Comments
Description
Transcript
ITALY
Centre international de recherches et d'information sur l'économie publique, sociale et coopérative ITALY Dante COSI, Martina IANNIZZOTTO, Amalia LULLI, Stefano SACCONI and Stefano ZOLEA CIRIEC Italy June 1999 http://www.ulg.ac.be/ciriec/ ITALY June 1999 Dante COSI Martina IANNIZZOTTO Amalia LULLI Stefano SACCONI Stefano ZOLEA CIRIEC Italy 2 I THE « THIRD SECTOR » AND WORK 1.1 General remarks The weight carried by the economic units of the « Third sector » in Italy, taken as a whole, is not negligible either in terms of entrepreneurial presence, with particular reference to some regions and areas of the country and to some sectors of the local and/or national economy, or in terms of contribution to employment: the percentage of the total workforce employed in this group of economic units can be calculated as between approximately 3.8% and 5% (see below for the uncertainties in definition and quantification). This figure derives in the first place from the convergence of two factors of different quality and origin: a) Labour co-operatives have always carried considerable weight in the Italian co-operative reality. The traditional, widespread presence of production and labour co-operatives in the construction sector and in some manufacturing sectors (which for the most part demonstrated a better capacity for resistance and reaction to crises compared to similar realities in other countries, thus confirming their importance and accentuating their prominence in a European context) has been accompanied by a growing assertion of the co-operative formula in numerous service sectors (transport, canteens, maintenance and cleaning, etc.) and the increasingly widespread introduction of social co-operatives. The total number of workers in the production and labour, services, tourism and social cooperative sectors of the companies belonging to the two principal national co-operative organizations (Confcooperative and Legacoop) is 294 000, equivalent to roughly 1.28% of the total labour force. b) The development of « private-welfare » economic formulas other than co-operatives during the 1980s and 1990s, the majority of which were involved in activities (personal grooming; environmental assistance, safeguarding and quality; management of educational and health structures) that are structurally highly labour intensive, and consequently even if their primary aim is not to provide new jobs as such, they are nevertheless important from the employment point of view. The contribution of these initiatives to employment has been estimated (according to the various criteria used for surveying and calculation) at between 242 000 (1% of the total work force) and 418 000 (1.8%) paid workers. To these two principal factors we should add a third, which also carries considerable weight. The importance, from an employment point of view, of the presence of other types of cooperative companies whose purpose is not directly to provide support for employment, but that are nevertheless extremely valuable in providing employment: suffice to mention, of the most important ones, the co-operatives in the distribution sector (consumer and retailer cooperatives, with a total of 39 500 employees in those co-operatives belonging to the two organizations), in the food-agriculture sector (65 000 employees), in the credit sector (cooperative credit banks, 21 000 employees). In some cases (retailers’ co-operatives, agricultural co-operatives supporting producers, etc.), one should also bear in mind, when evaluating the contribution to employment of such forms of companies, not only the number of workers employed in each company, but also, in broader terms, their contribution to the 3 protection, modernization, and strengthening of the competitive capacities of the small economic activities of their members to combat the competition from larger entrepreneurs operating in the same sectors. This competition is such that they continually run the risk of being forced out of the market, with the consequent - and not easily remediable - loss of jobs. This indirect contribution to employment is non accurately quantifiable, but the number of members in the larger organizations alone exceeds a million. 1.2 Problems of definition 1.2.1 Introduction In the Italian debate it would appear to be particularly difficult to arrive at an unequivocal and commonly acceptable definition of the « Third sector ». Briefly, there are two different interpretations: one of these, the more traditional, tends to include in the « Third sector », together with the non co-operative « intermediate » companies that fall between public economy and private company, the entire universe of co-operative entrepreneurship, or rather that part of it - the majority - which conforms to the « mutual requirements » provided for in art. 26 of « Basevi’s law » (DLCPS no. 1577 of 14 December 1947); the other, more recent and fairly common nowadays, tends to exclude co-operative entrepreneurship from the « Third sector », the only exception being the social co-operatives regulated by law no. 381 of 8 November 1991. Besides, even the name of the « sector » in question is not univocal, but has, over the course of recent years, been called by numerous names (cf. Inventory Nr 1). A brief historic reconnaissance may lead to a better understanding of these difficulties and uncertainties. 1.2.2 The co-operative predominance At the end of the 1970s it would have been basically legitimate, although not totally comprehensive or correct, to identify the « Third sector » with co-operatives. In fact, with the passing of the institutional reform of the National Health Service, the process of absorption of the principal health and social security structures within the public economy was concluded: what remained of the « private-welfare » could, in that phase, be rightly considered to be residual and of negligible qualitative, as well as quantitative, importance. In contrast, over the same years, the co-operative economy had been fiscally fully sanctioned, and its « welfare function » recognized by art. 45 of the Constitution. Art. 12 of law no. 904 of 16 December 1977 confirmed that the portion of annual profits that the co-operatives destined for a reserve that could never be disposed of was exempt from the taxable income. This law gave the cooperative economy a strong incentive for developing its own resources and for company growth, and it has increasingly shown itself to be an economic force present in the market with its own peculiarities (mutuality and absence of speculative purpose, democratic management, centrality of the human factor) that is capable of carrying weight within the market itself. 1.2.3 The recovery of the « intermediate » economy In the 1980s and 1990s the panorama became more complicated thanks to the recovery, also in new forms, of economic initiatives of an associative matrix and noticeably welfare inspired, a large part not in a co-operative form: voluntary organizations, associations managing assistance, health-welfare or educational provisions, the recovery or new creation of friendly societies, etc. The increase in the « charitable » co-operatives and in the 4 production and « integrated » labour co-operatives for the introduction of disabled workers (subsequently disciplined by law 381/91 as « social co-operatives » of type A and type B, respectively) fits in with the same general tendency towards a recovery in « private-welfare » initiatives. This renewed vitality in « intermediate » economic initiatives originates - to put it briefly from two converging factors: on the one hand the crisis of direct public management of « welfare » and, on the other, the diffusion of a different awareness of the possibility/opportunity to provide for this in an associative and self-organized form to satisfy those same welfare needs that were until then the object of public authority. The same legislation, in particular over the course of the 1990s, tends to recognize, regulate and support this type of initiative: here it is worthwhile mentioning some of the most important laws passed in this period: law no. 266 of 11 August 1991 (framework law for voluntary organizations), the previously mentioned law 381/91 that legislates social cooperatives, the decree law of 14 November 1997 (legislating non-commercial entities and socially useful non-profit-making organizations - ONLUS), law no. 461 of 23 December 1998 (legislative decree concerning the regulation of banking foundations). 1.2.4 Two different conceptions of co-operatives and the market In contrast, as far as the co-operative economy is concerned, there is a progressively growing current of opinion (expressed at the top level and with particular determination during the brief experience of the centre-right government in 1994) aimed at separating, also from a legal point of view, the larger co-operatives with a stronger entrepreneurial structure from the « minor » ones, which are considered to be closer to the welfare purpose of the co-operative formula itself, assimilating the first in the private/lucrative entrepreneurial model and thereby denying them constitutional recognition and the consequent special tax regime. Such a tendency would lead to a denial, for the co-operative economy as a whole, of its interpretation (developed in explicit terms especially over the course of the 1970s) as a form of company with specific characteristics aimed at introducing elements of welfare and of centrality of the human factor into the market, since this basically constitutes the « welfare function » that the Constitution attributes to it. This tendency interprets the « welfare economy » as being in conflict with market activity and incompatible with it: whence the splitting up - amongst other things - of the co-operatives into one « mercantile » segment and one belonging to the « Third sector ». The same conception of the market seems to be based, as far as the subjects operating in it are concerned, on an essentially unique model, or at least one which conforms to a single company type: the private/capitalistic profit-making one. On this more general level, that tendency is countered by a different interpretation, which is the continuous development of previous processes: that of a market where the operators are entrepreneurial types that are effectively different from each other as regards legal structure and ethical and social inspiration. 1.2.5 Co-operatives between sociality and firms Over the course of those same decades, the 1980s and (even more so) the 1990s, the organizations of the co-operative movement, in contrast, show to a greater degree the peculiarly welfare character of this type of company. On the one hand, in fact, they emphasize the potential of the co-operative intervention with regard to « welfare », both in general terms and through the specific tool of social co-operation: thus showing the affinity that exists between the co-operative formula and other formulas of the « Third sector », and therefore 5 that the co-operative belongs to the latter. On the other hand they tend to demonstrate, in parallel with contemporary data from other sources, those aspects of transparency, democratic management, and the social inspiration of co-operative entrepreneurship: proof of this can be found also in the widespread practice of publishing the « social reports » of the co-operative companies and groups and the intense discussion currently underway about « corporate governance », for the purpose of defining and implementing a specific « co-operative governance ». 1.2.6 A duplicity still to be overcome Despite these developments, at the end of the 1990s this duplicity of interpretation still has not been overcome in Italy. It would, however, appear to be legitimate to draw attention to the increasingly obvious insufficiency of a merely « residual » definition of the varied area of economic activities grouped together under the heading « Third sector »: as if it were « neither a private nor a public » economy. This is true especially with regard to the increasing responsibility assumed by this universe of economic initiatives, in relation to both the process of reform of the welfare State (and in general the reform/reduction of the public presence in the economy), and to the coming into force of the legislative measures that recognize the need for adequate capitalization in co-operative companies and at the same time strengthen their peculiarly social aspects (cf. law no. 59 of 31 January 1992, which provides for the introduction of the new figures of « subsidizing member » and of the « holders of cooperative shares », in addition to formalizing the « external mutuality » through the setting up of « mutual promotion funds » fed by 3% of the co-operatives’ profits; cf. also the recent introduction - with the 1999 budget - of the possibility for co-operatives to issue bonds). In this report we bear in mind both the need for an unambiguous and more comprehensive definition, and the fact that such a need is still today very far from being satisfied: in fact, we give an account of the reality of the « Third sector » in its wider acceptable meaning, but at the same time maintain a distinction between its two components according to the subdivision into « co-operatives » and « non co-operative types » (and treat the social cooperative, in keeping with the commonly accepted idea, as an area superimposed between the two components). 1.3 Problems of quantification Another area of uncertainty, no less important than that of the definition of the sector, is encountered when quantifying all of the phenomena that constitute the « Third sector »: whether co-operative or non co-operative. For the latter, the cause for uncertainty in quantification is the criteria adopted in the collection and classification of data from the different sources. This has a particularly noticeable effect on the estimate of the number of paid workers, and consequently on the effective incidence of the non-profit economy on employment: in 1997, for example, the number of paid workers in the non co-operative « Third sector » was estimated to be 418 128 according to a study carried out by the Johns Hopkins University, whereas a study by the Lunaria association estimated the figure to be 254 003, which was 39% lower (it should be noted that, in contrast, the number of voluntary workers was far more similar, at around 270 000, with only a few thousand difference between the two). As far as co-operatives are concerned, the uncertainty of the data is due to the unreliability of official sources, which should be gathered uniformly by the Ministry of Labour and Social Security. The figures in the Ministry’s possession are, however, very approximate and full of 6 contradictions which make them totally unsatisfactory as an information base. This fundamental unreliability of ministerial documentation, which affects all of the variables of the economic universe of the co-operatives, is obviously also reflected in the estimate of the contribution to employment provided by that entrepreneurial area. In this respect we should like to add that: • the Ministry is in the process of updating and re-processing its data which should, in a reasonable amount of time, enable it to provide acceptably reliable figures; the Ministry itself already has a sufficiently accurate database regarding social co-operatives and cooperation between non-EU and displaced citizens; • the mandate of the national associations of the co-operative movement to supervise the cooperatives belonging to their associations enables them to collect and collate data from the supervised entities which today provide a sufficiently reliable and detailed picture of this sub-group. As a result, based on the data available from the major national co-operative associations (Legacoop and Confcooperative), we can make a partial reconstruction of the data for the group that is very similar. 