b. “Lun Mingdai guonei shichang he shangrenziben 论明代国内市场和商人
资本.” In Zhongguo shehui kexueyuan jingjiyanjiusuo jikan 中国社会科学院经济研究所集刊,
Vol.5. Later reprinted with revisions in Zhongguo de xiandaihua, shichangyushehui, 111-43.
__________. “Xiandaihua yu zhongguo shiliu,shiqi shiji de xiandaihua yinsu 現代化與中國十六﹐
十七世紀的現代化因素”, in ZJYJ, Vol.52, Issue 4 (1988), 3-15.
__________. “Shiliu yu shiqi shiji de zhongguo shichang16 与 17 世纪的中国市场.” In Huozhi:
Shangye yu shichangyanjiu 货殖:商业与市场研究, Vol.1 (1995). Reprinted in Wu Chengming
Ji, 140-176.
__________. “Shiba yu shijiu shiji shangbanye de zhongguo shichang18 与 19 世纪上半叶的中
国 市 场 .” In Huozhi: Shangye yu shichangyanjiu 货 殖 : 商 业 与 市 场 研 究 , Vol.3 (1999).
Reprinted in Wu Chengming Ji, 177-228.
______. Zhongguo de xiandaihua, shichangyushehui 中国的现代化:市场与社会. Beijing:
Sanlianshudian, 2001.
________. Wu Chengming Ji 吳承明集. Beijing: Zhongguo shehuikexue, 2002.
Wu Dange 伍丹戈. “Mingdai de guantian he mintian 明代的官田和民田.” In ZHWL, Vol.9, Issue
1 (1979), 119-63.
_______. Mingdai tudi zhidu he fuyi zhidu de fazhan 明 代土 地 制 度 和赋 役 制 度 的发 展 .
90
Fujian:Fujian renmin, 1982.
________. “Mingdai Zhouchen fuyi gaige de zuoyong he yingxiang 明代周忱赋役改革的作用
和影响.” In MSYL, Vol.3 (1995), 1-22.
Wu Han 吴晗. “Mingdai de junbing 明代的军兵.”In Zhongguo shehui jingjishi jikan 中國社會經
濟史集刊, Vol.2, Issue 2 (1937 June). Reprinted in Dushi zhaji 读史札记, 92-141.
________. Dushi zhaji 读史札记. Beijing: Sanlain shudian. 1955.
________. Zhu Yuanzhang zhuan 朱元璋传.Beijing: Sanlian shudian. Reprinted in 2000.
Wu Hui 吳慧. Zhongguo lidai liangshi muchan yanjiu 中国历代粮食亩产研究. Beijing, 1985.
__________.“Mingqing(qianqi) caizheng jiegouxing bianhua de jiliang fenxi 明清(前期) 財政 結
構性變化的計量分析.” In ZSYJ, Issue 3 (1990), 39-56.
__________. “Lishishang liangshi shangpinlyu shangpinliang chegu: yi Song, Ming, Qing weili,
歷史上糧食商品率商品量測估: 以宋明清為例.” In ZJYJ, Vol.52, Issue 4 (1998), 16-36.
Wu Jihua 吳緝華. Mingdai haiyun ji yunhe de yanjiu 明代海运及运河的研究. Taipei, 1961.
_________. Mingdai shehui jingji shi luncong 明代社會經濟史論叢. Taibei: Xuesheng shuju,
1970.
Wu Liangkai 吴量恺. “Qing qianqi nongye gugong de gongjia 清前期农业雇工的工价.” In ZSYJ,
Vol.5, Issue. 2 (1983), 17-30.
Wu Songdi 吳松弟. 1993a.Beifang yimin yu nansong shehui bianqian 北方移民與南宋社會變
遷. Taipei, 1993.
_______. 1993b. “Huang-Huai-Hai diqu lishishiqi renkou fenbu de chubu yanjiu 黄淮海平原历
史时期人口分布的初步研究.” In LSDL, Vol.11 (1993), 155-168.
______. Zhongguo Renkoushi 中国人口史, Vol.4, Song shiqi 宋时期. Shanghai, 2000.
Xia Xiangrong 夏湘蓉, Li Zhongjun 李仲均 & Wang Genyuan 王根元. Zhongguo Gudai
Kuangye Kaifashi 中国古代矿业开发史. Beijing, 1980.
