OECD summarises options for addressing the tax challenges of the digital economy
by user
Comments
Transcript
OECD summarises options for addressing the tax challenges of the digital economy
Tax Policy Bulletin Tax Insights from International Tax Services OECD summarises options for addressing the tax challenges of the digital economy 26 March 2014 In brief The discussion draft released by the OECD confirms the view that tax measures designed exclusively for the digital economy are likely to prove problematic, primarily because of the difficulties in identifying a specific “digital” sector. Rather, the potential use of modern information and communications technology by all businesses seems to raise “digital” tax issues. Nonetheless, the OECD clearly believes that the perceived weaknesses in the territorial tax system and the international tax rules as a whole as require change in the tax rules in order to cope with modern business practices. The OECD’s Task Force on the Digital Economy was established in September 2013 under Action Plan item 1 of the Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS) project. Its remit was to consider the taxation issues arising from digital business and to identify potential measures to remedy any shortcomings, considering both direct and indirect tax options. Widespread concern with the question of whether the existing international tax rules have kept pace with the emergence of new business models enabled by the rapid development of information and communication technology was a key driver behind the BEPS Action on the Digital Economy. The relatively lengthy discussion draft underlines the difficulties of identifying ready solutions to the tax challenges of digital business. Nonetheless, by reference to the discussion draft’s own terms, it will be important for any potential solutions to satisfy the neutrality principle. As the discussion draft states, “ring-fencing the digital economy as a separate sector and applying tax rules on that basis would be neither appropriate nor feasible.” Inevitably, this will be a challenge to the extent that any solutions are designed for digital business alone. This suggests the OECD might seek to address the tax challenges of the digital economy largely through the other BEPS workstreams. A revised version of this report is likely to cross-reference how proposals potentially affecting broader types of business could have an impact on the digital economy. In detail The discussion draft includes some extensive background discussion of the development of the digital economy including emerging and possible future developments. It also discusses the spread and impact of information and communication technology across the economy, provides examples of new business models and identifies the key features of the digital economy. The draft then provides a detailed description of the core elements of BEPS strategies in the digital economy and discusses how the development of measures envisaged in the BEPS Action Plan and the OECD work on indirect www.pwc.com Tax Insights taxation are expected to address them. Finally, it identifies the broader tax challenges raised by the digital economy and summarises the potential options to address them that have been presented to, and initially discussed by, the OECD Task Force. The discussion draft raises a number of detailed questions (relating to direct and indirect tax) on which comments are sought. Unlike the other BEPS workstreams, in the OECD’s work on the digital economy there is a significant focus on VAT/ GST. In this context, there seems to be a clear consensus that, for digital services, the place of taxation should be based on the place where the consumption occurs. However, in order to determine where taxation should arise, there must be an agreed proxy to determine that location. It is also necessary to identify who is liable to account for the tax due and the mechanisms to simplify compliance and payment of the tax due. These are the main VAT/ GST issues that the draft seeks to address. Areas of concern to the OECD The discussion draft notes that, in connection with direct taxation, the common features of tax planning that raise BEPS concerns are: minimisation of tax in the source country either by avoiding a taxable presence or by maximising deductions where there is such a presence, low or no withholding tax at source, low or no tax at the level of the recipient, and no current taxation of lowtax profits at the level of the ultimate parent In relation to VAT, the areas of BEPS concerns are stated to be VAT avoidance or reduction by the use of: remote digital supplies to business in a jurisdiction giving full deduction rights with internal (branch to branch) recharge to an exempt business, and underdeclared VAT on B²C supplies, understatement of value of low value imports – inappropriate use of thresholds. Approach to tackling BEPS in the digital economy The discussion draft indicates at a general level how the OECD’s work on BEPS is expected to address direct and indirect taxation in the digital economy. In relation to direct tax, the main goal is to restore taxation on what is described as “stateless income” and this is expected to be delivered by