1.4 The « Third sector » in the Italian government’s « National Action Plan for Employment 1999 » The potential for development in the « Third sector », with special regard to the innovative forms which have manifested themselves over the course of recent years, is exploited in the Italian government’s « National Action Plan for Employment 1999 ». In April 1998 the government underwrote a « Solidarity Pact » with the permanent Forum of the « Third sector » (the majority of Italian non-profit organizations participate in the co-ordination of the Forum which has been in operation since 1994); in February 1999 a preliminary draft was signed - specifically dedicated to non-profit organizations - for an addition to the Social Pact stipulated in December 1998 between the Government and the labour and employers associations; in March 1999 a Commission was set up within the Ministry of Labour whose purpose was to put forward and to monitor actions for the development of employment in the sector. It should be remembered (see also the paragraph above dealing with institutions) that law 461/98 obliges banking foundations to allocate at least half of their profits to institutional activities (culture, instruction, research, welfare activities) that may to a considerable extent be carried out by the firms of the welfare economy. Already in 1998 the Government, in partnership not only with the regions and local authorities, but also with the European Commission, promoted a number of actions which involve co-operative subjects in various fields (from welfare inclusion to services and professions for leisure activities, culture, membership of associations and the environment; from the rehabilitation of urban areas to the differentiated refuse collection). The financial act of 1999 provides for tax exemption and support for employment within the welfare economy itself. A proposal for a framework law for an integrated system of services for individuals and the community is being discussed in parliament, which foresees the setting up of a national fund of ITL 500 billion in 1999 to build integrated networks of services for individuals and families, with particular attention to old people who are not self-sufficient. In applying the principle of subordination the government Plan of Action states « the non-profit sector will co-operate in the planning, design and management of the network of services ». 7 Lastly, in the document mentioned the Government announces its intention to arrive at a new set of rules governing the welfare firm by the end of 1999, which will allow for different juridical forms of economic-productive non-profit activities that will develop their growth and productivity. It would therefore appear to be plausible to say that the initiative and the presence of the « Third sector » in Italy, even for the non co-operatives, are approaching a phase in which it may, at an official level as well as on a day-to-day basis, benefit from more organized recognition and support. If this is accompanied by a progressive overcoming of the dichotomy that has existed for twenty years - for the historic reasons mentioned briefly at the beginning of this report - between the co-operative and the non co-operative sections of the « Third sector », then that initiative and that presence may benefit and be further strengthened, offering useful and advantageous solutions to the problems that the Italian society must face, especially on the work front. 8 II THE INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANISMS OF THE « THIRD SECTOR » 2.1 The Co-operatives 2.1.1 Specific characteristics There are two main differences between the Italian co-operative and the other major European co-operatives - of which Italy is one of the largest as regards number of cooperatives (an unofficial estimate from the Ministry of Labour and Social Security, not yet published, puts the number of registered co-operatives at just less than 160 000), number of partners, turnover and number of workers. One is the considerable presence of a large number of economic sectors and the other, the grouping of the co-operatives into inter-sectorial associations. Furthermore, in contrast to other European Union countries, according to Italian legislation although the « social function » of the co-operatives is recognized by the Constitution of the Republic (art. 45), there is no univocal definition of the co-operative firm. The law, which has provided the legal basis for co-operatives since 1947 (DLCPS no. 1577 of 14 December 1947, so-called « Basevi’s law », art. 26), lays down the « mutual requirements » that the cooperatives must have in order to benefit from the specific fiscal regime, but does so purely for « tax purposes ». Furthermore, the choice of the taxation tool as a support and incentive for co-operative entrepreneurs (by applying the aforementioned art. 45 of the constitution) has been by far the most predominant form of incentive in the history of the Italian Republic. Recognition by the constitution, the absence of a univocal typology of co-operative institution, the imposition of strict « mutual requirements » (limits to the distribution of profits, prohibition of distribution of reserves among partners during the life of the cooperative, transmission of residuary estate to the social utility in case of dissolution) in order to benefit from the specific fiscal regime provided for by the law, constitute the distinguishing signs of the Italian co-operative, and in some ways make up for the lack of a clear definition of the institution in civil law. With the result that, although no norm exists that explicitly prescribes the « requisites » mentioned in art. 26 of « Basevi’s law », and as co-operative companies also exist whose statutes do not provide for its adoption, in Italy when we speak of co-operatives or of the co-operative movement we are usually referring only to those cooperatives that observe these principles. One last point to consider, as a specific element of the co-operative situation in Italy, is the role played by the national Associations for the « representation, assistance and safeguarding » of the co-operative movement, recognized by « Basevi’s law » and to which the law entrusts the ordinary biannual inspection (compulsory) of their co-operative members, reserving any possible extra-ordinary inspections for the Ministry of Labour, in addition to the ordinary inspections of co-operatives not belonging to any Association. If we add to this the granting to the inspectors of a role not only of control, but also of support and consultancy for the co-operatives, one can legitimately deduce that Italian law outlines the « selfgovernment » of the co-operative movement centred around the co-operative companies’ joining, on a totally voluntary basis, the recognized Associations. 2.1.2 The sectors 9 For the purpose of recording the co-operatives in the prefectorial registers, art. 13 of « Basevi’s law » subdivides them into seven sections « according to the different nature and activity of the organs »: consumer, production and labour, agricultural, construction, transport, fishing, and mixed co-operatives. Following the issuing of this law there was a considerable increase in the presence of co-operative entrepreneurs in all the fields of classification, and it was further developed and extended to fields that were not then legally provided for. Suffice to think of the retailers’ and tourism co-operatives, and those operating in the most diverse segments of the tertiary sector or the more recent social co-operatives. One should consider whether an evaluation of Italian co-operatives could be said to be complete if it did not take into account those sectors (like credit) that are not considered by the stated law, presumably because they are subject to different methods of administrative control. Here we will abide by the association subdivision rather than the administrative one, with particular reference to the larger organizations of the co-operative movement: the Lega Nazionale Cooperative e Mutue (Legacoop) and the Confederazione Cooperative Italiane (Confcooperative): while the subdivisions do not completely coincide (since their respective membership base is different in part), they do, however, reflect the co-operative reality more faithfully than the legal classification. Looking at the membership of these two organizations from the point of view of the sector we find: LEGACOOP Sector Food-agriculture Fishing Production and Labour Services and Tourism Consumers Retailers Cultural Co-op. Housing Other activities Total Source: Legacoop No. co-operatives 1 323 250 1 020 3 000 230 15 602 2 500 1 270 10 210 No. members 277 145 20 500 30 850 115 000 3 610 000 5 650 14 500 435 000 10 500 4 519 145 10 Turnover (bn) 8 645 1 145 9 060 7 500 14 560 6 350 605 2 190 1 005 51 060 No. workers 19 260 2 900 34 650 125 000 36 000 3 240 2 500 1 700 1 450 226 700 CONFCOOPERATIVE Sector Food-agriculture Fishing Labour and Services Consumption and Distribution Culture tourism and sport Charities Co-operative Credit Banks Housing Total No. cooperatives 4 803 392 3 588 1 096 No. members Turnover (bn) No. workers 696 935 32 131 154 636 329 969 22 857 761 6 323 8 117 46 515 5 689 88 367 10 267 1 423 281 120 754 7 078 1 867 581 70 942 501 602 3 994 17 744 496 581 2 563 916 1 090 98 261 (deposits + fiduciary funds) 898 (exc. credit) 40 800 45 730 21 000 368 225 014 Source: processing of Confcooperative data From the above figures we can see quite clearly the enormous difference that exists between the formulas in the universe of co-operatives (like first and foremost labour co-operatives in industry and services) whose primary and directly pursued purpose is to provide employment for the members and those on the other hand whose purpose is to satisfy other needs of their members and they avail themselves of a workforce of employees to achieve that end. Compare for example the production and labour sector of the Legacoop universe (31 000 members and 35 000 workers) or the services and tourism sector (115 000 members and 125 000 workers) with that of consumers (3 600 000 members and 36 000 workers) or housing (435 000 members and 1 700 workers). Obviously the same is true also of Confcooperative sectors: here the most significant comparison could be between the charitable sector (social co-operatives with 71 000 members and 46 000 workers) and the co-operative credit banks (500 000 members and 21 000 workers). They should be different in part, for the reasons already stated, what should be discussed about co-operative formulas, as is largely the case of the food-agriculture or retailers’ co-operatives, which the ratio between number of members and number of workers does not fully demonstrate, is the value as a support for employment that such co-operative formulas offer to certain categories which would otherwise be at risk. On the basis of these data, the statement we made at the beginning would appear to be confirmed, that is that in Italy the « Third sector » (in the broadest sense) makes a not negligible contribution to support for employment, thanks to the strong presence of labour cooperatives in many areas, which is one of its most important factors. Before leaving the figures, it is worth noting that the number of workers in sectors classifiable as « labour cooperatives », in both organizations, accounts for the more than half of the total workers. - LEGACOOP: Production and Labour (34 000) + Services and Tourism (125 000) = 159 000 workers (70% of the total). CONFCOOPERATIVE: Labour and Services (88 000) + Charities (46 000) = 134 000 workers (60% of the total). 11 2.1.3 Social co-operatives In the case of social co-operatives (regulated by law 381/91), the data collected by the Ministry of Labour and Social Security proved to be quite complete and reliable, unlike those for the rest of the universe of co-operatives. Consequently it is worthwhile giving the complete official data. According to the census, in 1996 the number of co-operatives was 3 857, with a noticeable increase compared to the previous year (+1 023, equivalent to +36%). The total number of members was 118 472, the number of voluntary members 10 857, and the number of disadvantaged people employed in the productive activities of the co-operatives 15 746. See also table on page 42. 2.1.4 Representative Associations As we have already mentioned, in the life of the Italian co-operative movement the importance of the representative organizations, which have characteristics that are to a large extent different from those operating in other national contexts, is recognized also by the law. Such recognition is expressed through some of the mandates: the one we have already mentioned about supervision, which the law explicitly states is aimed also at promoting a more efficient business management; and the one contained in « Basevi’s law » (art. 29 bis), which obliges the Ministry of Labour to carry out those compulsory initiatives aimed at the « development of co-operatives » and at « professional training for the managers of the cooperatives » through the recognized Associations; and which orders the Ministry, « with the collaboration » of the Associations themselves, to implement those initiatives aimed at the « diffusion of co-operative principles ». Lastly, another mandate was provided for by law no. 59 of 31 January 1992, which entrusts the recognized Associations with the management of that « external mutuality » through the institution of their own specific « mutual funds for the promotion and growth of the co-operatives », to which the co-operatives contribute 3% of their profits, which, according to the same law, should be a generalized and binding practice for the companies. Through these mandates, and more generally by entrusting the Associations with a series of important tasks, the law appears to bestow upon these inter-company co-operative Associations a very peculiar role: that of guaranteeing and making more concrete the distinctiveness of the co-operative, for their respective entrepreneurial areas. This role is even more significant if seen as a continuation of the historically indispensable one played in the past by representative organizations for an entrepreneurial area - that of the co-operative which was originally the prerogative of the weaker social classes, who do not possess the technical and cultural tools necessary for an effective and competitive company management. And which acquires new importance in a phase like the current one, in which the cooperatives (and the « Third sector » in general) have the chance to assume new economic and ethical-social responsibilities. 