Issue 4(2002).
Xu, Dixin 许涤新 & Wu, Chengming 吴承明, ed. Zhongguo Zibenzhuyi de Mengya, Zhongguo
Zibenzhuyi Fazhanshi 中国资本主义的萌芽—中国资本主义发展史. Beijing, 1985.
___________. Chinese Capitalism, 1522-1840. Basingstoke : MacMillan ; New York : St.
Martin's Press, 2000.
91
Xu Tan 许檀. “Ming-Qing shiqi yunhe de shangpin liutong 明清时期运河的商品流通.” In Lishi
dang’an 历史档案, Issue 1 (1992), 80-5.
_________. “Mingdai shiqi shandong jishi de fazhan 明代时期山东集市的发展.” In Qingshi
Luncong 清史论丛, 1995.
_________. “Ming-Qing shiqi nongchun jishi de fazhan 明清时期农村集市的发展.” In ZJYJ,
Vol.45, Issue.2 (1997), 21-41.
_________1998a. Ming-Qing shiqi Shangdon Shangpin Jingji de Fazhan 明清时期山东商品经
济的发展. Beijing: Zhongguo shehuikexue, 1998.
________1998b. “Ming-Qing shiqi jiangxi de shangye chengzhen 明清时期江西的商业城镇.”
In ZJYJ, Vol., Issue 3 (1998).
_________1999a. “Qingdai qianqi liutong geju de bianhua 清代前期流通格局的变化.”In
Qingshi Yanjiu 清史研究, Vol.3 (1999), 1-13.
_________1999b. “Qingdai qianqi de jiujiangguan jiqi shangpin liutong 清代前期的九江关及其
商品流通.” In Lishi dang’an, Vol.73, Issue 1 (1999), 86-91.
_________. “Ming-Qing shiqi chengxiang shichang wangluo tixi de xingcheng ji yiyi 明清时期
城乡网络体系的形成及意义.” In ZGSK, Vol.3, Issue 3 (2000), 191-202.
_________ “Ming-Qing shiqi zhongguo jingji fazhan guiji tantao 明清时期中国经济发展轨迹
探讨.” In Tianjin Shifan Daxue Xuebao 天津师范大学学报, Vol.161, Issue 2 (2002), 43-47.
________. “Qingdai qianzhongqi dongbei de yanhaimaoyi yu yingkou de xingqi 清代前中期东
北的沿海贸易与营口的兴起.” In Fujian shifan daxue xuebao 福建师范大学学报, Vol.124,
No.1 (2004), 6-11.
_________ & Jing Junjian 经君健. “Qingdai qianqi shangshui wenti xintan 清代前期商税问题
新探.” In ZJYJ, Vol.18, Issue 2 (1990), 87-100.
Yamamura Kozo. “From coins to rice: hypothesis on the Kandaka and Kokudaka systems. “ In
Journal of Japanese Studies, Vol.14, Issue 2 (1998), 341-67.
Yamamura Kozo & Kamiki Tetsuo. “Silver mines and Sung coins: a monetary history of
medieval and modern Japan in international prespective.” In J. F. Richards, ed., Precious Metals
in the Late Medieval and Early Modern Worlds, 1983, 329-62.
Yanagida Setsuko 柳田節子. So Gen Gosonsei no Kenkyu 宋元鄕村制の研究.Tokyo, 1986.
________.So-Gen Shakai Keizaishi Kenkyu 宋元社會経済史研究. Tokyo, 1995.
Yang Guoqing 杨国庆. “Ming Nanjing chengqiang zhucheng renyuan goucheng ji
yonggongliang chutan 明南京城墙筑城人员及用工量初探.” In Dongnan Wenhua 东南文化,
Vol.153, Issue 1 (2002), 37-44.
92
Yang, Lien-sheng. Money and Credit in China, a short history. Cambridge: Harvard University
Press, 1952.
Yang Shengxin. “Cong Jishazang keyin kan Song-Yuan yinshua gongren de jige wenti.” In
ZHWL, Vol. 29, Issue 1 (1984), 41-58.