various measures including on treaty abuse, hybrids, permanent establishments, CFC rules, (including the possibility of anti-inversion rules) etc. This discussion reinforces the view that the OECD is increasingly seeing the response to the challenges raised by the digital economy as a part of its BEPS package as a whole, rather than as exclusively the product of a separate work stream on digital business. Nonetheless, the draft does also contain some specific proposals which arise out of the work of the Task Force on the Digital Economy. Options to address the tax challenges of the Digital Economy Five options have been specifically considered by the Task Force and these are discussed below. In assessing these possible options, it is clarified that regard should be had to the “Ottawa Principles” which were developed at the time of 1998 OECD Report, Electronic commerce: Taxation Framework Conditions. These principles consist of five criteria – neutrality; efficiency; certainty and simplicity; effectiveness and fairness; and flexibility. The five specific options proposed in the OECD paper are: modifications to the exemption from PE status, the creation of a “significant digital presence” PE, varieties of a “virtual” presence PE, withholding tax on digital transactions, and consumption tax options Modifications to the exemptions from PE status Several variations are proposed on changes to the exemptions from PE status for various items of a preparatory or auxiliary nature (Article 5, paragraph 4 of the Model Tax Convention). One option would effectively remove all those exemptions PwC Tax Insights except the one relating to the maintenance of a fixed place of business solely for the purpose of carrying on, for the enterprise, any other activity of a preparatory or auxiliary character. A second option would be to remove all the exemptions. A third option would relate to the following existing exemptions in the current Art 5(4): the use of facilities solely for the purpose of storage, display or delivery of goods or merchandise belonging to the enterprise, the maintenance of a stock of goods or merchandise belonging to the enterprise solely for the purpose of storage, display or delivery, the maintenance of a stock of goods or merchandise belonging to the enterprise solely for the purpose of processing by another enterprise, and the maintenance of a fixed place of business solely for the purpose of purchasing goods or merchandise or of collecting information, for the enterprise Under this option, all of the above exemptions would be available but only if the overall character of the activity conducted is preparatory or auxiliary in nature, (and not one of the core activities of the enterprise). Observation: In the context of the issues raised by digital business, etc. the report suggests revisiting the borderline between what is to count as crossing the PE threshold rule and what is treated as not creating tax nexus for the purposes of the rule because of the potential for the digital economy to penetrate a market with minimal physical presence. This would presumably be relevant to some (but probably a limited number of) digital businesses e.g. those carrying out marketing activities, etc. but the proposed change would, potentially have a more significant impact on wider business. The creation of an ‘economic presence’ PE where a business includes ‘fully dematerialised digital activities’ and such activity in a territory amounts to a ‘significant digital presence’ A new nexus is proposed based on a significant digital presence for an enterprise engaged in ‘fully dematerialised digital activity’. Two alternative proposals are put forward, one based on the use of personal data obtained from users in the country and the other based on other elements of the business model. The discussion draft indicates that there might be a test for determining the nature of a ‘fully dematerialised digital activity’. At the moment, only possible elements of such a test are considered in the draft. Taking one example from the eight possible options that are included, it is suggested that this approach could apply to a core business that comprises digital goods and/or services, to which a substantial proportion of profits can be attributed. There could be some physical activities (e.g. systems maintenance) but these would be incidental, and most of the business operations, including contracts and payments, would be carried out digitally or remotely. One alternative suggestion for when a ‘significant digital presence’ might be found is intended to apply to a digital business carrying out significant business in Country A using personal data collected from the internet activities of individuals in that country. The discussion draft suggests that it would require the use of data obtained by regular and systematic monitoring of internet users through the use of multi-sided business models. Country A would use the nexus to tax profits arising from the use of that data. The other alternative for determining a ‘significant digital presence’ relates to other elements of the business model of a digital business. Again, only examples are suggested. Included in this list of four examples is the situation