12 There are four national Associations of the co-operative movement operating in Italy1: • • • • Associazione Nazionale Cooperative Italiane (AGCI) with 5 523 co-operative members in 1997; Confederazione Cooperative Italiane (Confcooperative) with 17 964 co-operative members in 1997; Lega Nazionale Cooperative e Mutue (Legacoop) with 11 491 co-operative members in 1997; Unione Nazionale Cooperative Italiane (UNCI) with 4 874 co-operative members in 1997. Each of the four Associations (commonly known as co-operative Centrali) has co-operative members active in all sectors, although the proportion from each sector differs from one centrale to the next. Here are some examples: almost all of the co-operative credit banks (exCasse rurali e artigiane) belong to Confcooperative and constitute one of its largest sectors; consumer co-operatives make up one of the strongest and most extensive sectors of the Legacoop (the Coop is the principal commercial distribution chain in Italy), whereas for the other Centrali they only constitute a marginal presence (for Confcooperative they represent a sizeable share only for a few, limited, geographic areas); the Legacoop encompasses the principal nucleus of voluntary friendly societies, associated to FIMIV, whereas this presence is noticeably reduced in other Centrali; etc. With or without direct reference to the mandates granted to them by law, the Centrali act as a true organized « movement », performing a series of functions which together contribute decisively to the entrepreneurial, social and cultural area of the co-operatives present in the economic-social and democratic life of the country and capable of having a meaningful influence over it. On the one hand they exist to give the otherwise fragmented galaxy of cooperatives belonging to each of them the form of an entrepreneurial « system », which is coordinated as far as possible internally, and provides recognition and strength in their dealings with the market and the principal external interlocutors. The Centrali carry out this activity both through sectorial (sector associations or federations) and territorial structures (unions, federations, provincial and/or regional leagues), and via a constant commitment to coordination among the different sectors, accentuating their complementarity and activating any possible synergies. Externally, the function of the Centrali consists of promoting the interests of their associates (lobbying) and, in general, promoting the principles and the peculiarity of the co-operatives. One particularly important activity is that of promoting the co-operative economy both in the sense of the creation of new companies and in the sense of encouraging the expansion and the 1 In order to guarantee uniformity, the data is taken from ministerial sources. The same source offers the following time series (the reduction in the number of entities associated to the larger Centrali is largely due to mergers): Number of co-operatives recorded AGCI Confcooperative year Legacoop UNCI 6 430 5 940 5 737 5 523 14 024 12 126 11 342 11 491 4 453 4 568 4 663 4 874 1994 1995 1996 1997 22 096 21 228 19 489 17 964 13 Total Members 47 003 43 862 41 231 39 852 Non Members 111 561 113 595 116 835 119 046 Overall Total 158 564 157 457 158 066 158 898 development of existing companies. The activity of the Centrali, in this context, consists of developing and up-dating the original function of « assistance » to the co-operatives: if in the 19th century and the first decades of the 20th century this function meant supplying companies with « consultancy » on an administrative and management level, nowadays it involves making resources available to the weaker co-operatives and/or those in the initial stages, also by means of promoting and co-ordinating a series of tools (which will be dealt with in more details later) - such as experience, entrepreneurial know-how, the ability to penetrate the market - all accessible from the stronger co-operatives. This is, basically, a modern version of inter-co-operative solidarity. 2.1.5 The typologies Italian law provides for three types of co-operatives status, the « co-operative » (with the variation « social co-operative », disciplined by law 381/91), the « consortium » and the « small co-operative » law no. 266 of 7 August 1997, art. 21). The law does not establish any important differences between the types of co-operative operating in the various sectors: the differences are mainly concerned with the attribution of control and administrative competence, and the compulsory enrolment in certain albums or registers (this is the case of housing co-operatives and consortia of co-operatives participating in public tenders). From the point of view of legal discipline, it is worth drawing attention to the recent introduction (1997) of the « small co-operative », made up of between three and eight members, i.e. fewer than the minimum of nine required for the « ordinary » co-operative, and subject to a more simplified administrative procedure than the latter. Today such innovation acquires a particular significance due to the fact that it offers a possible tool for entrepreneurial and labour initiatives, in the most diverse sectors, mainly on the part of young people who have technical and professional qualifications. The greater flexibility and adaptability of the co-operative tool, obtained by the institution of the « small co-operative » is particularly important in a context such as that of the end of the 1990s, when the job prospects for qualified young people are no longer linked to the possibility of being taken on by a large company, and even less so by the public administration, but much more closely to the promotion of initiatives of an entrepreneurial character, even if they are of small or minimum dimensions. Worthy of mention is the introduction in 1991 of the « social co-operative ». Rather than being totally different from the « ordinary » co-operative, it is a variation on it, with a peculiar purpose and the presence of members belonging to particular categories: the number of voluntary members may not exceed 50% of the total, or - in the case of the co-operatives for « integrating » or providing jobs - the members recognized as « persons in difficulty » (disabled or belonging to socially challenged categories), should not be fewer than 30% of the total. Legal recognition of the peculiarity of this type of co-operative, in addition to legally sanctioning the increasingly widespread, and often successful, experimentation, has contributed to reaffirming the « social function » of the co-operative formula, to fully reintegrating it among the subjects of « Third sector » and to further emphasizing its possible use as a reform tool for the welfare state and in general for the public presence in the economic-social sphere. Not least, the legal discipline of this type of co-operative has sanctioned the availability of an entrepreneurial type employment tool in a sphere like that of personal and community services, which is destined for further, broad expansion; and has in another way shown the validity of creating jobs for the disabled and socially challenged not through administrative or assistance channels, but through their directly and autonomously assuming responsibility. 14 Finally the consortium is a traditional tool for co-ordinating and strengthening the cooperative companies and linking them with the outside world (the market, the public administration). The co-operative Centrali encourage the training, development, and transformation of the respective networks of consortia, sectorial or inter-sectorial, following the evolution of the potential and the needs of the different segments of entrepreneurial area to which they belong. There are also some examples of collaboration between consortia belonging to different Centrali, or of consortia made up of co-operatives from different associations. 2.1.6 Sources of financing for co-operative companies The capitalization of the co-operatives finds some support factors in Italian legislation, especially in terms of tax concessions. The first of these factors is tax exemption for the balance sheet profits appropriated by the shareholders’ AGM to a reserve fund that cannot be divided between the shareholders nor can it ever be disposed of law no. 904 of 16 December 1977, art. 12; the reference is to art. 26 of DLCPS no. 1577 of 14 December 1947, a.k.a. « Basevi’s law », which established the « mutual requirements » that the co-operatives must possess « for tax purposes »). Another important support factor is tax concessions (art. 13 of DPR 601/73, up-dated by art. 10 of law 59/92), within certain limits and at specific conditions, for loans granted by the members to their co-operative. In addition to the capital shares, of which incidentally law 59/92 increased the upper limit and allowed for a revaluation in line with the rate of inflation without the loss of any fiscal benefits, the members are therefore encouraged to contribute both to the capital consolidation of the cooperative, and to providing the working capital. There are other sources of financing in addition to the corporate base: borrowing from banks, which is particularly common (and costly) for co-operatives whose own resources are limited; procurement of foreign capital by means of the new figures introduced by law no. 59 of 31 January 1992, that is the « subsidizing member » (art. 4) and the holders of « co-operative shares » (art. 5 and 6), as well as issuing bonds, as co-operatives are permitted to do by the financial act of 1999. The financing innovations introduced by law 59/92 are quite controversial, and have yet to be applied on a large scale by the co-operatives. 2.1.7 Tools for support and promotion The Italian legislator’s constant and almost exclusive choice to support the development of the co-operative (support that is constitutionally compulsory) by means of the tax tool has brought about the almost total absence, or in any case irrelevance, of any public instrument aimed directly at promoting the activities of co-operative entrepreneurs. The only exception, at least in part, is the credit for co-operatives Section (Coopercredito) set up at the Banca Nazionale del Lavoro (whose roots are linked to credit for co-operative entrepreneurs). The privatization of this bank has, furthermore, stripped the Coopercredito of its characteristic public tool for the support of co-operatives. In keeping with the principle of self-government of the co-operative movement, enforced initially, as we have seen, by means of a series of State mandates to the recognized representative Associations, a large part of the tools for promotion and support are issued by co-operative movements themselves. 15 Above all the consortia are co-operative companies made up of co-operatives, to which the associated companies traditionally delegate a series of common functions: purchase of goods, supplies of raw materials and technology, co-ordination and promotion of sales, etc. A law which has been in force since 1911 disciplines consortia of co-operatives whose purpose is to bid for public tenders. The consortia have an important function in the financial field too: to facilitate access to credit by means of collective guarantees given to banks, advances on capital, management of the liquidity of the associated co-operatives, etc. All four entrepreneurial areas belonging to the Centrali have a dense network of consortia operating at different levels: local and regional, sectorial, national, inter-sectorial. The evolution of some of the consortia has led to their assuming their own autonomous entrepreneurial functions, with the consequent arrival of problems in their relationship with the co-operatives, including their own associates. In other cases the function of the consortia has remained purely one of « service » to their member co-operatives. Over the years the rigid co-operative discipline of the consortia (with special reference to the one vote per head - which has however been modified - makes it problematic for cooperatives that differ enormously in size and disposable means) has often led the cooperatives, as an alternative, to constitute ordinary companies (S.r.l. or S.p.A.) to carry out the functions of services to firms. Alongside the network of consortia, therefore, there exists a network of service companies that are not themselves co-operatives but are controlled by cooperatives. This type of tool is the subject of a lively debate within the co-operative movement: in the eyes of some, a too widespread use of service structures in the form of ordinary companies, also in cases in which this choice is not one dictated by the nature of the activity to be carried out, would risk the degeneration of the same mutualistic peculiarity of the co-operative, because of the delegation of important functions to organisms operating according to non mutualistic rules. The proposed alternative - given the need to strengthen the entrepreneurial capacity of the cooperatives, which is fulfilled by service companies - is that of reinforcing their capacity, first and foremost, by raising the level of capitalization, by making it possible for them to procure capital from sources other than their corporate base, and by recourse to the market (cf. « Sources of financing of the co-operative companies » above). As regards the « tools of the system » of the co-operative movement, promoted by each of the Centrali in the areas respectively represented, it should be stressed that numerous organs exist, both in the form of consortia and of ordinary companies, that are entrusted with important inter-sectorial institutional tasks, as much at a regional and local level as at a national level. Some are these that are aimed at training the junior and senior management of the co-operatives and at managing the editorial and communication activities. Particularly in the case of organs established for training purposes, it is one of the few channels through which the previously mentioned provision of « Basevi’s law » is implemented, which obliges the public authorities to carry out promotional activities through the representative Associations of the co-operative movement: for their specific activity, in fact, these organs can benefit from public resources. Moreover, it is obvious that these same training organs perform the function of increasing and qualifying employment in the co-operatives, and consequently in the labour force in general. The Istituto Italiano di Studi Cooperativi « Luigi Luzzatti » is a case apart, on similar ground. It is a centre for studies of co-operatives and for the promotion of the co-operative culture which was founded over a century ago and re-launched at the beginning of the 1990s after a period of limbo and provides a meeting point for the four co-operative Centrali. Through the 16 « Luzzatti » the Italian co-operative movement, also with the support of the Ministry of Labour and Social Security, promotes research initiatives, debates on the co-operative reality and on the « Third sector » in general. Over the course of recent years, on behalf of the Ministry of Labour, the Institute has also played an important role in the training of ministerial inspectors who supervise those co-operatives not belonging to any of the Centrali. 