Ye Dehui 叶德辉. Shulin qinghua, shulin yuhua 书林清话,书林余话. Changsha: Yuelu shushe,
1999.
Ye Tan 叶坦. Fuguo fumin lun: lizuyu songdai de kaocha 富国富民论:立足于宋代的考察.
Beijing, 1991.
Ye Xian’en 叶显恩, ed. Guangdong hangyun shi, the pre-industrial time 广东航运史(古代部分).
Beijing: ZSYCRenminjiaotong, 1989.
_________ & Tan Lihua 谭棣华. “Ming-Qing Zhujiang sanjiaozhou nongye shangyehua yu
xushi de fazhan 明清珠江三角洲农业商业化与墟市的发展. ”In Guangdong shehui kexue 广东
社会科学, vol.2 (1984).
Ye Shichang 叶世昌 & Pan Liangui 潘连贵. Zhongguo gujindai jinronshi 中国古近代金融史.
Shanghai: Fudan, 2001.
Yoshioka Yoshinobu 吉岡義信. Sodai Koga shi kenkyu 宋代黃河史研究. Tokyo, 1978.
Yu, Yuezu 郁越祖. “Guanyu Songdai jianzhizhen de jige lishidili wenti 关于宋代建制镇的几个
历史地理问题. ” In LSDL, vol.6 (1988), 94-125.
Yu, Zhijia 于志嘉. Mingdai jinhu shixi zhidu 明代军户世袭制度. Taipei, 1988.
Yuan, Liangyi 袁良义. Qing Yitiao bianfa 清一条鞭法. Beijing: Beijing University Press, 1995.
Zhang, Bincun 張彬村. “Shiliu shiji zhoushanqundao de zousi maoyi 十六世紀舟山群島的走私
貿易.” In ZHFL, Vol.1 (1984), 71-96.
Zhang, Dexin 张德信 & Lin Jinshu 林金树. “Mingchu juntun shue de lishi kaocha 明初军屯数
额的历史考察.” In ZGSK, Vol.47, Issue 5 (1987), 187-206.
Zhang, Guohui 张国辉. Wanqing qianzhuang he piaohao yanjiu 晚清钱庄和票号研究. Beijing:
Zhonghua shuju, 1989.
93
Zhang, Haiying 张海英. Mingqing jiangnan shangpin liutong yu shichangtishi 明清江南商品流
通与市场体系. Shanghai: Huadong shifandaxue, 2002.
Zhang Haiying 张海瀛. Zhang Juzheng gai ge yu Shanxi Wanli qing zhang yan jiu 张居正改革与
山西万历清丈研究. Taiyuan : Shanxi renmin, 1993.
Zhang, Jinpeng 张锦鹏. Songdai shangpin gongji yanjiu 宋代商品供给研究. Yunnan: Yunnan
daxue, 2003.
Zhang, Jinling 张金岭. Wansong shiqi caizheng weiji yanjiu 晚宋时期财政危机研究. Chengdu:
Sichuan daxue.
Zhang, Shengcheng 张圣城. Henan hangyunshi 河南航运史. Beijing: Renminjiaotong (ZSYC),
1989.
Zhang, Tingmao 张廷茂. “Guanyu shiliushiqi shiji chu huashang zai dongnanya huodong de
xifang wenxian 关于十六十七世纪初华商在东南亚活动的西方文献.” In ZGSY, Vol.102, Issue
2 (2004), 139-51.
Zhang, Wen 张文. Songchao shehui jiuji yanjiu 宋朝社会救济研究. Chongqing, 2001.
Zhang, Yan 张研. “Qingdai shizhen guanli chutan 清代市镇管理初探.” In Qinshi yanjiu 清史研
究, Issue 1 (1999), 39-52.
Zhang, Youyi 章有义. Ming-Qing Huizhou tudiguanxi yanjiu 明清徽州土地关系研究. Beijing,
1984.
__________. “Guanyu zhongguo jindai nongye shengchan jiliang yanjiu de jize gengju 关于中国
近代农业生产计量研究的几则根据.” In ZSYJ, No.2 (1990), Beijing.
Zhao Gang 趙岡& Chen Zhongyi 陳鐘毅.Zhongguo tudi zhidushi 中國土地制度史. Taipei, 1982.