of a branch in Country A offering secondary functions such as marketing and consulting strongly related to the core business of the enterprise. The other examples relate to the remote signature of contracts with customers in Country A; use and consumption of digital goods or services in Country A; and substantial payments from customers in Country A in connection with the provision PwC Tax Insights of goods or services in Country A as part of its core business. Observations: This seems largely a different version of the same question that arose a number of years ago with respect to business models arising from the use of radio, television, and mail-order. The conclusion has long been that merely selling into a market without physical presence or a dependent agent within the market is not sufficient to create a permanent establishment allowing that country to claim a share of the enterprise’s profits. This would be a substantial departure from those principles. From a technical perspective, one might reasonably conclude that there is nothing unique to doing business in the digital economy that should change that conclusion, but the magnitude of tax at stake as a result of the application of these principles to the digital economy is such that the OECD appears to be suggesting that they may need to be reconsidered. A related question is whether the mere fact that a market (but no commercial activity of the vendor) is located in a particular country should allow that country to consider that it may tax a share of the profits of the enterprise therefrom. That idea was previously rejected on the basis that the value creating activities take place at the location of production, not the location of consumption, so this would be another very major shift in approach. As these comments indicate and notwithstanding the difficulty in determining what constitutes ‘significant business’, the real issue is how “profits arising” would be measured. The ideas proposed in the OECD draft effectively represent a new threshold concept. The discussion leaves open the question as to how the proposals could be reconciled with the guidance on Article 7 (profit attribution) in respect of which it has already been acknowledged that attributing profits to a PE is one of the most conceptually difficult and practically complex issues in international business taxation. In particular, in considering the attribution of value to data, there are differing views about how the value really originates. Is the value in the data itself or the processes used to collect, analyse and use that data? The existing rules operate on the basis that “value” resides in the activities that create value from data, and profits should be attributed to the locations in which they occur. There are a number of terms and concepts used in the personal data alternative which are not yet defined and this raises additional questions as to the viability of this proposal. Alternative thresholds based on other “virtual” PE concepts The discussion draft notes the options for alternative PE thresholds proposed over the years by the Business Profits Tax Advisory Group (TAG): a virtual fixed place of business PE, a virtual agency PE, and an on-site business presence PE. However, it states that these are included “only for the sake of completeness”. Observation: It is unclear whether ‘for the sake of completeness’ means that they are not proposing to take forward these suggestions at this time. That does seem to be the logical inference but in any event seems to reflect a lack of enthusiasm for these alternatives. Many of our comments above regarding economic presence PE are also relevant to virtual PEs. For example, merely selling into a market without physical presence or a dependent agent has not been sufficient to create a PE, and this has been true long before the advent of the digital economy. Withholding tax on digital transactions Under current permanent establishment rules it is possible for an e-commerce provider to undertake substantial economic activity in a territory in which it has no physical presence, without being taxed there. It is proposed that certain payments made by residents of that territory to such providers, for digital goods or services, be subject to a final withholding tax. Observation: The broad international consensus for some years has been to try to minimise or eliminate withholding taxes because taxes imposed on gross income PwC Tax Insights do not take into account profitability and can act as a deterrent to international commerce by making expansion across borders unprofitable. Additionally, an important potential collateral impact is that withholding tax could be imposed on broad categories of “conventional” commerce that previously were not subject to withholding tax, for example, payments for software products, music discs, movies, which are all digital products. This illustrates the potential collateral impact of rules designed for a specific targeted industry. In addition, as noted in the report, there are various considerations that would need to be considered in relation to this proposal, such as trade obligations, and the practicalities of collecting such a tax, especially in the case of individual