2.1.8 The « recovery » of firms in crisis in a co-operative form Amongst other things, law no. 49 of 27 February 1985 (so-called « Marcora’s law ») introduced important measures to support employment through the co-operative tool: in particular, the law provides for concessions for the employees of private industrial companies in crisis who set up a production and labour co-operative in which they invest their employees’ severance indemnity, for the purpose of taking over the company’s activities. In order to implement the law, finance companies have been established (the major one being Compagnia Finanziaria Industriale - CFI, sustained by the AGCI, the Confcooperative and the Legacoop), who participate (up to 49% and for a maximum of 10 years) in the risk capital of the new co-operative, and also provide them with soft loans for management in addition to careful safeguarding. Law 49/85 (which became operative in 1997) proved to be an effective tool in combating the increase in unemployment due to company crises and in involving the workers in the managerial responsibility for their own company and their own jobs. One of the most important results was the « rescuing » and re-launching of the Orlando shipyard in Leghorn through the setting up of six co-operatives to manage the different segments and phases of ship building activities. In 1996 the activity of the CFI came to a temporary halt due to a veto imposed by the European Commission, which was subsequently overcome by making some modifications to the regulations. The activity of the CFI over the ten years 1987-1997 is summarized in the following table: COMPAGNIA FINANZIARIA INDUSTRIALE Applications Participation Outpayments (millions) Turnover (millions) Jobs Created 1987 79 2 1988 112 10 1 608 9 345 15 150 138 150 61 1991 160 84 1992 171 95 1993 186 108 1994 209 115 41 30 534 48 436 63 686 70 616 81 950 92 215 102 847 109 544 132 923 56 521 239 924 319 754 361 212 379 850 315 4282 340 185 457 036 502 220 553 411 2 358 3 055 3 743 4 122 4 399 514 1989 134 1 841 1990 1995 226 126 4 647 1996 238 13 5 026 Source: CFI - The figures do not show the increase in values, but the total for each year More recently, thanks to an UNCI initiative, the Nuova Soficoop s.c.r.l. suss., was set up. Its launch (1996) coincided with the legal quarrel with the EU that we have already mentioned, and hence the new company was faced with difficulty in getting off the ground. The Nuova Soficoop presented two projects for financing: the « IMEC Industria Meccanica Esplosivistica Chimica », which foresees the creation of 38 jobs; and the « ELCA Produzioni Elettroniche e Service », which foresees the creation of 14 jobs. 2 This figure does not include the turnover of the two co-operatives whose shares were alienated over the course of the financial year and whose turnover in 1992 was ITL 55 556 million. 17 1997 253 145 5 569 2.1.9 Employment for young People Since 1986 a law has been in force law no. 44 of 28 February 1986, so-called « De Vito’s law ») for the specific support of employment for young people. In order to manage the facilities provided for by the law a company was created (Imprenditoria Giovanile S.p.A.) with capital provided by the Ministry of the Treasury, the CFI and the promotion funds set up by AGCI, Confcooperative and Legacoop (Generalfond, Fondosviluppo and Coopfond). IG operates using regional, national and community funds, by way of conventions with institutions, territorial bodies, economic organs and private subjects. It holds shares in the companies that it promotes, for which it also organizes the activities of training in supervision and control, in addition to offering subsidized credit. The balance of the activities of IG in 1998 can be summarized in the following figures: • • • • • • • • • • Turnover Administrative resources Liabilities for company subsidies Total value of programmes co-financed by the European Commission Business plans evaluated Projects approved Companies financed Of which already active Turnover of financed companies and assets New jobs 63 billion; 4 777 billion; 3 784 billion; 1 096 billion; 5 200 (unity); 1 300 (unity); 900 (unity); 750 (unity); 1 500 billion; 12 000 (unity). The rate of survival of the companies financed is 81%. Approximately 25% of these have assumed the form of co-operatives or small co-operatives. 2.1.10 The « promotion funds » Art. 11 of law no. 59 of 31 January 1992, entitled « New norms for co-operatives », institutes the « Mutual funds for the promotion and development of co-operatives », further disciplined by art. 12 of the same law. This is a long awaited measure, set up in the wake of selfpromotion and self-government of the co-operatives, but also one of important innovative significance. In fact, through these « funds », the law sanctions and institutionalizes the principle of « external mutuality », which consists primarily of earmarking part of the economic results achieved by the single co-operative for the development and promotion of the whole movement. In other words, it is an institute that recognizes, disciplines and provides incentives, at the same time imposing a univocal orientation in the dynamic sense on « promotion and development », the principle of inter-co-operative solidarity which has always inspired the co-operative initiative. The funds are managed by non-profit S.p.A. (Plc’s), whose major shareholders, with not less than an 80% stake, are the legally recognized representative Associations that promote the funds. « The social object - according to the law - must consist exclusively in the promotion and financing of new companies and of initiatives for the development of the co-operatives, with preference being given to programmes directed at technological innovation, at increasing employment and at the development of the Mezzogiorno ». 18 The sources of financing for the funds foreseen by the law, show the strong link that the law makes between the objective of the funds themselves and the « mutual requirements » prescribed by « Basevi’s law ». In fact, apart from the possibility of receiving state financing for implementing their projects and contributions from the private sector, the principal financial assets of the funds come from the transfer of the 3% of annual balance sheet profits from the co-operatives associated to their respective centrale and from the transmission of the residuary estate of the bankrupt co-operatives; and compliance with such norms is stated as a condition in order to maintain the right to legal tax facilities. These regulations can therefore be interpreted as the partial transfer of the mutual requirements contained in « Basevi’s law » from a company to an inter-company context: the capital that constitutes the fund is in fact a percentage of those profits which should be appropriated to the non distributable reserve of the co-operative; while the destination of the fund itself, modifying art. 26 of « Basevi’s law », that finally specifies in an unambiguous manner what is meant by «transmission for the purpose of social usefulness» of residuary cooperative estates. The institution of the « Mutual funds for the promotion and development of co-operatives » has brought about a significant improvement in quality for the Italian co-operative movement: it has explicitly and systematically directed its activity and its success at supporting the development and modernization of the companies involved, at creating new co-operatives, at supporting the economic and social growth of the lesser developed areas of the country, and at increasing employment. Lastly, with the institutionalization of « external mutuality », law 59/92 accentuated the true and modern significance of the « welfare function » constitutionally acknowledged to co-operative entrepreneurs by giving it a more concrete implementation. All four legally recognized co-operative Centrali have established their own mutual funds. The importance of this innovation in concrete terms (as well as in terms of principle, as we have seen) for development and employment can be demonstrated by a rapid examination of the results achieved by the funds of the two larger Centrali: Coopfond S.p.A., promoted by Legacoop, and Fondosviluppo S.p.A., promoted by Confcooperative. Broadly speaking, the funds operate as rotating funds (but not for interventions without security). The types of intervention are generally: • • • (temporary) participation in the risk capital of companies as a subsidizing member; fixed term loans; safeguarding of the companies promoted. Coopfond S.p.A. In its initial six years of activity (1993-1998) it collected funds for a total of ITL 196.5 billion from co-operatives belonging to Legacoop. The resources invested, net of operating expenses, amounted to ITL 183.3 billion, encompassing a complex series of operations, subdivided into areas of activity: typical activities (promotion of new companies, development of existing companies), absorbed ITL 102.3 billion, and « strategic participation », a further ITL 73.9 billion, while ITL 7.1 billion can be attributed to the first returns of capital, according to the principle of rotation, rigorously exercised by Coopfond. These resources were used to finance 79 promotion interventions, for a total investment of ITL 320.76 billion, of which Coopfond provided ITL 70.17 billion (ITL 50.9 billion in participation in risk capital and ITL 19.27 in loans); and 36 development interventions for a total investment of ITL 261.77 billion, of which ITL 39.27 billion was invested by Coopfond 19 (almost entirely in the form of loans). The total additional employment achieved with these interventions was 5 358, of which 3 121 in promotion initiatives and 2 237 in development. It is worth noting that of the total investments made, 18.8% was pledged directly by Coopfond, while the remaining 81.2% came from different sources: with a ratio of over 5 to 1 between direct liability and total investment. It should also be noted that the investments of Coopfond have progressively focused on the European Union objective areas (principally the Mezzogiorno): in six years the average absorbed annually by these areas was 52.4% of total investments, but in 1998 this percentage reached 80%. COOPFOND S.p.A. Funds raised (bn) Expenditure deliberated 1998 36.0 1997 1996 1995 1994 37.3 33.1 31.2 30.2 No. Investments Coopfond Employment interventions (mn.) quota (+ no. jobs) Promotion Development Total typical activities 1993 28.7 Strategic Participation Total 196.5 Total Returns (from development) Total interv. Deliber. Source: processing of Coopfond data 71 36 107 283 237 261 766 545 003 63 049 39 266 102 315 2 717 2 237 4 954 20 127 8 10 880 555 883 37 522 73 858 176 173 7 120 195 5 149 404 135 593 405 183 293 5 553 Fondosviluppo S.p.A. In the first five years of activity (1993-1997) it collected ITL 96 billion from co-operatives belonging to Confcooperative, ITL 22.79 billion of which during 1997. It provided ITL 24.61 billion in risk capital for companies, granted financing of ITL 14.45 billion and invested a further ITL 26.97 billion in « other initiatives ». The total combined workforce of the companies in which Coopfond intervened is 4 034, showing a net increase of 1 000 workers. FONDOSVILUPPO S.p.A. Funds raised (bn) 96 Participation (bn) 25 Financing (bn) 15 Other initiatives (bn) 27 Total interventions (bn) 67 Employment (total) 4 034 Employment (additional) (ca.) 1 000 Source: processing of Fondosviluppo data 20 2.1.11 Credit and insurance In Italy, as in other European countries, there is a widespread network of co-operative banks. Of the two types of co-operative banks, one, the people’s banks, underwent a juridical and structural evolution which distanced it from the co-operative movement some time ago, while the other, the co-operative credit bank (ex-Casse rurali e artigiane, the equivalent to the Raiffeisen banks in German-speaking countries) has maintained its co-operative characteristics and almost all of them (581 banking institutions with over half a million members, operating with deposits and fiduciary funds of over ITL 98 000 billion) belong to the Confcooperative. The presence of the co-operative credit banks, particularly in some areas of the country, performs an important function of financial support for the co-operatives and is, in turn, made more solid and dynamic by the actions of the central credit institute for the category, ICCREA. The co-operatives belonging to Legacoop, in turn, avail themselves of Unipol, an insurance company which is controlled by a group of co-operatives. Unipol operates in all fields of insurance (damages, life, car, and recently also health policies via its sister-company Unisalute) and has, over the years, risen to an important position in the Italian insurance panorama. Unipol’s capital comes not only from co-operatives, but also other entities both Italian (trade unions, sector associations for artisans, retailers, farmers, Reale Mutua insurance company, Cassa di Risparmio di Bologna, Banca Agricola Mantovana) and foreign (including the French health insurance funds Maif and Macif, the German insurance group R+V, the Swedish Folksam and the Belgian group P&V). Unipol is also quoted on the stock exchange. In turn, Unipol controls a 60% share of the capital of the ex-Banca dell'Economia Cooperativa based in Bologna, which has recently taken on the name Unipol Banca and has an ambitious project to extend its branches over the entire country. The company is also active in the field of cultural activities: it established the Fondazione Cesar, which in addition to dealing with matters related to insurance, conducts research into the development and prospects of the welfare economy. 