_______. Zhongguo jingji zhidu shilun 中國經濟制度史論. Taipei, 1982.
_______. Zhongguo nongye jingjishi 中國農業經濟史. Taipei, 1989.
Zhao, Shiyu 赵世瑜. Li yu zhongguo shehui 吏与中国社会. Hangzhou, 1994.
Zhao, Xiaogeng 赵晓耕. Songdai fazhiyanjiu 宋代法制研究. Beijing: Zhongguo zhengfadaxue,
1994.
Zhao, Yashu 趙雅書. “Songdai cansiye de dili fenbu 宋代蠶絲业的地理分佈.” In Shiyuan 史原,
Vol.3 (1972), 65-94.
94
——————“Songdai nongjia jingying zi cansiye 宋代農家經營之蠶絲业.” In Bulletin of the
Department of History 臺大歷史學報, No.3 (May, 1976), 119-29.
Zheng, Kecheng 郑克晟. Mingdai zhengzheng tanyuan 明代政争探源. Tianjin, 1988.
__________. “Mingchu Jiangnan dizhu de shuailuo yu beifang dizhu de xingqi 明初江南地主的
衰落与北方地主的兴起.” In Beijing Shifandaxue Xubao 北京师范大学学报, No.5 (2001), 4958 .
Zheng Tianting 郑天挺. “Guanyu Xu Yikui ‘Zhonggongdui’关于徐一夔‘织工对’”. In Zhongguo
Zibenzhuyi Mengya Wenti Taolunji Xubian 中国资本主义萌芽问题讨论集续编. Beijing, 1960.
Zheng Xuemeng. Zhongguo gudai jingji zhongxin nanyi he Tangsong jiangnan jingji yanjiu 中国
古代经济重心南移和唐宋江南经济研究. Changsha: Yuelu shushe, 2003.
Zhongguo gusuanyan xuehui zhubian 中国硅酸盐学会主编(主编小组: 冯先铭,安志敏, 安金槐,
朱伯谦, 汪庆正). Zhongguo taocishi 中国陶瓷史. Beijing, 1982.
Zhongguo gudai meitan kaifashi bianxiezu《中国古代煤炭开发史》编写组. Zhongguo gudai
meitan kaifashi 中国古代煤炭开发史. Beijing, 1986.
Zhongyang yanjiuyuan lishi yuyan yanjiu suo 中央研究院歷史語言研究所. Zhongguo jinshi
jiiazhu yu shehui xueshu yantaohui lunwenji 中國近世家族與社會學術研討會論文集. Taipei,
1999.
Zhou Baozhu 周宝珠. Songdai Dongjing yanjiu 宋代东京研究. Kaifeng, 1999.
Zhou Liangxiao 周良霄. “Mingdai Susong diqu de guantian yu zhongfu wenti 明代苏松地区的
官田与重赋问题.” In LSYJ, Issue 10 (1957), 63-75.
_________. & Gu Juying 顾菊英. Yuanshi 元史. Shanghai: Shanghai renmin, 2003.
Zhou Yumin 周育民. Wanqing caizheng yu shehui bianqian 晚清财政与社会变迁.Shanghai,
2000.
Zhu Xinyu 朱新予, ed. Zhongguo Sichoushi 中国丝绸史. Beijing, 1992.
Zou Yilin 邹逸麟. “Lun Dingtao de xingshuai yu gudai zhongyuan shuiyun jiaotong de bianqian
论定陶的兴衰与古代中原水运交通的变迁. ” In ZHWL, Vol.8 (1978), 191-207.
_______. “Shandong yunhe lishi dili chutan 山东运河历史地理问题初探.” In LSDL, Vol.1
95
(1981), 80-98.
________. “Huanghe xiayou hedao bianqian jiqi yingxiang gaishu 黄河下游河道变迁及其影响
概述.” In Huangheshi luncong 黄河史论丛(1986), 221-42.
__________.“Huaihe xiayou nanbei yunkou bianqian he chengzhen xingshuai 黄河下游南北运
口变迁和城镇兴衰.” In LSDL, Vol.6 (1988), 57-72.
_______. ed. Huang-Huai-Hai pingyuan lishidili 黄淮海历史地理. Hefui: Anhui jiaoyu, 1997.
96
Fly UP