customers, would be highly challenging. Clarification would also be needed as to which payments would be subject to the tax, and whether the decision for this, and the rates of tax, would be at international or local territory levels. The interaction with indirect taxes may also be a factor, as would double taxation relief in the territory where the profits are taxed. Finally, many of the issues revolving around revenue characterisation of transactions in digital products and services are not new and in fact have been discussed in OECD guidance dating back more than a decade. Removing VAT exemptions on the import of low value goods To reduce administration and compliance costs, many jurisdictions operate a VAT exemption on the import of low value goods. The levels of such imports have grown exponentially in the digital economy. The discussion draft states that many tax authorities would benefit from the review of these thresholds, and that improving the efficiency of their collection mechanisms could help them to lower the threshold and increase the tax revenues generated. Observation: Collection is again noted as an issue for further consideration, with the suggestion that the onus could be on non-resident suppliers to register in the importing territory and be liable for charging, collecting and remitting the tax due on the goods they supply. Whether this would apply to all low value goods and to all recipients, remains to be seen. VAT on remote digital supplies to consumers With several countries having announced proposals for the VAT registration of nonresident e-commerce suppliers making sales in their territories, but where there is no economic benefit to that territory, the OECD recognises that these requirements are likely to be administratively onerous for both suppliers and tax administrations. The recommendation is that countries should consider the introduction of simplified registration schemes and thresholds to minimise the compliance burden, and that countries should improve international co-operation and information-sharing to facilitate the enforcement of tax collection and audits. Observation: With similarities between this proposal and that for low value imports, there is scope to combine both of these proposals, especially with the import element being key to the identification of transactions having taken place, to the extent that these are physical. The supply of services would need careful consideration. Other areas for clarification include the specifics of what and who might be excluded from such VAT. The takeaway The immediate impression from the OECD paper is that of the difficulty in devising viable tax responses in this area. For the most part however, those suggestions that seem to be predicated on the idea that digital businesses can be separated from other businesses are likely to prove inherently problematic and also likely to have an impact appreciably wider than their intended targets. In our view, any proposed rules should maintain the principle of neutrality and not single out particular industries for differential tax treatment. Further, it does not seem possible to define a “digital business” in a way that could not, potentially, apply to virtually any business. As stated in the discussion draft: PwC Tax Insights “As digital technology is adopted across the economy, segmenting the digital economy is increasingly difficult. In other words, because the digital economy is increasingly becoming the economy itself, it would be difficult, if not impossible, to ring-fence the digital economy from the rest of the economy. Attempting to isolate the digital economy as a separate sector would inevitably require arbitrary lines to be drawn between what is digital and what is not.” PwC Tax Insights Let’s talk For a deeper discussion, please contact: John Steveni, London +44 (0) 207 213 3388 [email protected] Diane Baylor, California +1 408 817 5005 [email protected] Martin Blanche, London +44 (0) 207 213 8347 [email protected] Peter D’Avanzo, New York +1 646 471 5611 [email protected] Rob Bridson, London +44 (0) 207 804 7590 [email protected] Thomas Nardozzi, New York +1 646 471 4463 [email protected] Matthew Chen, Washington +1 202 414 1415 [email protected] Paul McNab, Sydney +61 (2) 8266 5640 [email protected] Steve Nauheim, Washington +1 202 414 1524 [email protected] Peter Collins, Victoria +61 (3) 8603 6247 [email protected] Peter Skewes-Cox, California +1 408 817 3885 [email protected] Stephen Dale, Paris +33 156 574161 [email protected] David Ernick, Washington +1 202 414 1491 [email protected] Joe Tynan, Dublin +353 (0) 179 26399 [email protected] Christ Economos, New York +1 646 471 0612 [email protected] Gunnar Andersson, Stockholm +46 (0) 8 555 33860 [email protected] Richard Collier, London +44 (0) 20 7212 3395 [email protected] Phil Greenfield, London +44 (0) 20 7212 6047 [email protected] © 2014 PwC. All rights reserved. PwC refers to the PwC network and/or one or more of its member firms, each of which is a separate legal entity. Please see www.pwc.com/structure for further details. This content is for general information purposes only, and should not be used as a substitute for consultation with professional advisors. PwC