2.1.12 Temporary work Law 196/97 introduced the institution of temporary work in Italy, a practice common in other European countries for many years. The measure is aimed at facilitating the matching of demand and supply of labour, also in cases in which the needs of the firms do not lead to permanent employment: the desired effect is that of contributing both to greater efficiency in the utilization of productive factors and to increasing employment. The law strictly defines the opportunities and procedures for the practice of temporary work, for the protection of the workers. The « hiring out » of labour to firms in temporary need must be done through companies disciplined by the law who have obtained specific authorization. Since the publication of the law, the co-operative movement, too, has decided to equip itself with a tool for participating in the management of temporary work: a project formulated in collaboration with co-operatives and other subjects of the welfare economy has led to the creation of a company supplying temporary work called Obiettivo Lavoro, in partnership with the Dutch foundation, Start, a non-profit agency for temporary work. Obiettivo Lavoro is a co-operative with about 300 members, the majority of them firms, with a capital of over ITL 9 billion. Obiettivo Lavoro has 60 branches and operational offices throughout the country and has 120 counters co-ordinated by the headquarters in Milan. It is obliged, by the social 21 statute and ethical code adopted, to reinvest profits in training and in other initiatives for the advantage of temporary workers. In the first 16 months of activity it sent roughly 10 000 people out to work, with an average length of placement of over seven weeks. At the end of the contract, one worker in five was then employed on a permanent basis by the contracting firm. 2.2 Non-Co-operative Entities 2.2.1 Regulatory scope of the « Third sector » in Italy In terms of law requirements, similar considerations apply to non-co-operative entities as those applicable to co-operatives. This is because no organic or specific rules have been provided for under the laws of Italy to regulate non-profit-making organizations as commonly described in economic and sociological terms. Even the concept of « socially useful nonprofit-making organizations » (ONLUS in Italian) underlying the recent legislation identifies less a new set of legal persons subject to the general law than a tax-relevant category. Still, it is possible to outline the loose set of legal (especially tax-related) provisions all or most of these organizations are subject to. In the Italian law system: a) No organic body of laws has ever existed to govern non-profit-making operations, as much as the debate about, and the attention given to, the « Third sector » have brought about a cross-industry tax legislation applicable to the whole set of socially useful nonprofit-making entities. Accordingly, appropriate civil-law provisions are needed to regulate this area, or, at least, Book I of the Civil Code - for long the object of many amendments in the past - should finally be revised. b) Under the Italian Constitution, regional governments are expected to regulate certain matters - e.g. charities, health and educational services, vocational training, etc. - which coincide with non-profit organizations’ typical activities. c) Another peculiarity of the Italian law system is the firmly established tradition, asserted by even constitutional rules, of the close relationships between the State and religious denominations. These relationships are regulated by special « covenants » differentiating the ways in which the non-profit organizations of each denomination are treated under the law. d) A peculiar set of interlacing public and private interests is found to prevail in many entities operating in typically non-profit domains. The Italian system of public governance through public corporations has long been characterised both by individual groups’ participation in the management of public corporations and by the formation or transformation of associative public corporations. e) Various forms of family solidarity are especially favoured. f) Social co-operation, a typical occurrence in the Italian system, tends to be specifically encouraged (see also hereabove). g) In Italy, unlike other countries, non-profit-making ventures originated by political parties, labour unions or religious denominations exist, as a rule, without any formal legal correlation with their originators - a condition that may well be referred to as « collateralism in fact ». 22 On the basis of the latest, most widely known studies on the non-profit sector, some major common traits can be identified in most non-profit-making organizations, each of which can, therefore, be described as an entity that: a) has been formally established, i.e. set up under a memorandum of association, a by-law or any other document regulating its membership and its members’ behaviours and mutual relationships, its legal form and other relevant characteristics; b) has a legal status as a private entity, in the sense that it must be not part of the public sector; c) is self-governing, i.e. it shall not be controlled, in carrying out its decision-making process, by any organization belonging to either the public sector or the sector of profitmaking businesses; d) is subject to a non-distribution constraint, i.e. to the absolute prohibition to distribute earnings to its partners, members or employees, whether directly or indirectly, under an obligation to re-invest any profit it may make in its own activities - the feature most widely shared by non-profit-making organizations. This amounts to the non-profit concept itself. If the entity involved has performed business operations or received donations, none of its surplus assets can be distributed to either its members or its founder(s) upon winding-up, this being another unavoidable condition for defining the « solidaristic », non-profit-making quality of any such organization; and e) can accommodate voluntary work contributions, i.e. labour services which are not paid and in respect of which only any expenses as incurred and evidenced and insurance payments are refunded. Other features of the non-profit-making organizations are: a social purpose, the presence of voluntary workers, an egalitarian, participatory ethos, and the separation between finance contributors and end-consumers. 2.2.2 Fluid notion of the non-co-operative « Third-sector » in Italy Within the domain of non-profit-making organizations proper in Italy, even the terms and conceptual notions currently applied to non-profit-making operations still remain fluid, as the following summary discussion will show. a) Voluntary action (Ascoli3). There is a school of thought in our country that opposes the definitions offered above, rejects the very notion of non-profit organizations as a separate sector of society, and maintains that the term « voluntary action » should be used instead. « Volunteers » are taken to be « all those who freely offer their services without pay in publicly-run or voluntary organizations engaged in various welfare activities ». In this view, such terms as « Third sector », « third dimension » or « privato sociale » (private welfare) are primarily limited by the fact that the terms « sector » or « system » ought only to be used at a very high level of abstraction. This is because the aims and characteristics of the entities these words are intended to refer to appear to be too different from one another, and their autonomy from the public sector is purported to be exceedingly weak. Even the term « private welfare » is thought to be misleading in that it appears to put together widely differing associative realities under the same umbrella. b) Civil economy (Zamagni4). The advocates of this term use it to describe an approach that, though existing within the market, draws its legitimation from needs and standards 3 Ascoli U., Azione volontaria e welfare state, Bologna, 1987. Zamagni S., « Il non profit della società postfordista alla ricerca di una nuova identità » in Vittadini G., Il non profit dimezzato, Milano, 1997; Zamagni S., « Economia civile come forza di civilizzazione per la società 4 23 expressed by the civil society and the ruling principle of which is not trade, but reciprocity. The State has the task to create suitable conditions for the market to exist. According to Zamagni, « a market economy adequate to account for the welfare needs of such a post-Fordist society as our own must be able to walk on both legs of the private economy and the civil economy. The principle underlying the former is an exchange between peers, that underlying the latter is reciprocity ». The civil economy concerns itself with the production and distribution of goods (e.g. personal services) of a kind that cannot be framed within the customary market laws. c) Solidaristic economy (Revelli). It is thought that the failure of the former balance between the State and the market, and the gradual shrinking of the « wealth redistribution » sphere can be overcome by re-activating that third loop of « reciprocity » and « solidarity » that has certainly become barren and dried up in the course of the 20th century. This can be done by substituting, not the dissipative model of utility (the market), but the connective model of symmetricalness for that of « centrality » (of the national State). The « solidaristic economy » somehow runs parallel with the market economy, and exhibits the following basic components: the segment’s consciously voluntary dimension, its reference to social links maintained through the conduct of economic activities, a common « doing » intended to transform the community’s existence, and, above all, the opening-up of self-contained public spaces deriving rather from « reciprocity-regulated » processes than from pecuniary or administrative powers.5 d) Privato sociale (private welfare) (Donati6). This term, along with the term « volontariato » (voluntary work), is only widely used in our national context. The existence and purport of the privato sociale system can only be grasped in view of a sociological theory based on two basic assumptions. First, society is viewed as a dynamic entity revolving around four hubs — the State, the market, private welfare, and primary networks. Secondly, the fact is acknowledged that society is based on the production and exchange of four types of goods: public goods produced by the State, private goods produced by the market, collective relational goods produced by private welfare, and primary relational goods produced by primary networks. The development of the nonprofit sector involves a process whereby private welfare organizations are included as fully entitled holders of rights in the citizenship complex. This development is expected to make for the extension of individual citizens’ personal rights to intermediate social formations, these being, in the author’s opinion, the only entities that permit the full civic inclusion of individuals within society. e) Third dimension (introduced by Ardigò7). According to Ardigò, this term includes « a plurality of practices and behaviours which have in common the expression of an autonomy, a non-alienated experiential conduct and life worlds that have held back their delegation to the social system and lost confidence in the political, economic and sociocultural sub-systems ». Such a plurality of practices include modes of action which go from the grey, hidden economy to the collaborative management of service provision by public corporations and social co-operatives; from forms of local-level communal intermediation between providers and consumers to mutual-aid actions; and from organised voluntary actions to the expression of solidarity. The term is not so much referred to a well-defined domain, with boundaries of its own, as empirically referred to relational modes and practices based on reciprocity, solidarity, co-operation, and shared values. italiana » in Donati P., La società civile in Italia, Milano, 1997. Revelli M., La sinistra sociale, Torino, 1997. 6 Donati P., Risposte alla crisi dello stato sociale, Milano, 1984; Donati P., Sociologia del terzo settore, Roma, 1996. 7 Ardigò A., « Volontariato, welfare state e terza dimensione », in La ricerca sociale, n. 25, 1981. 5 24 f) Third sector (Bassanini and Ranci8). This term is used to indicate private practices and organizations which are intended to produce and allocate goods or services of a public or communal interest. The sociological approach highlights the altruistic value and orientation of the activities personally carried out by the entities concerned. The economic approach highlights the value of these activities in terms of participation in determining the collective good, so that this sector can be clearly distinguished from the market sector in that its aims are not profit or gain-related. g) Third system (Ruffolo, Borzaga, Gui9). This term was first introduced and developed in the business environment, and later adopted as a self-definition and self-description by the most highly organized component of the non-profit-making solidaristic realm, i.e. the social co-operatives. The term is used to convey both the entrepreneurial role and the socio-economic role that non-profit-making organizations as a whole have to play in any given social formation. 2.2.3 Special relevance of the non-profit sector to employment In 1991, the organizations in the non-profit sector as a whole in Italy employed about 418 000 people (measured in full-time equivalent terms, whereby two part-time employees are taken to be equivalent to one full-time employee), accounting for 1.8% of total jobs nation-wide. Still in full-time equivalent terms, about 273 000 voluntary workers, 15 000 conscientious objectors and 16 000 persons seconded and paid by their employers were estimated to work for organizations in the non-profit sector. When these voluntary workers are added to the number of paid workers, the proportion of the non-profit sector is found to increase considerably up to 3% of the country’s total employment and 4.9% of all the employed in the service industry (Table 1). Table 1: Employed and voluntary workers in the non-profit sector Employed Voluntary (1) (2) Absolute value (standard labour units) Percentage of employment (standard labour units) of total economy of service industry 418 128 1.8% 2.0% 302 950 1.3% 2.1% (1) + (2) 721 078 3.0% 4.9% Another dimensional indicator is the ratio of the non-profit sector’s current expenditure (then to the exclusion of capital expenses) to the gross domestic product (GDP). As the non-profit sector’s total running expenses approximately equalled ITL 27 000 billion, its contribution to the GDP would account for 1.9%. Again in this case, the amount arrived at in the Italian case appears to be lower than those recorded in the other countries regarded by the survey as being in line with the relevant employment figures. 8 Bassanini M.C. and Ranci P., « Non per profitto. Il settore dei progetti che erogano servizi di interesse collettivo senza scopo di lucro », in Quaderni Fondazione Olivetti, 1990. 9 Ruffolo G. « Il terzo sistema: per riequilibrare la società », in Impresa sociale, n. 29, 1996; Borzaga C., « Il terzo sistema. Una nuova dimensione della complessità economica e sociale », Padova, 1991; Gui B., « Le organizzazione produttive private senza scopo di lucro. Un inquadramento concettuale », in Economia Pubblica, n. 4-5, 1987. 25 Table 2 gives an idea of the relative weight of the different classes - then of the different operating areas - of non-profit-making organizations. Though each class has a different weight depending on the variable being considered (employed workers, voluntary workers, expenses or value added), five of them account for more than 90% of the sector regardless of the variable considered: social services, education and research, employers’ and trade-unions’ associations, health, and culture and leisure. The remaining 5 groups have a just marginal weight. The 3 classes of social services, health and education alone account more than 75% of all jobs in the non-profit sector. The last column in Table 2 specifies the share of the total added value generated by each class of the non-profit sector. The welfare services class is found to be the most significant group, followed by education and research. Table 2: A breakdown of employed workers, voluntary workers, expenses and value added by activity in the non-profit sector Employed Voluntary Expense Value Value Total added added value Employe Voluntary added d Percentage of total non-profit sector Culture & leisure 6.3 30.3 11.4 6.1 31.3 16.2 Education & research 28.5 9.2 20.7 27.3 9.5 20.1 Health care 14.1 12.8 17.8 16.9 16.4 16.7 Welfare services 33.4 35.3 21.4 22.3 25.3 23.5 Environment 0.2 1.6 0.2 0.1 0.6 0.3 Local communities 4.5 2.9 1.6 1.8 1.3 1.6 Civil rights 2.1 1.7 2.3 2.5 2.2 2.4 Philanthropic interme0.5 0.1 0.9 0.4 0.1 0.3 diaries International activities 1.4 1.5 1.7 1.5 1.7 1.6 Professional and trade 8.8 4.5 22.0 21.1 11.7 17.3 associations Non-profit sector 100 100 100 100 100 100 In carrying out their operations, non-profit-making organizations, in addition to paying their employees, purchase the necessary equipment and buildings, and expendable goods and services for current use, and directly distribute money in the form of transfers. The one-butlast line of Table 3, accounting for a breakdown of expenditure in the entire non-profit sector, shows that more than one half of the sector’s total costs and expenses is accounted for by personnel expenses, about 7% by capital expenses (movable and immovable assets purchased to be used over a number of years) and 40% by other expenses. This analysis reveals the peculiar character of this sector as a highly labour-intensive industry because of these organizations’ activities typically involving personal services (health care, welfare, leisure) requiring comparatively moderate capital investments. 26 Table 3: A percentage breakdown of the non-profit sector’s expenses Personnel Capex expenses Percentage of total expenditure Culture & leisure 27.9 9.4 Education & research 69.1 4.4 Health care 49.6 16.3 Welfare services 54.6 3.3 Environment 22.4 4.3 Local communities 57.9 4.5 Civil rights 59.0 3.3 Philanthropic intermediaries 21.0 6.8 International activities 47.3 30.0 Professional and trade associations 50.1 3.7 Variation coefficient (standard deviation) Non-profit sector – professional and trade associations excluded 0.342 52.3 52.9 0.942 7.1 8.1 Other expenses 62.9 26.5 34.2 42.1 73.3 37.6 37.7 72.3 22.7 46.2 0.376 40.6 39.0 2.2.4 Types of non-profit-making entities A recent work of the association Lunaria (Lunaria, 1998) proposed seven criteria to identify (non-profit), « Third sector » organizations (TSO), starting from the definition adopted by the Johns Hopkins University (Salomon and Anheier, 1996) and trying to capture the peculiarity of the Third system as producer of social utility (also according to the recent Italian law on Onlus, non-profit organization of social utility, decree 460/1997). According to this set of criteria a « Third sector » organization should be: 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. formal: institutionalized to some extent; private: institutionally separate from government; non-profit distributing: not returning profits neither directly nor indirectly; self-governing/ independent: equipped to control and to govern its own activities; democratic: « Third sector » organizations should have a democratic structure; voluntary to some significant extent: involving some meaningful degree of voluntary participation; 7. providing social utility: engaged in activities of social solidarity and working for social promotion. According to this definition, it can be said that in Italy belong to the (non-profit) Third system: • • • • • associations, and in particular social associations (the latter waiting for the next to receive a legislative frame); foundations (not the banking ones); voluntary organizations (disciplined by the law 266/91); non governmental organizations (disciplined by the law 49/87); social co-operatives (disciplined by the law 381/91). 27 Public institutions, commercial business (excluding the co-operatives), political parties and movements, trade unions and professional associations are therefore excluded by the Third system. The analysis of the Third system in Italy depends upon the examination of the three fundamental Italian laws on TSO: • law 266/1991 on voluntary organizations; • law 381/1991 on social co-operatives; • decree 460/1997 on ONLUS (Non-profit organizations of social utility). The legislation on voluntary organizations and social co-operatives covers the main features of these institutions and introduces a range of facilities to promote their development and to simplify the management of their activities. ONLUS have been introduced to spur the development of the Italian non-profit sector. The law aims at defining a complex framework of rules, facilities and opportunities for all the agents involved in the « Third sector ». Actually a non-profit organizations for social utility is not a specific organization of its own, but it defines the fiscal status of « Third sector » agents and the voluntary organizations and social co-operatives regulated respectively by law 266/1991 and law 381/1991 as well as other institutions such as associations and foundations could be considered ONLUS. In connection with the Italian legal system, it is useful to stress that non-profit-making organizations have no specific legal status of their own. As no unified typology can be identified, non-profit organizations in Italy are acknowledged to belong to one or another class of legal persons provided for by the civil code, or to some other figures subject to special law requirements. Table A: Legal forms under the Civil Code Approved Associations Foundations Non-approved Associations Committees Co-operatives Civil Code, Art. 14, ff. Civil Code, Art. 14, ff. Civil Code, Art. 36, ff. Civil Code, Art. 39, ff. Civil Code, Art. 2511, ff. In addition to the civil code provisions applicable to legally approved and non-approved entities, specific supplemental regulations apply to each of the different classes of nonprofit-making organizations, under the proviso that the following table is by no means intended to provide an exhaustive listing of all non-profit-making bodies that exist in Italy. 28 Table B: Non-profit-making entities subject to special regulatory provisions Voluntary-work organizations Act 266, 11 Aug.1991 Social co-operatives Act 381, 8 Nov. 1991 Ecclesiastic agencies Acts 206 & 222, 20 May 1985 Banking foundations Act 218, 30 July 1990, and Delegated Act 461, 23 December 1998 Friendly societies Act 3818, 15 Apr. 1886 Public relief and charity institutions Act 6972, 17 July 1890 – IPAB (and privatized IPABs) Public opera and music corporations Legislative decree 367, 29 June 1996 A) Associations and Foundations Associations and foundations are still regulated by the Civil Code (C.C.) dated back to 1942 and, differently from what happens for voluntary organizations and social co-operatives, no specific law has been introduced about them. B) Social co-operatives Social co-operatives, regulated by the law 381/91, represent the most original legal form of the Italian « Third sector ». Act 381/91 is an important piece of legislation in two respects. First – in the case of Type A social co-operatives – because it is an attempt to spur the dissemination of mixed experiments in voluntary and co-operative work, with paid employees and unpaid voluntary workers, in providing social and educational services. Secondly – in the case of Type B social cooperatives – because it provides for the compulsory placement of disadvantaged people into the productive system, thus making them accountable for their own work. 29 Facilities and perspectives for social co-operatives introduced by the law 381/1991: - towards disadvantaged workers: - towards tax reliefs: - the exemption from the payment of contributions for the social insurance; - reduction of the VAT rate (fixed to 4% in the 1998) for the A type co-operatives; - exemption from the taxes on donations or inheritances; - several forms of exemption from the income taxes (or other facilities, as for instance, lower rates, easier deductibility of costs, etc.). As for voluntary organizations, these facilities can be extended by the ONLUS regulation. Economic and employment dimension of social co-operatives Social co-operatives represent the « entrepreneurial » component of the Third system in Italy and they seem to be the subject of the Italian « Third sector » more capable of stimulating the growth of employment and at the same time of answering, mainly in terms of personalization of social performances, to old and recent social needs, left unfulfilled by the contextual crash of market and traditional state intervention. In the following Table the distribution of social co-operatives on a type scale is shown: Typology distribution of social co-operatives, 1996 Ministry of Labour absolute percentage values values Type A co-operatives 2,298 59.7 Type B co-operatives 1,326 34.5 mixed co-operatives and consortiums 223 5.8 Total 3,847 100 According to the data of the Ministry of Labour, in 1996 the number of social co-operatives has increased from 2 126 units to 3 857 units. The growing professionalisation of the activity is confirmed by the growth of employment in A type and in B type co-operatives and by the decrease of the number of volunteers. According to the data from the inspection minutes of the central co-operatives, between 1992 and 1993 the average number of employees grew by 1.8% in A type co-operatives and by 0.7% in B type co-operatives, and between 1993 and 1994 by 1.8% in A type co-operatives and by 0.5% in B type co-operatives. The average number of employees amount to 29 working units in A type co-operatives against 27 in B type co-operatives. The data shown in table 3 show the two very important variables for the economic and employment in social co-operatives10. 10 The determination of the number of paid and unpaid member of social co-operative presented some problems, 30 Social basis and labour force of social co-operatives, 1994 and 1996 Ministry of Head Co-operatives Labour absolute averag absolute average number values e values of cases Total members 118 472 30.7 66 363 49.6 1 337 from whom volunteers 10 857 2.8 3 542 2.9 1 225 Paid personnel (members and not 33 410 26.0 1 282 members) from whom disadvantaged people 15 746 11.8 3 005 10.8 278 Source: Centro Studi CGM, 1997 C) Voluntary organizations Thanks to the law 266/91, voluntary organizations received a legal status and a specific regulation, as well as the opportunity to benefit from a regime of tax benefits. Section 1 specifies that purpose of the Italian State is to promote the development of this organizations, to pace their autonomy and to stimulate their original contribution in the achievement of social, civil and cultural aims. Besides, it fixes « ground rules » which regions must stick to in order to regulate the relationships between public institutions and voluntary organizations, as well as the criteria that regions and local councils must comply with regarding the same relationships. A voluntary activity must meet the following requirement, as defined in the second section: • the absence of profit-making purposes; • the commitments of voluntary workers personal, spontaneous and unpaid; • the implementation of activities must be directed towards the pursuit of social solidarity. Under these essential conditions, we can classify as voluntary organizations those organizations set up for carrying out activities centred on the personal, voluntary and unpaid engagement of its adherents. Although the law gives voluntary organizations the freedom of choosing the most suitable legal status, with the sole limit of it being compatible with the solidarity purpose, it explicitly requires that the statute include some crucial elements: • the presence of non-profit and solidarity aims; • the condition of member as well as the services provided by them must be gratuitous (for voluntary workers the law takes into account only the reimbursement of expenses); • the will of organizing itself as a democratic structure; • the criteria for admission and exclusion of members, as well as their duties and rights; as the Ministry of Labour does not calculate the paid personnel, and for the way the paid personnel of the social co-operatives is calculated. Part-time workers are calculated as full-time equivalent, so that two part-times correspond to a full-time (Centro studi CGM, 1997). 31 • the duty of drawing up the balance sheet, in which all the assets, the subscriptions and the donations received must be included. All these conditions make an organization eligible for its enrolment in specific registers managed by the regions. The registration is a necessary pre-requisite in order to have access to public contributions, to stipulate agreements with regional and local corporations, to accept voluntary subscriptions and charitable donations and to benefit from tax reliefs. If the registration is denied by the regions, voluntary organizations have the right to apply to the regional administrative court. Indeed, a significant part of the law is dedicated to the agreements between voluntary organizations and regional and local authorities. These agreements must ensure the existence of essential conditions for the systematic implementation of voluntary activities, as well as for the respect of users rights. They must also provide for the check-up of the activities, the quality of services as well as of the procedures for the reimbursement of expenses. Lastly, the regions are responsible for making the principles contained in the law 261 executive and appropriate to the specific circumstances. Regarding the personnel engaged in these organizations, the law allows for the recruitment of wage-earning employees only if their role is instrumental to the regular performance of the organization or it is required to qualify and specialize voluntary activity. Besides, the condition of voluntary worker is not compatible with any paid job done in the same organization. Voluntary organizations must insure their adherents against injury at work, as well as against third party liabilities. Strong attention is paid to those volunteers who have « regular » job outside the organizations: they can benefit from special working time flexibility in order to carry out voluntary activities. With regard to economic resources, voluntary organizations can accept adherents subscriptions, private contributions, national grants, international institutions aids, donations, testamentary legacies and reimbursements from agreements provided that those are used for the implementation of voluntary activities. Revenues from industrial and commercial activities can also be addressed to the regular performance of voluntary organization only if they come from activities considered « marginal » by the organization. If the organization decides to dissolve or to close down, all the assets remaining after the winding-up, must be handed over to similar organizations. The relevant piece of legislation also provides for the building of a nationwide observatory of the voluntary-work environment and the institution of an appropriate fund. The fund for the voluntary world should be used for the funding of projects promoted by the organization. 32 Finally, the law considers the possibility of setting up at regional level special funds whose resources are addressed to the creation of service centres for supporting voluntary organizations in their activities. Facilities and perspectives for voluntary organizations The facilities introduced by the law 266/1991 are: - towards volunteers: - towards tax reliefs: - towards fund-raising: - the possibility for the organizations to draw up collective insurance (accident, health, third party liabilities) adopting simplified mechanisms; - the right for volunteers to obtain flexible forms of working timetable to facilitate their voluntary activity. - the exemption from the taxes put on the constitution of the organization; - the exemption from Value Added Tax (VAT); - the exemption from the taxes on donations or inheritances; - the exemption from the income tax. - donations to voluntary organizations are partially considered deductible contributions; - voluntary organizations will also be supported by a public funding system at national and local level. All these facilities can be extended by the ONLUS regulation. Economic dimension and employment Among the great number of definitions recently created of the word « volunteer » there is « person who spend part of his time and energy in a citizen project (humanitarian, social, ecological, educational), without any wage, with no profit purpose and for people sake » (definition from the general assembly of European Youth forum, Brussels). This phenomenon seems to increase and it seems to be object of studies and attention during the last years; associations, foundations and co-operatives based on voluntary work are developing in great number. The dimension of work in voluntary organizations in Italy is shown in the following tables, based on F.i.vol.’s 1997 report (F.i.vol.: Italian Voluntary Service Foundation). They studied, trough a questionnaire, a sample of 10 542 organizations; they find 3.1 millions people working in these organizations in different ways and with different tasks; expanding this result on the known organizations they estimated a total of 3.7 millions of workers; it corresponds to the 9.2% of resident adult population. 33 Quality differences between one kind of voluntary action and another are otherwise definable according to motivations, forms and objectives of action itself. Some motivations can be defined in this way: - psychological: participating in an action felt of general interest and utility provide satisfaction and increase volunteers’ self-esteem; relational: volunteer is involved in different relations, with users, with other operators, with institutions and different people in general; ideological: sharing the aims of the group is one of the main motivation to start activities, aims can be social, political or moral; formative: often the volunteer acquires knowledge and professionalism that he can be spent later in the labour market. Details on Voluntary World: the sex factor The dimension of voluntary work in Italy Type of workers Organizations in the sample Expansion to all the Voluntary Organizations (estimate) Active volunteers * 334 723 400 000 Part time volunteers 2 750 777 3 300 000 Conscientious objectors 4 322 5 000 Waged workers 6 008 7 000 Total 3 095 830 3 712 000 * Active volunteer means « person working with non-profit aims, in a permanent and operative way » Source: FIVOL, 1997 Gender female male Source: FIVOL, 1997 % 49.9 50.1 Details on Voluntary World: the time factor age factor Hours per week % until 5 56.3 from 6 to 10 25.9 from 11 to 15 9.6 more than 15 8.2 Details on Voluntary World: the Age Less than 18 From 18 to 29 From 30 to 45 From 46 to 65 more than 65 Source: FIVOL, 1997 Source: FIVOL, 1997 34 % 3.0 27.4 32.1 29.1 8.4 Details on Voluntary World: the status factor Activities employed unemployed % 45.4 8.7 pensioners housewives students Source: FIVOL, 1997 18.8 12.9 14.3 Details on Voluntary World: the education factor Studies % Basic school degree 7.9 medium school 33.6 degree High school degree 44.1 University degree 14.4 Source: FIVOL, 1997 D) An Italian peculiarity: IPABs on the borderline between the public sector profit-making organizations and non- IPABs-Istituzioni pubbliche di assistenza e beneficenza (public relief and charity institutions), formerly « Opere Pie » (religious charitable institutions), are « public » not because of a « historical accident » (i.e. the Crispi Act of 1890 designed to laicize the Opere Pie and to make them subject - as local, non-territorial public corporations - to government supervision by the Prefects), but as a result of specific choices made by the newly unified liberal State which was: (a) hostile to « intermediate bodies » (as was its successor, the fascist regime, in the case of entities outside its corporative scheme); and (b) resolute to build a state administration which was merely designed as a support to government’s power, rather than (not even at a local level) a self-regulated civil service organization intended to take planned actions on social and economic matters. An approach has been taken in the last 20 years or so to provide some measure of « reprivatization » of IPABs through a number of legislative actions and court orders. The present condition of the « IPAB environment » There were 5 500/6 000 IPABs formally existing in 1997. About one thousand IPAB public corporations disappeared in the twenty years from 1977 to 1996, one half of them following extinction (or take-overs by merger), and the remaining one half as a result of reprivatization. It has been estimated that about one thousand IPABs provide actual sheltering services, less than one thousand run crèches or nursery schools, and about 3 000 provide « sundry » services. « Inactive » IPABs or IPABs otherwise having limited (or now negligible) economic dimensions are less than one thousand. The geographical breakdown of IPABs can be summarized as follows: 61% in the North, 20% in the Centre, and 19% in the South. When these figures for the IPABs are tentatively compared with those for the 19 512 voluntary work associations, it can be noted that: • • each IPAB is matched by at least three voluntary action associations country-wide; and in terms of geographical areas, the ratio of IPABs to voluntary associations points to a greater proportion of IPABs in the North, and to a greater proportion of voluntary associations in the Centre (fully in line with the well-known long-established local corporative and solidaristic tradition in this area). 35 If IPAB « numbers » are further roughly compared with those of private foundations (originally recognized as such) engaged in the welfare sector (just a few hundreds in the 1972 CIRIEC survey) and with those of the private foundations recognized by regional administrations in the 1972-1996 period (about 500), as well as with those of the IPABs of a non-associative type re-privatized in 1990 through 1996 (a few hundreds), the resulting proportion is found to be four IPABs for each private welfare foundation. When looking at the total proportion of the IPABs (taken as local entities of the public welfare sector to the exclusion of municipalities and « municipal institutions » as provided for in Act 142 of 1990) to the non-profit-making welfare organizations, the resulting figure is estimated to stand around one quasi-public IPAB against four non-profit-making entities. Finally, it is appropriate to point out that the IPABs have, at least for the time being, been declared ineligible to the benefits provided for in the legislative decree on the ONLUS. 2.2.5 Employment and the non-profit « Third sector » Problems of analysis During the last years many authors have underlined the main role the « Third sector » can play in the development of new economic patterns and therefore in the creation of new employment opportunities. Nevertheless an analysis of work in the « Third sector » is not simple. The « Third sector » is in fact a very heterogeneous and fragmentary world and non-profit organizations differ for dimensions, aims, activity, structures, economic resources, cultural and political trends. The most complete analysis of employment in the research conducted by the Johns Hopkins University (Barbetta, 1996) on the larger world of the non-profit. The main results emerging from this research are: • the lower employment contribution of the Italian Third system in comparison with the other countries under study; • the great concentration of non-profit organizations in the welfare services sector, demonstrated by the fact that the three groups active in the health, education and social services cover 75% of the total number of employees in all the « Third sector ». Employment in the non-profit sector % on total employees % on employees in services 15.4 10.0 9.4 10.4 8.6 5.5 3.0 United States 6.8 France 4.2 United Kingdom 4.0 Germany 3.7 Japan 2.5 Italy 1.8 Hungary 0.8 Source: Salamon and Anheier, 1994 But such data do not suggest any clear evaluation on employment opportunities in the Third system. 36 Many authors, looking at this data suggest that in Italy the « Third sector » could grow till reaching at least the average of the other industrialized countries, not considering the difference of the Italian Welfare mix in comparison with the other European countries. In Italy most of the services provided from non-profit organizations, first of all in the fields of health, education and social services, are still offered by the public sector. Based on this last consideration, F. Scalvini has clearly warned against an exceedingly optimistic view of any contribution to employment as may be expected from non-profit organizations in Italy (See F. Scalvini, « Terzo settore, lavoro, occupazione », in N. Iovene and M. Viezzoli, Il libro del Terzo settore, pp. 182, ff., Abnkronos Libri, Rome, 1999). Another element very important to sustain the thesis of employment potential in the « Third sector » is the fact that employment in this sector has generally grown faster than in the rest of the economy. The dimension of the non-profit and the « Third sector » charities in Italy: a comparison between the two definitions Non-profit (JHU) « Third ∆% sector » (Lunaria) Number of TSO 53 816 51 611 - 4% Workers 418 128 254 003 - 39% Volunteers 272 861 267 487 - 2% Conscientious objectors 14 529 13 708 - 6% Total personnel 705 518 535 198 - 24% Average number of personnel for 13 10 - 23% TSO Volunteers/total personnel 0.4 0.5 + 25% Total expenses for personnel units * 54 41 - 24% *ITL Millions. Source: our elaboration on Pianta (1997) The expansive trend of employment in the « Third sector » has been confirmed by a research that Lunaria has conducted in the summer 1996 on a sample of 60 organizations - the majority of them were social co-operatives - concentrated in the Northern and Central areas of Italy. The organizations examined were divided in seven fields: welfare, environment, civil rights, culture, international solidarity, sport, fair trade. Welfare comprehends social and health assistance, personal and community services, activities for social inclusion. Within civil rights there are civic organizations on migration, on antiracism. 37 Trend of employment for TSO by field of activity (%) Fields of positive stable negative activity Fair-trade 60 40 0 Environment 60 20 20 Sport 50 50 0 Culture 45.4 45.4 9.2 Welfare 42.9 57.1 0 International 37.5 50 12.5 solidarity Civil rights 20 60 20 Source: Lunaria (1998) total 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 The end of the State monopoly left room for new entrepreneurial initiatives. As many authors already explained (Borzaga, 1996; Ruffolo, 1997; Gui,1997; Zamagni, 1998) social enterprises for their characteristics are the best agents to occupy such room. Social enterprises are real economic initiatives, and this differentiates them from the other Third system organizations, with the remuneration of all factors of production, the most relevant of which is, as we talk about services, labour. A clear confirmation of such trend comes from the only certain data about employment in the Social economy: the creation exnovo of 80 000 job places in social co-operative (CGM 1997). As a conclusion, for many scholars, social enterprise creates employment because is active in fields with a « normal », physiological employment growth. But besides the quantitative ones, there are also qualitative elements which characterize employment in the Social economy. The relationship between worker and the « employer » is necessarily very different from the traditional sectors. Social enterprise are generally democratic structure where workers participate in the decisions taken by the organization. Other peculiar aspect is the combination and interaction between paid work and voluntary actions. All this leads to a great demand of flexibility, dynamism, informality and participation. The great difficulty is to regulate a social enterprise in order to assure, on one hand, the principle rights of the people involved in the organization (employees, volunteers, beneficiaries) and, on the other, the necessary flexibility and dynamism, pivot variable for its success. Some arguments have recently taken place between the unions and Third sector organizations on the issue of the guarantees to be secured to workers employed by undertakings of this type. These arguments now seem to tend to be settled, leading up to a situation of mutual understanding in the bargaining process. The « Third sector » is characterized by the mixed presence of entrepreneurial and social elements. Looking at it as an economic phenomenon means to focus on the possibility to create new employment opportunities, to strengthen the economic growth, to support the production of social services, to provide occasions to experiment innovative and flexible forms of work organization. According to this - it can be defined the « economic view » - the « Third sector » is essentially the way to fight the unemployment produced by the jobless growth and to find alternative productive systems between the State and the market, once (even partially) accepted their failure. Although this approach is broadly diffused, it seems to be a reductive interpretation of the role the « Third sector » plays in the social system. Indeed its relevance is not just in the 38 economic features or potentials, but in the combination, as already said, of economic and social elements. The principle of solidarity is at the basis of all the experiences in the field of Social economy and it is therefore the key factor under which each analysis regarding this world should be conducted. This leads to the second view - the « social view » - useful to look at the « Third sector » also as provider of social services and as the only way to meet unsatisfied social needs, which are characterized by a high degree of differentiation and are thought and « produced » according to the beneficiaries’ necessities. Thus, solidarity on the one hand, and the need to adapt supply to demand on the other hand, are transferred into the structures of non-profit organizations by the adoption of democratic and participative internal rules and are reflected in the forms of work, especially by a pronounced flexibility and motivation of workers. These elements seem to give to « Third sector » organization some competitive advantages in respect of the « for-profit enterprises » but, at the same time, define a very peculiar operative framework not easy to be understood just using the traditional schemes and parameters. It is evident that many problems concerning work can be probably solved by global policies sustaining and promoting the development of the « Third sector ». In Lunaria’s research on the « Third sector » (Lunaria, 1997), the 16.4% of the organizations, which have been questioned, think that would be necessary drawing up a specific national contract for the « Third sector »: the organizations should be one of the parties, and the trade union the other one, but maybe this would mean to admit that there are different interests between workers and organizations. According to the results emerged from this research the other main possible interventions are: • • • a partial exemption from the payment of social contribution that would be charged to the State. The organizations could pay only one third of contributions for the first two years, and then the 50%; the possibility of using training contracts obtaining the exemption of the 75% of social contributions; the incentive and facilities for the utilization of part-time contracts. The context policies, singled out in the research, for the increasing of employment possibilities (and reduction of precarious forms of work) are, ordered by importance: 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. a more spread and organized national civil service; a major attention of the local institutions on the « Third sector »; the lowering of working times; a granted minimum salary; leaves for voluntary service; specific rules for women. This should let emerge a big part of the « black economy », and should make many jobs that are now insufficiently paid become « real » occupations. It is also evident that the situation of work in the « Third sector » is connected in many ways with the general situation of the labour market and of the labour world. Nevertheless, the only real solution is finding the balance-point between « Third sector » peculiarities and a satisfying standard of workers’ protection. In fact, the dynamism and the informality of « Third sector’s » working organization are not only key factors to grant the effectiveness of 39 the action or elements that are indispensable to the organizations’ survival. They are also an expression of freedom, of a better work environment, and of the experimentation possibility. At the same time it is not possible to conceive that the rights of workers can be derogated, even if they are satisfied and gratified workers, or that the lack of protection is a price that must be paid to reach the fixed goal. Otherwise, two are the risks. The first one is that talking about the possibility for the « Third sector » to provide new employment opportunities can become a non sense, spurring only the creation of non-work, intended as bad-work, not protected or not sustained by strong social and economic basis. The second one is the creation of a deep and irremediable contradiction between the spirit and the essence of the Social economy (social aims, democratic organization, economic transparency, non-profit purposes), and its practises. The « Third sector » is surely needed by the society for its growing social and economic role, but it is needed at its higher potential, therefore it will be ever more important to find the appropriate forms and schemes to let its typical organizational freedom free from abuses and misunderstandings. A recent Italian study11 has reviewed the prospects of some development scenarios in welfare-quality markets (e.g. certain forms of care of the elderly and of non-hospitalized nonself-sufficient patients, baby-sitting, etc.) with a view both to causing a real demand and an entrepreneurial supply to emerge and to opening up these markets to actual quantitative and qualitative growth opportunities. According to the scheme proposed by this study, both the demand side and the supply side should be regulated as follows: - - - 11 The price collected by an enterprise providing welfare quality services should be the market price, and the market price should not be subjected to regulation where adequately competitive conditions prevail. The price should be regulated through the use of contract agreements with public authorities, e.g. with local governments wherever competition is poorly developed or supply temporarily scarce. In any event, the quality of the services to be so supplied should be subjected to regulation and control. Prices can be differentiated by government authorities in favour of consumers unable to pay full market prices, through vouchers to be sold to consumers (and used by them in making payments to service providers) or by making the price paid by them to purchase a service tax-deductible. Both the voucher prices and the tax-deduction rates, as the case may be, should be differentiated on the basis of each consumer’s financial situation, and public resources should only be committed to the extent required to make good for the difference between the purchasing power of the vouchers and the prices charged to lowincome consumers or to cover the tax-deductions so allowed. Incentives to the demand for services on the part of groups of users’ associations, e.g. by making public facilities available to them or by granting partial contributions towards the payment of costs. The development and regulation of the role non-profit-making enterprises can play in welfare-quality markets, so that the peculiar nature of their mission target and related motives for action may bring about a growing degree of consumers’ confidence, then a greater effective demand, thereby improving the market’s functioning. Real services - especially of an information and education type - and financial services especially through financial institutions selecting business ventures and conveying public De Vincenti C. and Gabriele S., eds., I mercati di qualità sociale, Bari, 1999. 40 and private funds to support them - could be provided to start-up enterprises in the « Third sector ». The proposed framework is supplemented with a scenario accommodating some labour market flexibility for workers employed in welfare quality markets under reduced working time arrangements, and fixed term or interim employment contracts. Financial instruments: The Banking foundations issue Ethical finance instruments should be developed to enhance and support investments, savings and lending in view of a solidaristic principle. This is why ethical banks should be permitted to exist at a domestic level. Far more important financial measures are required to allow the banking foundations to play a more active role in funding third-sector operations. The banking foundations represent, together with the IPABs discussed above, a peculiarity of the Italian environment. Until 1990 (the year of the « Amato » Act no. 218), these institutions comprised the area (not even uniformly regulated) of the public credit institutions (originating from the former Sate banks of pre-unification Italian states or from the fascist corporative regime’s financial ventures) and of local major savings banks. These institutions were not treated as private enterprises in the banking industry, but as public corporations operating in that industry. Banking operations were spun off from the newlyestablished foundations, and granted the status of joint-stock companies, in 1990. The equivocal configuration taken on by banking foundations since 1990 — as entities responsible for providing socially useful services and, at the same time, for directly managing their own assets consisting in majority equity investments in their spun - off banking subsidiaries - will be gradually eliminated (over 6 years) under a very recent piece of legislation, Act 461 of 23 December 1998. The legislative decree (delegated by parliament to, and approved by, the government in April 1999) will prevent banking foundations from having a dominant position over banking undertakings. In other words, the banking foundations will dispose of their controlling interests in the banking institutions that were spun off from them in 1990. Thereby, the banking foundations - which number about one-hundred with assets totalling ITL 70 000 billion - will essentially focus their operations on the achievement of the « purposes of social usefulness and advancement of economic growth as provided for in their charters ». Even so, the issue of the so-called « self-reporting » ability of banking foundations’ directors arising from their older by-laws will remain unsettled along with the issue of the greater role played by the local « powers that be » and municipalities, which have been empowered to appoint the foundations’ managing bodies responsible for the handling of the banking subsidiaries’ shares, which may be sold off in many instances over the planned 7 yearsperiod. Banking foundations - now being gradually changed into quasi-associative foundations - will tend to become the largest single group within the non-profit-making sector in Italy. 2.2.6 Recapitulatory remarks about the principal legal characteristics of the non-profit sector in Italy 41 From the analysis carried out it appears that under the Italian legal system there are no organic or specific regulations concerning non-profit organizations. The recent decree law no. 460 of 4 December 1997 which reforms the taxation of non-commercial bodies and introduces the concept of socially useful non-profit-making organizations (ONLUS), does not in fact designate a new type of juridical figure, but rather establishes characteristics that are important only from a tax point of view, that the various civil law figures may assume if they possess the necessary requisites. The decree regarding non-profit-making organizations affects only a part of the non-profit universe and only a part of the « Third sector ». Many thought it more appropriate to first establish a complete set of regulations for the « Third sector » at a civil level and subsequently, using this as a basis, establish a separate set of tax norms. However, the way things have developed, these legitimate expectations have not been fulfilled. The differences that exist among the various types of non-profit organizations under our system are such that it is improbable that we shall arrive at a unitary category of « Third sector » companies. The majority of non-profit organizations in Italy do not even possess the three characteristics typical of this sector: the private nature, the independence from external entities and the lack of direct political links. Many non-profit organizations, since they have a semi-public legal regime, are not institutionally separate from the State and receive financing which, by law, is destined for public institutions. The management structures of many organizations are strictly controlled by public or ecclesiastic (IPAB) authorities. Lastly, other organizations that are controlled or supported by political parties are obliged to support the candidates and policies of their « sponsors ». It would, therefore, appear to be quite clear that the concept of the « Third sector » is even more limited than that of the non-profit segment, where the discriminatory factor appears to be limited to a simple, generalized absence of lucrative purpose. Moreover, there are other ambiguities in the universe of the non-profit subjectiveness in the Italian system. Some examples of this are: the lack of internal democracy within recreational and cultural associations that offer services exclusively to their members and are therefore excluded from being considered socially useful non-profit-making organizations; co-operative companies which, in order to be distinguished by their mutualist or company nature, find themselves on the borderline between the market and the non-profit sector; the banking foundations that are asked to concentrate on raising funds to be destined for non-profit organizations, progressively abandoning their role as manager of majority interests in banking companies. In addition to stressing the various ambiguities that exist and the lack of a general conceptual univocality and of sector regulation at a civil level, it is also opportune to clarify that not even the tax system provides for a total concept of non-profit entities. In other words, fiscal regulations do not contemplate a unitary concept of the non-profit figure, not even in the oversimplified accepted sense of « non-profit-making », with the result that an organization of that type cannot expect to automatically receive a specific treatment so that they may exist as such. This does not even happen with the ONLUS, and they hold the record in terms of tax concessions. 42